Official Report 428KB pdf
Agenda item 3 is our third evidence session on the Long Leases (Scotland) Bill. We will hear from two panels. Following today’s meeting, we will conclude our evidence sessions on the bill by hearing from the minister at our meeting on 7 March.
Good morning.
I invite members to ask questions.
I suggest that we invite Mr Wightman to make a few introductory remarks on the backdrop to this evidence session and on where we are with the Long Leases (Scotland) Bill in the Parliament.
We can easily do that. Mr Wightman is looking at a particular aspect of the bill with regard to the situation in Edinburgh. If he wishes to make a short introductory statement, we would be happy for him to do so.
I do not have much to say, other than that I did not submit written evidence to this committee because the invitation was extended, as I understand it, merely to look at changes to the bill as it has been presented this session as opposed to the bill that was introduced in the previous session. My particular interest is in the common good, and no changes have been made in that regard, so I did not submit any written evidence.
Thank you. I will kick off by asking you to tell us why you think that the Waverley market area is part of the common good of Edinburgh.
Specifically why I think that the Waverley market is part of the common good of Edinburgh is a long story and perhaps need not detain the committee. I will cite just two sources of evidence, one of which is extensive documentation from the early 1980s, when the deal over the development of the shopping centre that stands there was being negotiated. I have a letter here from the council’s director of finance, for example. There is extensive written evidence and there are legal views on the fact that the Waverley market was part of the common good and that it had long been accepted as common good.
We will follow up those matters in detail. First, I will look at common good status. On page 228 of your book “The Poor Had No Lawyers”, you state:
Yes. The council told me in 2005 and 2009 that it was part of the common good. Waverley market is specifically germane to the committee’s considerations, but there is a more general point about the common good. One of my concerns is that, in its work on the Long Leases (Scotland) Bill, the Scottish Law Commission proposed to exclude everything—there were no exceptions. That is a perfectly understandable way of proceeding. The minute one opens up consideration of any bill to people arguing for exemptions, one does not know where it will end, but I have become keener on an exemption for the common good since the Government minister in the previous session conceded that long leases of commercial properties for which the rent was more than £100 a year should be exempted. If commercial interests can successfully lobby for an exemption in their own private financial interest, I fail to understand why, where land that is held for the common good of the people is concerned, we cannot have an exemption in the public interest. We do not know how many properties would be involved: a number have been identified and although there are almost certainly far more than that, it is probable that there are not a lot.
Do members wish to follow up the points that have been made?
Good morning, Mr Wightman, and thank you for coming to the meeting.
That is a very good question, and you are correct. The bill suggests that there should be automatic extinguishment of ultra-long leases on an appointed day. It contains provisions to allow leaseholders to be exempted—or is it landlords? Forgive me. There is a procedure in the bill by which people who hold long leases—landlords or tenants—will have to identify that before the appointed day. That will be straightforward in most cases. If a landlord or tenant fails to realise that they are party to a long lease, tough.
Thank you for your interesting response. Would that mean flushing out of the identification of common good land in Scotland that is under a lease? The broader issue is that there is uncertainty around the extent of common good land in Scotland.
The procedure would only assist in flushing out common good land that is subject to an ultra-long lease. There are potential problems with the idea. If Parliament exempts common good land, that could cause difficulty. I can only really conceive of a process whereby the legislation would state explicitly that conversion of leases affecting properties that are held by local authorities will not take place until a certain process has been followed. That would mean that, in 100 years, we could still have common good property subject to ultra-long leases that have not converted because the process has not been followed. You would have to find some way of exempting the common good land that has been identified—the common good land that we know about—as well as the unknown common good land, I guess. I do not think that that is a particular problem. The process could be crafted in a relatively straightforward way.
I am slightly concerned that the basis of your evidence and of the discussion so far is that ascertaining what is common good land is a black-and-white affair. Is it not correct to say that, because of the difficulty of ascertaining what is common good land from title documents and other related documents, it is not always possible for a council—or anyone else, for that matter—to answer that question clearly? Is it not also the case that, through usage and the passage of time, some land that was originally common good can cease to be so?
In many cases, councils have been sloppy, but I accept the point and agree entirely. There is no black-and-white definition of common good land. There is case law, which is relatively clear but, as evidence from throughout the country right now shows, councils can get a range of legal opinions arguing a range of conclusions on whether land is common good. That is partly a reflection of the fact that Parliament—not just this Parliament, but previous Parliaments over the decades and centuries—has failed to keep common good law under review.
Does that not confirm my point? The fact that you argue that one must go to court for the matter to be determined suggests to me that it is not possible for Parliament or anyone else to set out a clear set of rules for ascertaining exactly what the position is. The matter must go to court for the best legal minds in the country to ascertain what the position is.
Yes, but that is what I am arguing. I do not suggest that the Long Leases (Scotland) Bill should contain a legal test for what is common good land; I suggest that it should contain a procedure whereby the courts can determine that question. I think that we are in agreement.
Does that mean that there is no accepted procedure at present?
There are the courts. I am a citizen of Edinburgh and, if I had the money, I would go to the sheriff court and seek a declarator that Waverley market forms part of the common good. To be frank, I wish that the citizens of Edinburgh would dig into their pockets and do that. If they had done, we might not be in this sorry impasse.
If we were to put something into the bill about the procedure, we would repeat the current procedure.
Well, the specific procedure that you put into the bill would be up to you. I am not legally qualified, but my understanding is that the simple and straightforward way of seeking to determine whether a piece of land is common good is to go to the court and seek a declarator from the sheriff. People who wished to do that would present their evidence as to why it was or was not common good land. They would seek answers from those who had an opposing view and the sheriff would rule.
I will stick with the issue of the common good but come at it from a slightly different perspective.
As I understand it, that is a rationale for excluding Peterhead harbour and other harbours, which is fair enough—I agree. The rationale for excluding common good is not based on the ability to put it to beneficial use. However, if one were to extend that to commercial leases, the same argument would apply. There is no argument for exempting commercial leases of more than £100 a year because the land cannot be put to proper use. My understanding is that that was a straightforward lobbying exercise that was successful. I do not know what the rationale for excluding such leases is, although there might be one.
I have a more general question. Can we take it from what you say that, although it might be desirable to have a full and accurate common good register compiled throughout Scotland, in reality, it would be impractical if not impossible to achieve that?
No—I do not think that that would be impractical or impossible to achieve.
How do you suggest that we go about doing it?
We would do it by examining the historical records, which are extensive, and identifying all the land that was acquired by burghs over the years that satisfies the common good test.
If we were to pursue that, should we leave the process to the local authorities, or should it be centrally driven?
That is an existing responsibility of local authorities, because they took over the responsibilities of the former district councils and town councils. Local authorities are under a legal obligation to secure the interests of the common good for the benefit of the residents of the burghs. They have long been under that legal obligation, but they have failed in that legal duty over the years and, as a consequence, tens of millions of pounds that belongs to the people of the burghs has been lost. Indeed, as I understand it, local authorities were meant to have compiled a list by 31 March 2009. I did a survey of that. I am afraid that I have not had time to publish the results, but I will endeavour to do so soon.
It would be useful to see the results.
Were the remarks from the City of Edinburgh Council part of that survey?
Yes, my latest information from the City of Edinburgh Council is that the Waverley market forms part of the common good.
What are your views on the compensation provisions for common good land under the bill? Do you think they are sufficient? How do they fit into your analysis?
The compensation provisions appear, in general terms, to be fair. I support the general thrust of the bill, which is to convert long leases. A policy decision has been made that we do not want ultra-long leases of more than 175 years. Indeed, it is now incompetent to grant such a lease.
Good morning. I understand your point on exempting common good land, but there is a huge amount of confusion about what constitutes common good land. Many people do not know what common good land is. Can the bill progress without a definition?
In answer to a previous question, I indicated that it is not for the bill to do that. If one were to amend it and include an exemption for common good, the phrase “common good” would be well understood in legal terms and the parties undertaking any proposed procedure under the bill—councils and leaseholders—would follow the bill’s provisions.
As there are no more questions, I thank you for coming along and for your helpful evidence. You have opened up areas of the bill that we must scrutinise carefully.
I welcome our second panel. Will you introduce yourselves, for the benefit of the committee?
Thanks, convener. My day job is committee manager with Fife Council; I am also president of the Society of Local Authority Lawyers and Administrators in Scotland.
I am property management and development manager for the City of Edinburgh Council.
I am principal solicitor at City of Edinburgh Council. I head up the property and commercial law teams at the council.
I am head of asset management for Glasgow City Council.
I am estates manager at Aberdeenshire Council.
Thank you. We will ask general questions in a minute but, first, the situation with regard to the Princes mall shopping centre is intriguing. It is contended that a sublease and lease, which appear to have been amalgamated, are central to the City of Edinburgh Council’s interpretation of the status of the land. Will Mr Strachan or Mr Miller explain the situation as the council understands it?
That is probably a question for me. Mr Wightman might have raised a particular issue to do with the legal status of the interests of the Premier Property Group, the current owner or tenant of Princes mall; there is also a separate question about the alleged common good status. Perhaps I may take the latter issue first. We gave evidence to the Justice Committee on 1 February 2011, so to some extent I will refer to that. However, the make-up of the committees has changed since then, so it might help if I explain the council’s position again.
The first thing that we want to establish is whether it is your understanding that the purpose for which land is used is the reason for its being deemed common good land or whether, if land is common good land, it does not matter whether it is used for a particular purpose—in other words, markets can be transferred from one place to another, but that does not alter the status of the land from which they are removed.
As I understand it, such transfers can alter the status of the land, but I would defer to Andrew Ferguson’s legal analysis of common good law.
I am interested in your analysis of it, first.
As I understand it, if a function that could be said to give land common good status is transferred elsewhere, there should be no reason why the land where that function was originally carried out should continue to have common good status. In addition, if land is used by the public for a particular function and then it is no longer used by the public for a long period of time, there is no legal reason for it to retain common good status. In practical terms, why should it? We cannot have land that is sterilised and which cannot be used for anything else when its original purpose no longer applies. I believe that there is case law to that effect.
You are telling me that you think that the use of land that is deemed to be common good land could change—
Yes.
You are suggesting that, because of such a change, the land’s common good status could be removed and that the council would not have an interest in ensuring that it was still a part of the common good of Edinburgh.
As I understand it, for a site—of a market, say—to lose its common good status through non-use, there would have to be a fairly long period of time over which it was not put to that use. It is not something that would happen overnight. It is probably fair to say that, for the most part, such instances are quite historical. When that happened, people were probably a lot less aware of the issues.
You say that you operate in “shades of grey”, but it should be fundamental that land that belongs to the city remains part of the city’s assets.
Yes. Bill Miller might comment further on this, but I think that we have a good handle on what our register of common good assets is.
Thank you.
Good morning. Andy Wightman said that if he had the resources, or if the people of Edinburgh could get the resources together, he would like a declarator to be obtained. You said that you thought that the site was no longer common good land, but you also said, “If we are incorrect”, and talked about “shades of grey”. Given that, would it be good governance for the council to find out the legal position through the court and to get a declarator? You could then draw a line under the matter.
The issue was looked into in some detail before I came to the council. I have given the legal opinion that we reached. It is not for me to decide, but I am not sure whether spending additional time, resources and public money on seeking a declarator from the court on the alleged common good status would be the most appropriate use of council time and money, when we have already reached a view. That is my thinking.
You will wait for someone else to make a legal challenge and then react.
Our position is that we have looked at the question. Officers have spent time, effort and money and we do not think that the land is common good. We hear Mr Wightman’s considered views. If we genuinely felt that the land was common good, it would be on the common good register.
As part of his research, Mr Wightman wrote to ask all councils in Scotland for details of all their common good properties. The City of Edinburgh Council replied, but I admit that we replied with very poor information on what we had in the common good. Mr Wightman replied to us and said, “But what about” and listed a number of properties that he felt should be common good and which were not on our register. At that point, we carried out a major exercise to look at those properties and at common good status. We agreed that a number of the properties that he suggested should be common good, and they were added to the register. We did not agree that other properties that he suggested were common good, so they were not added.
Before we turn to Andrew Ferguson and others, Graeme Dey wishes to ask a supplementary question.
Thank you, convener, and good morning, gentlemen. I want to develop this point, so I would ask the other witnesses whether their local authorities are confident in the accuracy of their common good registers.
Our council has a common good register that contains a number of property assets. Like Bill Miller, I could not guarantee that the register is 100 per cent accurate. However, just as in Edinburgh, Glasgow City Council will carry out an investigation of any piece of land for which sale or lease is being proposed, and we will decide whether it should be designated as common good and be on the register. If there were still a requirement to sell or lease the piece of land, we would then have to go through the normal procedure to have it removed from the register or have a judgment made on whether we could remove it.
In Fife Council, we are pretty confident that our common good register is now perhaps 95 per cent accurate. We are at the stage of zeroing in on properties that are particularly difficult. I will give a brief example. A bit of links in a fishing village in Fife was acquired by the burgh in the 1930s. It was held on the leisure and recreation account, not on the common good account. We had some doubts about it but, when we did a sift, nothing in the title for the land gave a clue as to whether it was common good. In the 1930s, there were statutory powers to acquire for recreational purposes, so the land may have been acquired under such powers. At some point since then, the land became a caravan park—although none of us has a long enough memory to know exactly when. Some income went into the common good fund, and some went into the general fund. We then sent somebody off to St Andrews, where we hold the minutes for this particular burgh, and had her spend time—I think that it has been two mornings so far—looking through the minutes to find out why the burgh bought the piece of links. There are all sorts of interesting historical documents—for example, concerning disputes with a farmer grazing animals. We are not yet able to say definitively why the land was acquired, whether it was to be on the common good account, and, if so, whether we can treat it as common good.
I would mirror the responses that have been made. We have a common good register. Aberdeenshire Council is the successor to a number of previous councils, and the records kept by those councils varied. Some were extremely good but others were not so good. We are developing our register as we go along. When something comes up for a possible transfer, we investigate at that stage whether it is common good.
Good morning. I am certainly not a lawyer and the issue is extremely complex. I stay near the burgh of Lanark, which has its own common good fund, with its own complexities. There are many reasons why common good land might not be in public use at a particular point in time. Can Iain Strachan or any of the other witnesses comment on that? My understanding of what Mr Strachan said is that, over time, that might cause the land to cease to be common good, but perhaps I misunderstood that remark.
That is my understanding of the situation. For example, if council officials used a building for administrative purposes some time ago and then, for whatever reason, that use ceased, it would be arguable that, although it might originally have been on the common good account, after a period of time it was no longer so. As such, the council would be entitled to sell it without reference to the court, because its common good status had been lost.
Is there not an understanding that common good land should be protected by those who hold it in trust—“in trust” is perhaps the wrong legal term—or have an obligation to look after it for the people of the burgh? Do you or other witnesses want to comment on that?
That is right. As I said, instances of use changing over time probably tend to be historical, although it is difficult to generalise about an entire country. There is now a greater awareness of common good. The officers who report to me and Bill Miller’s team are all aware that common good is an issue that we should always be alive to when we deal with council assets. That is certainly the case now, but I cannot comment on what happened in the past. As a legal concept, what you suggest is right and it is something that could happen, so we need to be alive to these things.
In response to Ms Beamish’s initial question, I stress that disuse of a common good asset for public use does not always mean that it falls out of the common good altogether. When it is disposed of, the usual convention is that the proceeds of the sale go into common good. Common good assets cover a multitude of sins. The one that we have looked at most during the meeting is Waverley market, which clearly had a public use. There are other public buildings such as town halls and so on. If a common good asset is sold on, it does not necessarily mean that there is not a return to the common good.
The City of Edinburgh Council is going through a number of cases at the sheriff court for the leasing out of common good assets. I can give you an example that you will know about.
I echo what Bill Miller said. The fact that assets are listed as common good does not necessarily mean that they are set in aspic. What happens to them and what is the best management for them for the common good might be to, for example, lease out a building that has a history of neglect or has become uninhabitable or unusable in its current form. The best way of preserving that building might be to lease it to a community or to a commercial organisation.
Good morning, gentlemen. I have two questions. One is specifically about the position of the Waverley market, but I am sure that we will get back to that. On the more general issue, I have listened with interest to the discussion about the definition of “common good” and the suggestion that it is a bit of a moveable feast because it is not fixed at any given point in time and is quite difficult to identify. It is costly in man-hours for a council to conduct a full audit of what it owns and how it owns it, particularly in times of tight budgets.
You are right. Probably we have told you all about the complications of common good rather than its simplicities, if there are any. Andy Wightman said, quite fairly, that common good is a recognised legal concept in Scotland. The fact that three lawyers in a room will argue from three different points of view about whether a property is common good does not alter that fact. Existing legislation, particularly the Local Government (Scotland) Act 1973, talks about land forming part of the common good. Therefore, an exemption would use the same phraseology and leave the difficult cases—and I stress that there are difficult cases as well as pretty straightforward ones—to be argued out.
Good morning, gentlemen. Since the 1930s, we have had several changes in councils. In my area there were six district councils; we have had the regions; we went from burghs to districts; and now we have unitary authorities. Have we lost quite a lot of the knowledge about what is common good in that time?
That would be an easy way out but, after carrying out all the investigations and receiving advice, we in the council have quite clearly deemed it not to be common good. I do not see how we can go back on that decision.
So in 1937 you sold it, moved it on or whatever. Basically, you are asking the committee to use the bill to dig you out of a hole because under its provisions the area would be sold off or given away to the person leasing it. After all, according to evidence that we heard earlier, it is worth only 40p, 60p or whatever—in other words, a penny a year.
I should clarify that the council still owns the ground on which the shopping centre sits. We are talking about a long ground lease; the shopping centre itself was built by a developer. If the bill as it stands were to be passed, the council would lose ownership of the ground, which would mean that we would have to look at the bill’s provisions to find out whether this particular case would be covered and what compensation, if any, would be paid.
I want to return to the issue of common good land. Such land is supposed to be held for the good of the people of the surrounding areas, districts, burghs or whatever but, even if it is held on a central register, it can be sold off at any time unless someone objects. I know from my 30-odd years’ experience in councils what can happen to land gifted to a local area. Land in New Stevenston was gifted to the people but the council decided to extend the curtilage of the local school into it and the people in the area were no longer allowed even to walk on it. Do you agree that councils can make such rulings?
Perhaps I can answer that question. You are right that the council has to make an initial judgment on the matter. As you say, land might have been gifted for a particular purpose or dedicated for recreational or whatever use; indeed, it might have had that use for centuries. Initially, the council has to make the sometimes difficult decision whether some or any of that land should retain that use because, for example, the land itself might have fallen into disuse or it might be put to better use that will bring in money. I stress again that money from disposals of common good land and property goes into the common good fund to be used for common good purposes. After the council makes that initial decision, if there is any suggestion that the common good land is what is called inalienable—in other words, it is not meant to be sold—the courts have to decide what is in the best interests of the people of the burgh.
Yes, but I will press the point. We have witnesses from the councils in Edinburgh, Glasgow and other areas. My local government experience is that, although land has been gifted to local areas with the intention that it should be used by people and therefore any money that is raised from the sale of the land should be used for the benefit of those areas, most of the money goes into the central fund or pot and is used for other things. Do you agree?
I am not aware of that having happened in Fife—of common good land having been sold and the money having been used outwith the burgh. I am not saying that it has not happened.
Just to finish, convener, if you will allow me—
I will.
As Mr Wightman rightly says, he needs money, or people to give him money, to fund legal challenges. At the end of the day, councils hope that people will not come back to them with such challenges. You only really wait for people to come to your door. You do not go out and ask them.
The practice in Fife is that, where there is a proposal, there is consultation with the local community and the matter is considered by the local area committee first, before it is taken to the policy, finance and asset management committee. However, practices might vary.
This morning’s discussions have highlighted the general difficulties with how we define common good land and the problems therefrom. I want to bring us back to the bill. When the previous bill was before the Parliament in the previous session, the minister who was responsible said that there are probably five parcels of common good land that could be affected by the bill because they are subject to ultra-long leases. I think he said that there are two in Glasgow, one in Edinburgh, one in Fife and one in Aberdeenshire.
Peculiarly, both of our long leases are for areas that are outwith the city boundary. The two long ground leases on common good land are on Rouken Glen park, which we lease to East Renfrewshire Council, and Balloch country park, which we lease to West Dunbartonshire Council.
Thank you.
The case in Aberdeenshire is an area of recreation ground in Stonehaven, which was let on a 999-year lease to a trust that was set up by Parliament to manage the ground. The consequences for the area of transferring the land to the trust are not financial. A term of the lease is that the land should always be used for recreational purposes and the lease gives that protection. If there was an intention to use the land for another purpose, the landlord’s consent would be needed. Of course if the ownership transfers, that consent will no longer be required. There might be other protections—the act that set up the trust might require that the land be protected for recreational use, for example. However, Aberdeenshire Council is not the trustee, so we are not certain about that. The requirement in the lease that the land be used only for recreational purposes adds a level of protection.
There is one case in Edinburgh; it is a very small area of ground on Stevenlaw’s Close, off the High Street. A long lease was granted, which runs until 2191. A corner of an office block has been built on the land and eats into the close. The land is still held on the common good account, but it is really part of a building. That is the only case that we have that falls within the terms of the bill.
I understand that the Fife example is no longer an example.
The Fife example is no longer an example, not because we do not think that it is common good land but because we do not think that there is an ultra-long lease.
Notwithstanding the discussion about Princes mall, is it fair to say that we are talking about a very academic point? Given the limited amount of property that would potentially be affected by the bill, are the financial implications for councils minimal?
Yes, in relation to the cases that have been mentioned. However, we do not know what cases other authorities have. I understand that a number of authorities have not provided information—they might not necessarily know about cases. The issue is not a big one for the City of Edinburgh Council. It would be a different matter if Waverley market were included, but it is not.
We have been talking about the identification of common good land. We think that such land should be exempt in principle, because it is held for the people. There might be examples out there that we have not captured, some of which might be more significant than the ones that we have talked about. It is unlikely that that is the case, but there might be cases that we have yet to discover. There should be a safety net, in case something significant comes up as the process rolls forward. However, from Glasgow City Council’s point of view, the ultra-long leases are such that the issue is relatively insignificant.
The lease in Stonehaven was entered into in 1932—I was not around then and did not negotiate it. The purpose of doing the transaction by way of lease rather than sale is not entirely clear, but one reason might have been to include the protection on the use of the land. The consequences of doing away with long leases are not only financial.
I acknowledge that other members might have a greater grasp of some of the issues than I do at the moment. At the time of the transfer of the Waverley market to the East Market Street site, was the East Market Street site deemed to be common good land, or was it given common good status at the transfer?
It was not deemed to be common good at the time. That is why the status was moved from the Princes mall site to East Market Street.
I thought that that was the case. That meant that, in the act, everything was transferred from the Waverley market site to the East Market Street site. Is that your understanding?
My understanding is that the common good status—indeed, the whole market—was transferred to that site.
Yes, and the common good status went to the then new site at Cranston Street.
So, one area became common good and one stopped being common good.
Yes.
Okay. Thank you.
That is a difficult question for me to answer. We are continually looking at whether land in some areas forms part of the common good. There are areas where we believe that the land is common good and we are considering going to court to have the common good status removed. However, none of those areas involves an ultra-long lease.
Is the council going to court to have the common good status removed so that the ground can be sold on?
The reason varies, but that is one possibility.
I think that my question is for the City of Edinburgh Council, but it may be relevant to all our witnesses. It has been pointed out that no allowance is being made for a grassum having been paid—a large, up-front payment with peppercorn rent being paid thereafter. Do you see many circumstances in which that might occur within your local authorities? Does the situation relate only to common good, or could it relate to some commercial properties that local authorities own?
My understanding—Bill Miller will correct me if I am wrong—is that only two properties in Edinburgh would potentially come under the scope of the bill.
Those are Stevenlaw’s Close and Princes mall, and the grassum issue probably applies only to Princes mall. There may be instances of ultra-long leases elsewhere around the country.
In the excellent briefing on the bill from the Scottish Parliament information centre, mention is made of Brodies LLP having previously given evidence on variable rents, whereby the base rent is very low and the real rent is linked to, for example, how well a shopping centre is doing and the incomes of the individual shops. It is not really for me to comment, but I imagine that that may be an area for the bill’s draftspersons to look at.
It is common for grassums to be paid for leases for particular reasons—for example, when a landlord sees fit to take a large lump sum of money at a certain time and grant a longer lease at £1 per annum or for a peppercorn rent. In such circumstances, they take a lump sum of money equivalent to the rent over the period of the lease. That is quite common in commercial leases. It means that the landlord still has control over the land or property. They have not sold the land so they do not lose control and can still influence what happens during the period of the lease and thereafter. That is what the City of Edinburgh Council did with Waverley market: it did not want to lose ownership of the site for many reasons, including its location. Perhaps Mr Strachan can comment further, but that is the commercial position.
I will make some comments by way of background to Princes mall. As my colleague has said, the council would never have knowingly sold the site and completely given up all interest in it. It is a unique site of special significance to the capital city, located as it is beside Princes Street gardens and adjacent to Waverley station, which is itself a landmark destination. It is close to the transport hub at St Andrew Square and is in a United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization world heritage site. We all know the vision of the city that gets beamed around the world at hogmanay. Given the site’s significance, the council, as guardian of the city, should have an involvement in it and so should retain its heritable interest going forward.
I have a question on that point. It seems that your failsafe position for Princes mall at this stage—notwithstanding that the bill was around in the previous session of Parliament—is to include a specific exemption for it. Do you feel that the Princes mall scenario is unique and that, therefore, an exemption for Princes mall would not impinge in any way on circumstances that may pertain elsewhere? As Mr Strachan said, statute by exemption is not how things are normally done, but it can be done for specific cogent reasons. Having considered the issue, does the City of Edinburgh Council believe that the case has been made for such a specific exemption?
I am not aware of any other such case. We have talked about common good in the abstract, but when it comes down to the nuts and bolts, there are maybe only a handful of cases that would, in practice, be affected by the bill.
With respect, you are now saying that the land is not common good, so we are into a completely different set of arguments.
Yes, but—equally—I am not aware of evidence that there are other properties throughout the country that have special significance and might also be caught. Elected members in the City of Edinburgh Council clearly feel that a case can be made that the property in question should be exempted, given its location and the comments that I made earlier.
I appreciate that it is not necessarily for you to know the situation throughout Scotland, but it is for the legislators to have an idea of the concrete impact of providing for one specific exemption along the failsafe lines that you suggest.
I admit that our suggestion is in some respects rather simplistic but, in essence, the grassum is the rental income capitalised on a day 1 basis. The amount of money might be lower, but that is because the landlord has decided that because they get all that money up front, they are prepared to take a slightly lower amount than they would get from rental that was spread over the lifetime of the lease. However, given that the bill seeks to exclude commercial leases on the basis of a monetary test, if we accept that a grassum is akin to the rental over the lifetime of the lease and then treat it as rental income and bring it into the calculation of the annual rent, we might get a truer reflection of the monetary value of the property. That is where I was coming from on that point.
Do you feel that, if we were starting again today, some councils might structure their property dealings differently? You talked about the council being the guardian of the land that it owns, whether or not it is under common good. Might it now be felt that the way in which some deals were structured was perhaps not in the best interests of the citizens?
If we had known at the time that we might lose Princes mall through the bill, which was not at that time under consideration, we might have thought that we should take a certain level of grassum but retain the £100 rent to ensure that we had on-going involvement in the property. With a landlord-tenant relationship, there is an on-going contract. Title conditions are notoriously difficult to enforce, so from a landlord’s perspective, if we seek to have involvement in or control over use, potential development and the like, it is often easier to have a landlord-tenant relationship than a relationship that is based purely on title conditions. Therefore, the answer to your question is, “Possibly.”
From listening to the evidence, there seems to be agreement that there is uncertainty around the accuracy of the common good register, but you all seem to be positive that what you know of long leases is accurate and correct. That is certainly what has come across to me.
From an Edinburgh point of view, it is easier to identify leases, because there is legal documentation, whereas the title for a common good property does not actually say that it is common good land.
I see that the other witnesses are of the same mind—they are nodding.
That relates to the point that I made earlier. The justification for excluding common good property from the bill is to cover exactly that point as transactions occur, and as we investigate the land or buildings whose purpose will change when they are sold, leased or transferred to community ownership. Although it is unlikely that there is anything significant of which we are not aware, if the bill can provide a failsafe, Glasgow City Council would encourage the committee to consider that.
From an Edinburgh point of view, I am 100 per cent certain that only two long leases come under the bill. We have a good property register of what we own, but whether land is common good land is a grey area: we think we know what we have in the common good account. There may be odd ones out, but they are not on leases. We know what long leases we have: the only two are for Waverley market and Stevenlaw’s Close, which have been mentioned. I would be amazed if anything else were to come out; our records, which have been gathered over many years, do not show anything else.
The SPICe briefing says that eight councils have not yet reported back, so there are some known unknowns about how many ultra-long leases there are. As my colleagues have said, knowing what is covered by an ultra-long lease is a lot easier than knowing what is covered by common good. If I may be mischievous, perhaps the easiest way for the bill to cover the matter would be to exclude all local authority ultra-long leases. That would cover Waverley market, but perhaps the committee would not like to go that far.
For the record, today is the final day for submissions from the eight councils. We have received responses from four of them, so we will know after today what they have to say about their common good registers.
I will return to Princes mall. I say again that if we took Mr Wightman’s advice, the property would be put in a common good fund. I have experience over the years of sitting on property committees—Mr Young used to work for my authority many years ago—so I know how many leases, solums and other things you guys have had to deal with since the 1980s. Basically, you were forced into that because of costs and trying to bring money in to councils.
Yes—that is right. If we, as a council, had known that there was a chance that the lease would be removed without our being able to do anything about it, we would not have entered into a lease of such length, but would probably have gone for a lease of lesser length. It is also right to say that, over the years, councils have leased out property and taken grassums because they needed capital for capital investment programmes.
I suggest that you were encouraged by various Governments over the years to do that.
I do not. You are going into the area of human rights and rights to property and so on. The Government’s legal advisers will advise on that, but I do not see a huge risk of legal action against the Scottish Parliament or Scottish Government for making such an exception. Don’t quote me.
We are pleased that you were all able to come today. Your information has been helpful.
Yes.
I want to talk about the Edinburgh case again. Mr Miller remarked that the extension of the Waverley market site’s lease from 125 to 206 years was made at a particular time so that a new arrangement could be made with the lessees. That underlines Mr Wightman’s point that the arrangement was made for commercial reasons by a commercial group so that it could extend its interests in the site, which suited the council at the time. The extension of the lease is an interesting area.
The original lease that was commenced in 1982, if I remember rightly, was a ground lease to the developer who built the shopping centre. In 1989, the council was approached by the developer, who wanted to sell on his interest, but the 1982 agreement was such that the ground lease had a rental attached to it because the property was sub-leased back to the council. The rent was quite high at that time.
The rent was greater than £940,000 and 76 per cent of the rental income.
A substantial rent was being brought in at that time, because although the council paid the rent, it sublet, or sub-sublet, all the shop units. So, when we were approached by the centre’s owner to extend the lease, there was a good income. For various reasons, including monetary ones and perhaps the one that Mr Lyle suggested, the council negotiated the extension of the lease and stepped back from being party to the tenancies. I think that the lease became a straight ground lease—am I right? I just cannot get my mind back there.
It was a ground lease originally, but the council and the developer sold their respective interests together, because the marriage value made greater financial sense. The council could have bought the developer out, and probably considered doing so but did not have the capital resources. The whole thing was sold for £23.5 million, of which the council received £6.25 million at the time.
The answer is that we still wanted to hold on to the lease agreement, even though the rental was up. We took a lump sum in lieu of rental.
It is useful to have this on the record, for our next meeting and beyond.
There are two points to make. We accept that under the current compensation provisions the compensation for the loss would be minimal. As you correctly say, landlords can claim additional payments, based on the loss of residual heritable interest and potential development value, but I think it is fair to say that given that you are talking about a lease that expires in a significant period of time, its value, as assessed by the Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors in Scotland, would be minimal. We should look at this not purely on the basis of the asset’s monetary value, but its non-monetary value to the city. Does that answer your question?
That is useful, as we gather evidence before considering it. Does anyone else have final points to make?
At the end of the lease, the whole site would revert to the council. Although the council took a grassum, as was said earlier that does not necessarily mean it took the full, open-market price for the property in a market where there is a willing buyer and seller. However, the whole site will revert back in couple of hundred years or whatever is left of the lease. There might be a requirement for something other than a shopping centre or mall, but we do not know. There might also be a value beyond that period, but we cannot tell at this time what it will be, because it is too far away. As Mr Strachan said, the RICS looks at the valuation of a reversion. We cannot look ahead 200 years, and the amount would be peanuts, really. Under the compensation provision in the bill, the council would get no monetary compensation.
Thank you.
You might think that there is no connection between Waverley market and the recreation grounds in Stonehaven, but the connection is that there is more to a lease than rent. The main concern that I pick up from Edinburgh is that, as part of a leasing arrangement rather than a sale, they are looking to have some control over the asset in the future. In respect of many ultra-long leases it is possible that the terms of the lease, other than the rent, are of more concern. Once a grassum is accepted, the owner will get only a peppercorn rent, but it is not the peppercorn that the owner is interested in, but what the other terms of the lease give. That is the connection between the two cases that I referred to and, probably, others, including cases that may not have been picked up yet.
Thank you, gentlemen. We have been talking about peanuts and peppercorn and irritating common good matters, which probably needed to be stirred up so that we can consider in more detail what has been proposed. I thank you for your evidence. If there are additional matters on which you wish to write to us, please feel free to do so.