Official Report 339KB pdf
We move on to day 2 of stage 1 consideration of the Water Services etc (Scotland) Bill.
There are two issues: one is structural and one will be in the detail if one proposal in the bill goes ahead. Splitting Scottish Water to allow competition in the non-household market would create business separation. The bill proposes a Scottish Water retail business and a Scottish Water wholesale business. Our concern, which is based largely on our experience of other utilities that went down that road some years ago, is that huge costs are involved in such separation. It involves rebranding and the setting-up of marketing, sales and billing operations, all of which have a huge cost that must be passed on to the consumer.
Given what the Executive intends to do, how would you set up Scottish Water to succeed?
We would not split Scottish Water in the proposed way—that is the essence of our evidence. We do not believe that splitting Scottish Water is the way forward. Our view is that the business should not be separated and that non-household competition should not be created. We start from disagreement with the Executive on that point.
I want to follow on from that. My experience is that opinion favours the view that retail competition in the domestic energy sector resulted in a significant fall in the relative cost of energy over a considerable period of time. Why do you suggest that similar competition in the water industry—whether as prescribed in the bill or beyond it—would not be equally beneficial?
I would be happy to provide you with research that was undertaken by the University of Sussex a couple of years ago, which studied in detail the price shift in the energy market to determine how much was due to competition and how much was due to other factors. The research concluded that most of the reductions at the early stages—bear in mind the fact that we are in a situation of rapidly rising energy prices—were to do with coincident changes in raw material prices, that is, raw energy prices, and were not due to competition at all. The reason for that is that any small saving that competition may introduce is balanced by the additional costs of establishing the system, which are massive.
Are there any circumstances in which retail competition can be beneficial to the consumer?
In a word, no.
That was very clear.
I will address the section 3 issue. Last week we debated the composition of the water industry commission. Paragraph 8 of your submission states that you want the
It is fair to say that local authorities' views differ on developer costs. Indeed, the Convention of Scottish Local Authorities itself does not have a single view on the matter. We have to face the facts. The Executive's consultation paper "Investing in Water Services 2006-2014 (The Quality and Standards III Project)" makes it clear that, over the next 10 years at least, something like £1 billion a year will have to be spent on Scotland's water and sewerage infrastructure. Obviously, that is a huge sum of money to find, which is why the second consultation—on how we pay for it—is the more difficult one. Moreover, the construction industry needs a huge amount of capacity to deal with the issue.
I must follow that up by pointing out that, at the moment, 38 per cent of all rural settlements in the Highland Council area are constrained by inadequate water services and that three major regeneration projects involving the council are potentially at risk. We have also heard that a moratorium has been introduced in Perth. The water industry commission will have to address major deficits in many parts of the country, a recent example of which is the Western Isles. The suggestion in paragraph 8 of your submission will not meet conditions throughout the country; we need a clearer picture of how such an approach will affect the rest of the country and the background of any personnel who might be appointed to the commission.
We need to separate out two issues in your question, the first of which is the importance of extending our networks to areas that are currently not supplied by sewerage or water systems. Clearly, as that involves public expenditure, it is a legitimate public policy issue. The second point relates to commercial developments in new housing schemes and so on. In those circumstances, it seems only reasonable that developers pay all or most of the costs that might be incurred.
That is an interesting answer because we spent a lot of time arguing about this matter at our previous meeting. One of the things that we were trying to get clear in our minds was exactly how the public policy framework is set. As you rightly say, the quality and standards III process and the investment consultation are under way. We want to work out at what point an examination of efficiency and value for money delivering the service kicks in and how the calculations about various policy objectives, for example on the environment or social justice, come in. Last week, we were trying to find out whether those considerations are part of the minister's job, in instructing Scottish Water, or whether they are part of the regulator's job. Who makes those decisions? Does the STUC have a view on that?
We do. In the first place, there is clear ministerial direction on investment and funding. I am sure that members of the committee have studied the current consultation documents. The "Investing in Water Services 2006-2014" document sets out the investment in Scottish Water in a particularly clear way for the first time—previously, valid criticisms were made, especially by the old Transport and the Environment Committee, about the fact that the investment was not properly explained.
What would be your ideal appeal system?
That is a political decision for ministers, who are accountable to Parliament. Parliament, not a London-based commission, should decide whether the balance of public policy and other issues is appropriate for Scotland.
It is clear from your submission that you are quite sceptical about the privatisation of utilities. I share some of those concerns, particularly in relation to the pressures that come from outwith the European Union, such as those arising from the general agreement on trade in services. However, put yourself in the position of ministers. On one side there is the Competition Act 1998, which is driving some form of competition in the utilities and, on the other, there is pressure to retain the delivery and control of utilities and services in the public sector. How should that balance be maintained? Do you think that the Executive has got it right in the bill? If not, how does the STUC envisage that balance being addressed?
This is a convenient answer, but there is no doubt that we would rather not be where we are in terms of the legislation. The Competition Act 1998 must be the most ill-thought-out piece of Westminster legislation for a long time. It sounded fine at the time, but nobody thought through its long-term consequences, particularly in the devolution settlement. The problem does not end there. One of the reasons why we highlight in our submission the importance of keeping a weather eye on the issue is that the European Parliament has voted twice against the liberalisation of water, but the European Commission keeps coming back with other proposals. The services directive, which was published in January, is another attempt to liberalise water and there are drives within the general agreement on trade in services, particularly from the United States, to extend the neo-liberalisation of public services. The 1998 act is simply another example of that, but we are where we are and now that we have that piece of legislation we in Scotland have to manage as best we can and retain as much control as we can over our public services, including water.
I am not entirely clear whether you are saying that ministers' hands are tied. You seem to be saying that ministers could take more of a role in some areas. Will you explain that?
We partially had this debate during the consultation in 2000. One option for ministers is to say that water is a public service issue in Scotland for public policy reasons and because it is a service of general economic interest. There are provisions in schedule 3 to the Competition Act 1998 that arise from the competition directive and they would enable ministers to make the case that water is a public service that is not open to competition. There are different views and many things have not been legally challenged in the courts so nobody knows what the outcome would be. The view that ministers took in 2000 is different from the view that they take today. In our view, there is scope to go somewhat further and use the full exclusion provisions under schedule 3 to the 1998 act—that is our preferred solution. The current proposals will not only mess up the water industry at a time when it needs to concentrate on other things but open up the possibility of further privatisation in the industry.
One of the issues that was discussed thoroughly last week was cross-subsidy. The business community feels aggrieved that it is, as it perceives it, cross-subsidising domestic supplies. It also seems that the large water users insist on getting cut prices, which means that they are being subsidised—perhaps by medium-sized businesses. However, the large companies say that if they do not get those special terms, they can go off network and find their own private supplies. It seems to be a Gordian knot that is almost impossible to untie. What are your thoughts on the matter?
Provision exists for off-network solutions, which are obviously attractive, predominantly but not entirely, to large business users. There is some evidence of the alleged cross-subsidies; the Executive sets out some of it in "Investing in Water Services 2006-2014", but it is far from proven whether there is a cross-subsidy or how large it is. Everyone accepts that if we had spent millions of pounds setting up grandiose information systems, as the WIC has argued for for some time, we might have a better feel for what the figures are, but that would be millions of pounds not spent on improving water quality and safely disposing of sewage. Such judgments always have to be made and we have always argued that we need to get the political priorities right, but nonetheless if that information was available there might be a clearer view about whether there is a cross-subsidy.
What you have said is very interesting, but I want to get back to pursuing the idea of whether there is any value in cross-subsidy. Should there be cross-subsidy between the commercial customers of Scottish Water and the domestic customers? We keep hearing about the dichotomy between the commercial and the social. For example, in the domestic market, should people who live in big houses be subsidising people on low incomes? Should that be done by Scottish Water, or should the issue be addressed in another way, perhaps through Executive policy?
That is not an issue for Scottish Water. As you know, there is cross-subsidy at the moment between north and south. That was part of the reason for establishing Scottish Water. A number of cross-subsidies exist, but they are a matter of clear public policy. Business would rightly argue that such cross-subsidies are not necessarily an issue for them but, irrespective of the business view, Scottish Water's position should be that it is there to provide a service in accordance with public policy considerations. The decisions are political and should be for ministers and Parliament.
So, any subsidy of small or large businesses, of domestic users, or—as Rob Gibson mentioned—of developments, should come from the Executive rather than from Scottish Water's budget.
No, I am not suggesting that the money for subsidies should come from the public purse, but the decision on whether or not to have a cross-subsidy is a public policy decision. We have cross-subsidies now, as a matter of public policy.
I would like to ask the panel about the replacement of the water industry commissioner with a commission of three to five executive directors. What is the panel's view on the proposed composition of the commission? How should members be chosen? Should it be on the basis of technical expertise, or to represent particular stakeholder groups?
We would have reservations about turning the commission into a purely stakeholder body, which would be difficult with only five members. The primary function of the commission is not simply to represent stakeholders.
Will the bill's impact on employees be neutral? If not, what are the potential implications?
The bill obviously involves further upheaval for employees. Probably some 200 staff will transfer from Scottish Water to the proposed new Scottish Water retail. The bill could have a further impact, assuming that all other things were equal and that competition worked as it is supposed to do in theory. Our concern, which is based on the financial memorandum and the regulatory impact assessment, is that the bill's impact will be anything but neutral. There could be a serious impact for staff not only on the retail side but on the wholesale side because both operations in Scottish Water could be undermined. That is a crucial structural issue. We have touched on it already, but I cannot emphasise enough that it is essential that if the split goes ahead, which we do not recommend, we get both arms of the business right, with the right levels of cost and revenue accruing to both. That would be the best opportunity for the bill to be neutral as far as staff are concerned.
Will you expand on what the potential negative implications would be for staff and how those would impact on service to the customers, particularly where infrastructure is concerned?
If we get things wrong—or even, to be frank, if the split goes ahead at all—and everything goes pear shaped, there will be impacts on staff job security and morale. In the energy industries, there have been problems with the constant barrage of complaints day in, day out from customers who are confused and bewildered by the structure that was established in those industries. The aggressive phone calls and face-to-face contact and the other problems that our members face daily in those industries will be replicated in Scottish Water and that level of customer confusion and upset is not something that we want to export from the energy industries to the water industry. However, ultimately, the issue is economic viability and our concern is that if the proposed structure gets the balance wrong, our members' job security and ability to provide what they want to provide—a high-quality service to the public—will suffer in the longer term.
Might there be an impact on the number of staff who would be employed and therefore their ability to maintain the network at a standard that the customers would expect?
Yes. That is probably focused more on the speed and scale of what are wrongly called efficiency savings. The savings that have been made so far have been made in two ways predominantly. The first is the economies of scale that the creation of Scottish Water created. Those have come at a price to local accountability, but nonetheless, any economies of scale make savings. The second way of making savings is to introduce new technology, because, when new plant and equipment are introduced, they tend to use fewer staff than were previously needed. We accept that entirely; whether the service was in public, private or any other hands that would happen as a result of the technological changes.
I thank the three of you for coming along this morning. We have noted your support for the retention of domestic customers in the public sector and your criticisms of the proposed split in Scottish Water. We have tested some of those issues on other witnesses and I suspect that we will test them on subsequent witnesses today and later. I thank you for putting your representations in writing before the meeting and for being prepared to answer our questions.
Meeting suspended.
On resuming—
We move on to our second panel. I welcome Nigel Bromley, who is the chief executive of Gemserv, and Ceri Jones, who is the regulation and competition director with Northumbrian Water and who is here to represent Water UK. We will not invite you to make opening statements; we already have your written submissions, for which I thank you.
Quite a lot of the Water UK submission deals with estimates of retail costs, and much of it is disquieting. Could you expand on that? You state:
Yes, I am happy to. Perhaps it is worth saying a few words first on why the appropriate wholesale cost is so important before I move on to the numbers themselves.
I will ask a daft-lassie question. What is meant by retail costs? What is included under that budget heading?
That is actually a good question, because that is one of the issues that might determine the answer we are looking for. Broadly speaking, the retail function would not include production and distribution. Essentially, it relates to billing and customer service costs. However, the reason why your question is a good one is that, in order to answer it properly, we would need to define clearly which functions rest with wholesale and which rest with retail. For example, in relation to metering, we would need to be clear about where the metering function lay. Depending on the definitions that were used, it could lie on either side. Clearly, that has an implication for the cost allocation. If you were seeking to separate the functions, it would be important to be extremely clear about what precisely you were including in the retail function.
That is helpful.
I am still not totally clear about this. If the retail function is billing and meter reading, why would it be more expensive in one area of the country than in another? How would it be possible to cherry pick?
It would be easier to service some customers than others. For example, the level of bad debt might be higher among one group of customers than it is among another. I accept that the cherry-picking issue might be a greater concern in situations involving common carriage, for example, but that is not part of the proposals in Scotland.
I am aware of that but I did not think that the cherry picking of retail services was an issue. However, I understand what you said about levels of bad debt and so on.
The issue is more likely to be related to customer characteristics than to geography.
The first page of the Water UK submission made a great deal of play about the difference between the regime in England and Wales and that in Scotland in relation to public health risks and common carriage. In particular, it flagged up the issue of a potential legal challenge. I would like you to expand on that and talk about the reasons why there might be such a legal challenge. Would you accept that it is entirely legitimate for the Scottish Executive to come to a different view from that held by the drinking water inspectorate in England and Wales?
We were not trying to comment on the correctness of the proposals; we were commenting that it is interesting that a different conclusion has been reached. It is likely that some commentators will point to those differences and it is possible that some parties might want to challenge the fact that a different conclusion has been reached.
So your view is that a public health issue would not be a relevant consideration for the Competition Commission.
The view that has been taken in England and Wales is that some serious issues need to be resolved. That is why much effort has been exerted to put in place a licensing regime that will ensure that any new entrant must meet the same standards as the incumbents. The industry felt strongly about that.
I appreciate that that is the DWI's view in England and Wales and I dare say that it is a welcome view from the industry, but a different perspective is taken north of the border, where the public health issues are felt to outweigh any competition issues, so I am interested in your take on whether competition should override the perceived public health concern in Scotland.
Ultimately, that is an issue for the lawyers. I understand that the public health issue is emotive. It received much debate in England and Wales before the DWI reached its conclusion.
When the minister appears before us, we can ask him the same questions. The committee's job is to scrutinise the bill and to reach its own view on the public health issue and on whether the Scottish Executive has got it right in the bill. We can follow up the question with several witnesses.
Gemserv is not in a position to comment on public health issues. We are primarily involved in and can advise on implementation of legislation.
Does Roseanna Cunningham have a follow-up question, or is that enough for the moment?
I could go on for a bit, because the potential players do not necessarily come from the UK. We could go quite a long way in querying how widely we should impose the same standards. A French water company might have to deal with a completely different standard in France from that here, for example. However, perhaps we should move on.
I was just giving you the final say.
We should flag the matter up as an issue to explore.
We will return to it.
I will ask Mr Bromley about the part of his submission on the avoidance of undue influence. Your submission says:
No. On the contrary, that would enable competition. We have been involved since the beginning of the liberalisation of energy and we have a lot of experience. From our perspective, it is wholly appropriate to go down the route of separating Scottish Water retail and Scottish Water wholesale. It is important that Scottish Water retail starts off on the same footing as any new entrant competitor. To give an example of the issues that we allude to in that comment, if the governance structure is such that Scottish Water wholesale is responsible for managing switching processes, it is possible that it would take one, two or three years, or even more, for business relationships between people in the two Scottish companies to have faded away. We saw some examples of such communication, and therefore of advantage being given to certain companies, in the early days of energy liberalisation. We advocate that the governance regime and the rules associated with switching should be in the control of all players, and that there should be no chance of Scottish Water wholesale tilting the rules, perhaps subliminally, in favour of the incumbent company.
Further on in your submission, you say that
There have been examples in Europe in which companies have been ring fenced and have had to move into separate premises, with movement of staff to different places. There are rules in energy whereby staff who move from a distribution business to a supply business that is owned by the same company must take garden leave for six to eight weeks; the rules about companies that own both distribution businesses and retail businesses are quite strict. That situation still prevails in energy; some of the large energy companies have evolved two separate companies from ring-fenced businesses that were within one company. That is a comment on the evolution of the water industry rather than on where it should start. It might take longer to form separate companies than to ring fence businesses.
Is forming a separate company more onerous than ring fencing a company? Are there extra costs involved? What is the difficulty with moving from one to the other?
I do not think that there is a difficulty. One precedes the other—that is our comment. I agree with the remarks that have been made about the proper allocation of resources and costs to each of the businesses.
In your submission, you say:
There could be more direction in the bill on how it is to be implemented. There are roles for independent organisations that are not connected with Scottish Water. Such organisations would enable the process of competition to work better—for example, it would be useful for a small organisation to control the database of which customers are owned by which retailer.
Would that system run parallel to Scottish Water and the various water retail companies?
It would not be a parallel system; it would be a master system that would determine which business customer is with which supplier.
It would not be held by Scottish Water.
No. The point is that it should not be held by Scottish Water; it should be held by another organisation or body. That would be perceived by new entrants to be fairer. Further, in the development of switching rules, it would mean that that organisation could be formed by a group of companies who are competing in the marketplace. They could collectively own a small subsidiary that manages the switching process. What surprised a lot of people in energy is that the systems and processes are not necessarily that simple. I suggest that it is worth examining what happened with some of the switching arrangements in energy.
Are not the points that you raise just legal issues between someone's supplier and a future supplier? In the energy market, it does not work in the way that you suggest it should in the water market. If you have a dispute with your energy company and want to transfer to someone else, you cannot go to a third party who will arbitrate the situation; you simply have to deal with it. Why do you suggest that a different approach be taken in relation to the water industry?
Your description of the situation is not quite correct. In the energy sector, there are arbitration organisations that are collectively owned by competitors in the market—
They will arbitrate for businesses rather than domestic customers, presumably.
That is right.
So you are suggesting that we should set up new structures on top of what is already in the bill.
I think that new structures will evolve in any case once the detail of the change-of-supply process is worked through. I have suggested that the bill could be more directional with regard to the way in which those structures are set up.
On the subject of the independent policeman, are you suggesting that that role would be played by the water industry commission, the Department of Trade and Industry or the Competition Commission—basically, someone else again?
The independent policeman would certainly be directed by the water industry commission. The example that I was talking about in the submission related only to business separation, where it was found necessary to direct companies to appoint an independent business separation compliance officer. That might be an interim arrangement. For example, for the first year, Scottish Water could be directed to appoint a separation compliance officer to provide assurance to the commission that it was ring fencing the businesses appropriately and playing fair.
I would like to get a bit more information about the registration authorities that have evolved in the energy market. Did you say that groups of competitors had set them up in order to facilitate switching between them?
Yes.
So, for the customer, where does undue influence come into the situation?
It is quite appropriate for companies to meet to make arrangements for the market to work well. In fact, if companies do not have a formalised approach to communicating with one another when customers transfer between them, that could inhibit competition.
Is not a customer who wants to switch in or out of that group of competitors at a disadvantage, in that case?
The idea behind having a formalised approach to switching processes is to ensure that the process is smooth.
Is that not afforded for in the bill already? Do you think that the arrangement that we are discussing should be utterly explicit rather than being something that evolves through custom and practice and depends on entrants to the market having a view on how they want to organise matters? Given that we have experience of how the process works in other industries, should we not set out some sort of arrangement in the bill? It seems quite vague to say that we will see how things work out once a couple of companies have decided what they are going to do.
We are advocating that the commission ensures that companies put in place proper switching arrangements and that the commission gets directly involved in understanding that those processes are clear to new entrants and all parties.
Would Scottish Water retail be part of that, or would only the competitor companies have this arrangement?
Scottish Water would be part of it; however, it should not have undue influence. It should have the same involvement in determining how switching processes work as anybody else. It would have to be involved, as it is important to be able to lose customers as well as to gain customers.
Are you thinking about an independent organisation that would be constituted by a variety of companies? In your submission, you used the term "authority", which makes me think of public policy. You are saying that it should not be connected with any retail or distribution business. Is it about the water industry commission having a clear set of rules rather than having another organisation on top of the water industry commission, which merely consists of the companies that are operating in the market? I am trying to tease out exactly what that implies for the way in which the structures will work.
I would view an optimal arrangement as one whereby the commission would direct companies to form an association that would agree the baseline design for the switching process and whereby the commission would oversee a very clearly defined process for changing customers between companies—
—so that there is an agreed set of rules for everybody to ensure that, whether someone is a customer or selling to a customer, everyone knows what the score is when they get involved in the contractual relationship.
That is right. It is really about ensuring how things operate behind the scenes; it is not a customer-facing activity. The customer should be able to agree to a new contract with a new supplier, then the processes behind the scenes should be effected as smoothly as possible. Without a defined business process for that, there could be delays in transfers or possibilities of dual billing and some of the problems that we have seen with the energy companies. The transfer of customers between the energy companies has evolved significantly over the past 10 years. It is important that the lessons that have been learned in that market are transferred to the proposed water retail market in Scotland, England and Wales.
I presume that the situation is slightly less complex because we are not talking about domestic customers but focusing on businesses. Getting that right is a fairly definable task.
Yes, it is more easily defined.
In your submission, you talk about the governance framework and transfer protocols. I presume that those will be functions of the independent body that you are talking about. I wonder what the cost will be of the industry organising itself and setting up new structures. Is there an advantage to that for business customers? Surely, all the costs will be on the customers themselves.
That would not be a function of the body that I am talking about, and the body would not necessarily have to employ many staff, if any. The body would be a place where a defined process was agreed that everybody would sign up to. You are possibly extrapolating more than the comment in our submission intended.
But you talk about multiparty agreements. Those will need to be brokered and I presume that there will need to be monitoring of the agreements. I cannot envisage there being no costs associated with the commission.
There will definitely be some costs; however, it is our view that formalising the process and ensuring that it is visible and that everybody can evolve it will, ultimately, cost less than the money that could be wasted through having ill-defined processes and misunderstandings between companies.
I want to move to a more general, philosophical point. I have been listening to your arguments about opening up the water industry to competition—at least to the limited form of competition with which the bill deals. From your experience in England and Wales, can you tell me whether objectives such as spatial planning and economic development are served by competition and, if so, how?
The competitive regime in England and Wales is still in its infancy and it is probably too early to say how effectively it will work and what impact it might have on planning issues and so on. I would not immediately regard such issues as being insurmountable. It is probably fair to say that they have not had a high profile to date in discussions in England and Wales.
I will step back even further and make a philosophical point. I was interested in David Watson's evidence earlier, particularly his comments about a bunch of economists and economic rationales making certain things happen. Back in the mid-1980s, the Central Electricity Generating Board was a monolithic organisation that was directed towards building bigger and bigger power stations—that seemed to be what the CEGB wanted to do. The advent of privatisation and liberalisation in the energy market changed not only the deal for customers, but the whole strategic planning of the market; indeed, it led to the rapid transformation of the sourcing of gas by power stations for electricity. People can comment that it was not competition but a change of fuel supplies that led to a drop in prices, but without faster-moving, enlightened management trying to work in a competitive market, the gas stations would have been built later and the impact on the environment would have been felt later.
It seems to be the political will to keep Scottish Water, by and large, as a public utility in Scotland. Therefore, your experiences are not helpful to me at the present time in finding out whether competition has helped spatial planning, economic development or social justice. Your comments are interesting, but not necessarily relevant to the bill.
I think that I responded to the wider, philosophical question that you put.
Members can read the Official Report afterwards and draw their own conclusions.
You mentioned the basic customer transfer process that you devised. How widely is that being used across England and Wales?
Very defined processes in gas and electricity operate across the whole market.
So that system is widely used. It has been adopted.
Yes.
That is the case in the energy sector, but there is no equivalent at this stage in the water sector. Only when the new legislation takes effect next year will we start to see customers changing suppliers. The current proposal is that the incumbent will manage that process. There is no proposal for a central registration body. At this stage, Water UK does not see any particular requirement for such a body.
So you are giving us conflicting advice about the benefits of central registration.
We clearly have a different opinion on that issue. It is certainly Gemserv's perspective that the incumbent should not be responsible for holding the ring for customer transfers and registration processes.
Statistics show that Scots are reluctant to change companies, whether their electricity company or their gas company—or possibly even their water company. Do you think that companies will be queueing up to compete with Scottish Water retail?
It is difficult to say. I think that some companies will want to do so. A similar question would arise in England and Wales. I think that we will see some new entrants who wish to test the market. I suspect that the level of competition will be relatively modest—at least, initially. That will probably be true on both sides of the border. That is one reason why we think that it is important that the processes are simple, straightforward and cost effective. We will find out only by testing the water. Our view is that the level of competition will probably be relatively modest and grow relatively slowly.
That seems a good point at which to end this series of questions. I thank you both for answering a broad range of questions, including detailed, pernickety ones. I thank you for giving us your written evidence in advance, which helped us to focus our questions.
Meeting suspended.
On resuming—
We kick off with our third panel this morning, which represents Scottish Water. We have with us Professor Alan Alexander, who is Scottish Water's chair; Dr Jon Hargreaves, who is the chief executive; and Douglas Millican, who is the finance director. You will note that we have amassed questions in the past couple of weeks. If we can remember them, we will direct them at you. As with other witnesses, I thank you for providing written evidence in advance. Rather than asking you to repeat that, we will go straight to our questions.
The bill does not include duties to ensure that water is used efficiently. That issue is regulated differently in England and Wales. Will that inconsistency affect water conservation in Scotland under the new bill? What are your thoughts on that?
I will say something in general, after which Jon Hargreaves will go into the detail. One must see the bill in the context of the other legislation under which we operate. As members know, under the primary legislation that established Scottish Water, we have a statutory duty to promote sustainability. We in Scottish Water have interpreted that on the broad rather than the narrow definition of sustainability, so that it covers efficient water use as well as the way in which water is supplied, charged for and so on in the Scottish economy. My view is that the bill is not the right vehicle to enlarge on that duty. Steps can be taken on water conservation, but this is not the right bill for that.
The Scottish Environment Protection Agency is certainly concerned about the matter, because it—and you—must deal with the physical loss of water.
Indeed.
I will expand on Alan Alexander's answer and try to help the member. Water efficiency has impacts on two fronts: one is in the house or the factory and the other is in our pipes. We separate those two matters. It is true that for some time in England and Wales targets have been placed on companies to reduce leakage in their systems. One interesting aspect of that is that a much higher proportion is on the customer side than anybody thought before the process started.
That only partly answers my question, because I am interested in what encouragement people are given to conserve water and in the measure of the effectiveness of that.
Do you mean encouragement through their charges?
Yes.
I think that all members know that our regulator feels pretty strongly about standing charges and feels that charges should reflect costs. In economic terms, he is right: 80 per cent of our costs are fixed and his view is therefore that a large proportion of a bill should be fixed. From a sustainability point of view, a fairly reasonable argument is that that inhibits people from saving water.
So the bill will not increase the efficient use of water.
As Alan Alexander said, it does not set out to do that.
Leakage targets are one of the sustainability indicators that you might choose to use. You would probably not want them to be included in the bill, but you want to be active on a range of other aspects of sustainability in relation to the economy, social justice and other environmental targets. Is there a place for sustainable development in the bill? Should it define the role of the new water commission more stringently? If you do not want leakage targets in the bill, how do you want the bill to address sustainable development? Where do the responsibilities lie to push you towards action on such targets?
To return to my original answer, the first thing is for us to produce and consult on a sustainability policy—as we have done—and to implement it. Whether or not there are to be further statutory obligations on Scottish Water in that area—I do not comment on whether that would be right or wrong—the Water Services etc (Scotland) Bill is not the bill in which to do that, because it is about regulation and competition. That is not to say that there is no case for such obligations.
We have a legal obligation on sustainability, but the regulatory process in Scotland does not specifically require the regulator to take it into account. The minister can do that under the bill through his direction; we welcome the fact that the minister will direct policy in the water industry in a much clearer way than in the past, but it would be useful to us, and therefore to Scotland, for that to be mirrored by the regulator. One of the difficulties that we face is that if an obligation is placed on us but we are not funded to deliver it—as we have seen with development constraints in the past four years, which were not highlighted at the time—we end up with a lot of energy being expended in argument about why the work is not being done. If we are not funded to do work on an obligation, we cannot do it. The obligation must be matched with the ability to fund it.
As Jon Hargreaves mentioned, the bill provides for ministers to set out periodic directions to the water industry commission when undertaking strategic reviews of charges. We are pleased to see that in the bill. As for the clear operation of the whole industry, given the role of ministers in setting policy, the role of the commission in undertaking charging reviews and the role of Scottish Water in delivering, the direction function needs to be clearly specified, so that there is no ambiguity on the part of the commission in calculating prices for Scottish Water. It is clear from ministers' policy objectives, whether they concern sustainability or economics or both, that we are being funded, ultimately, to deliver those objectives. The issue is about clarity of roles and responsibilities.
Do you believe that those are clear in the bill?
They are reasonably clear. Whether that clarity could be strengthened further might be worthy of debate.
It is worth pointing out that there are other ways in which to bear down on issues such as leakage. Let us consider the biggest single capital project that is currently under way: the water treatment plant at Mugdock. The costings for that assumed a substantial reduction in the amount of leakage that we would tolerate in Glasgow, because that would reduce the capital cost and the operating cost. We build such considerations in where we can.
Does anyone else want to follow up on the issue of sustainable development and sustainability?
Yes.
It seems that everybody in the committee wants to come in on that. For the avoidance of doubt, and to reassure members, I have allocated a relatively generous slot for the Scottish Water witnesses. I knew that we would be working through a number of issues this morning and I want to ensure that we finish each one. I ask colleagues to keep indicating if they want to come in on a particular issue. Otherwise, I will move on to the next one.
We dealt with this subject previously, so you do not need to go to any great length to answer this question. I would still like to ask it, however. How important is it, particularly in the non-domestic sector, that the charges that are levied actually reflect the service that is provided? Do you believe that the introduction of retail competition will help to deal with the imbalances that exist at the moment? In particular, will it help smaller businesses that believe that they are being overcharged for water?
The introduction of retail competition will not do that. However, if we get it right, using the result of the consultation on charges, that will be a way in which to tackle the issue. As you heard from Mr Jones, what we are talking about is a relatively small element of the total bill—whether it is 4 per cent or 10 per cent. The costs do not go down to nothing, as the competitors have costs themselves. What is profit and what is real cost is debatable.
The reason that I asked that question was to open up a broader concept. My concern is that the form that the bill takes will result in the provision of a system that is essentially policy led rather than demand led. That covers both the domestic provision of sewerage services and the problems that I believe Roseanna Cunningham will go on to deal with in relation to development constraint. Do you believe that the bill provides adequately for appropriate demand-led development within the Scottish Water system or does it lead us down an alley where policy will be the main driver?
I take it that you are referring to demand for new services and connections to the system.
That is one of the points, but we could generalise and talk about the balance that might exist between policy-led and demand-led development of the industry.
The bill provides a framework for decisions to be made on the back of the "Paying for Water Services 2006-2010" consultation about who should pay for extensions to the network; views were expressed about that earlier. There are big costs attached to resolving development constraints. There is a real issue about the extent to which that burden should be borne by current customers or by those who are creating the new demand—developers or new customers—and the bill provides a mechanism to deal with that.
The point that Alex Johnstone raised is important. I do not agree that there is necessarily a clear dichotomy between the industry being policy led and being demand led. It is really a question of how policy reflects demand. Development constraints, for example, require choices to be made. The other point that frames much of this discussion is that, whatever happens to the bill, until a mature market is created the business will continue to be strongly regulated. There is a sense in which the pressure of regulation will be more important until the market is established. I do not want to guess how long it will take for there to be a mature market, but it has certainly taken a long time in other liberalised utilities.
This example might colour our attitude to the process. Do you agree that in going down a demand-led route in relation to sewerage provision where constraints exist, that the appropriate course of action is to load the costs on to the developer? However, to ensure that the development of sewerage systems is policy led, the Government has to come up with money to support it.
There always comes a moment in these evidence sessions when I say that members are leading us into matters of public policy and I think we just arrived there. I will try not to duck the question. Given the costs that need to be incurred to deal with things such as development constraints, particularly in the waste water network, we have to have a way of deciding how those costs are shared. They could be met through general taxation, by Scottish Water customers and they could be, as your question suggested, loaded in some way towards those who will benefit most directly, which would be developers. However, that is a matter that should come out of the "Principles of Charging for Water and Wastewater" consultation. Whatever is determined, we as a delivery company will implement it.
The committee made a good point during Dave Watson's evidence. The work that we have done over the past two years on constraints in general, whether for water or sewerage, shows a clear difference between building 300 houses on the outskirts of Edinburgh, selling at £250,000 to £300,000 a house, and building a small development in the Highlands. The situation is not exclusive to the Highlands; it exists in Dumfries and Galloway, Ayrshire and most of the rural areas of Scotland where Government policy requires councils—rightly so, one could argue—to provide low-cost housing. Even when low-cost housing is not being provided, there is an issue about the number of houses that are being built on a specific plot.
I am sure that it does. The entire committee probably wants to ask you about that.
I am glad that we have got on to this general area and I was relieved to hear some of your comments, especially in connection with the enormous range of organisations that could come under the umbrella of the term "developer". I was interested to hear you say that Scottish Water should not dictate housing policy in Scotland. In many areas, however, that is in effect happening right now: Scottish Water is dictating housing policy in Scotland. As the MSP for Perth, I have a particular, recent interest in what has been happening. Under the single umbrella term of developer, Scottish Water has imposed development embargoes the length and breadth of Scotland. However, a developer could be a massive developer, such as the one behind the Gleneagles west development, or it could be a small one such as Perthshire Housing Association. Do you agree that it would be completely inequitable to apply the same standard to both kinds of developer?
Can I say yes and no? In policy terms, it would be inequitable to apply the same standard. I grant you that absolutely. If the same standard is applied, there is a danger that any kind of social housing development will be squeezed out. I said "and no," because when Scottish Water has to object to a development, we must do so on the ground of not condoning the breaching of our consents. There is a sense in which that is not sensitive to whether the development is one house or a major development. However, you are right in what you say, because a distinction must be made in policy terms; otherwise, as Jon Hargreaves said, we get to the point where we become the planning authority for the whole of Scotland, which is not what we are here to do.
Is development constraint affected in any way by the bill—positively or negatively—either in the short, the medium or the long term? That is a bit of a multiple-choice question, but I am sure that you understand what I mean. Will the bill's overall impact be positive or negative in respect of development constraint? Will we get more development constraint or less as a result of the bill? Either way, might we see that impact in the short, the medium or the long term?
The answer is that it depends on the regulations. As I understand it, how the primary legislation will actually work will be fleshed out in regulations. The bill has raised—rightly—the issue of development constraint and it is creating the opportunity for a different solution to the current one. However, the regulations will decide how much developers will bear, how much Scottish Water customers will bear and how much the social aspect of development will be dealt with.
The bill would be implemented after the conclusion of the consultation process on the principle of charging and investment, both of which feed directly into the question of how much development constraint can be relieved, and at what cost and what rate. I would regard the bill as broadly neutral as far as changing that situation is concerned. As Jon Hargreaves says, changes can be made in the implementation process and in the regulation process after the bill is passed.
Do you have a rough timescale for that?
We are effectively taking evidence on all three things at the same time: on quality and standards, on the investment framework and on the bill. When we have the minister in front of us, we will be able to put the same sets of questions to him.
There is a clear answer to the question of timescale. We know that our investment programme will cover the next regulatory period of four years, with some indication of where we will go in the four years after that. It is into that context that decisions about how much of the investment bears on development constraints need to be fed. There is very little in our current investment programme that is specifically directed at development constraints although, wherever possible, using the process of design and investment, we try to achieve the relief of a development constraint at the same time that we have to achieve a set of outputs under a regulatory settlement. There is little in the bill that specifically addresses that, however.
This is a pretty complex argument. I have been on the other side of the debate and have seen people suffer because there was not a development constraint and their houses were flooded. There was then a difficulty with your being able to secure the resources to provide the solution because of the Q and S II process. How will it help resolve such difficulties, or will it not?
Do you mean the bill?
Yes.
It will come firmly down to ministers' direction to Scottish Water through the regulatory process for investment from 2006 to 2010 to resolve the issues to which you are referring. The money set aside specifically for flood relief, for investment in improving drinking water quality and so on will be allocated in that direction. The bill itself does not impact on that process, although the regulatory process that will determine prices will ultimately be different, because it will be undertaken by a commission rather than by a commissioner. On the face of it, the bill does not alter how much money gets spent on what. That comes under the current extensive consultation process.
When you responded to Roseanna Cunningham, you said that a percentage of the costs for developments should be picked up by Scottish Water. What do you think a reasonable or realistic percentage would be?
As Professor Alexander said, that is a policy decision. If ministers decide that all the costs can be picked up by Scottish Water, then they will all be picked up by Scottish Water. There is not an easy answer to that, although people can have a view on the matter. I have tried to express our view as clearly as possible.
It is worth returning to the point that Alex Johnstone made about demand and public policy. The way in which the Q and S III process will operate means that eventually we will get to the point where ministers will decide what the quantum of investment should be that Scottish Water will be tasked to achieve in its next regulatory period. At that point, our investment programme becomes a zero-sum game, in the sense that the more that is taken out for development constraints, the less there is for everything else—water quality, waste water compliance and so on. That is what makes the decision a public policy decision.
It is interesting that at the moment a number of developers—I have to admit that although they are in rural areas they are in big communities—are quite happy to discuss investing millions of pounds directly in Scottish Water's existing infrastructure to allow their developments to proceed. What they require in return—not unreasonably—is that they bag that capacity. There is an interesting debate along the lines that, although that seems a reasonable way of solving the problem, for how long can we exclude others from taking some of that capacity? In other places, if the developer decides that he does not want to use that capacity and another builder comes along, be it for social housing or whatever, he gets recompense for the money that he has invested in our assets.
Would that capacity be a completely separate water and sewerage system?
No.
So why should someone get exclusive use of something that is going into the public system?
They would not get exclusive use. Let us say that we have a town of 1,000 people, the sewerage system is at capacity—it cannot take another house—and a developer wants to build another 100 houses, which would add another 200 people to the population. We would say that we needed to build a bigger sewerage works and increase the size of the pipe. Let us say that that would cost £1 million, for the sake of argument. The developer would contribute that £1 million, which would allow 100 houses and maybe more to connect to the system. Let us say that he was going to phase that development over five years by building first 30 houses, then more and more over time, which is what tends to happen. He would say to us, "I'll pay you that £1 million so I can add these extra houses, but I'm going to add them over five years. What I don't want to have happen is that you spend £1 million with a view to creating that capacity, I build 30 houses and then find that Professor Alexander's company comes along and wants to build 50 houses and you give him that capacity, which I have paid for."
May I take you back a step and ask whether that is the right approach? Historically, local councils used to take decisions on the long-term planning policy for a settlement, based on the potential long-term investment costs. Let us suppose that we are talking about a development of 1,000 houses. Surely councils should weigh up the relative merits and costs of that settlement against those of a neighbouring or different settlement. Councils might want affordable housing. In Edinburgh, for example, the average house costs £250,000—it is not an affordable house, but the price reflects the market rate. What happens to the people who cannot afford 250 grand and need affordable private housing, rather than social housing provision?
I am pretty certain that in all the cases that we are currently dealing with discussions are taking place with developers and councils. The developments are part of councils' development plans, some of which include low-cost housing because councils insist on that. Members will be aware of a fairly famous example at Garthamlock in Glasgow, which has attracted a lot of publicity. That situation was resolved through the process that I described, but the process has involved working closely with Glasgow City Council.
The interesting point about the Garthamlock example is that by putting money into relieving the problem, Glasgow City Council was acting—in a sense—as a surrogate developer in exactly the same way as a private developer might act, as we described. It is possible. However, I emphasise Jon Hargreaves' point: one of the great problems that we face in Scotland is that we do not do joined-up government well. If we could join things up and get the cycles right, it might be easier to bear down on the issue.
We will capture that thought and take up the matter with the minister.
Perhaps it is time to move away from that interesting topic, but I take issue with the suggestion that the matter has not been raised. I distinctly remember raising the matter with the minister in relation to rural housing development when we discussed the Water Environment and Water Services (Scotland) Bill. SEPA raised the matter then, too. I was extremely disappointed that not enough resources were provided for rural housing development.
Whether we are dealing with economic regulation or customer relations, the general point is that we need absolute clarity about how the system works. My view, which I think my colleagues and board share, is that there is a lack of clarity because we have an economic regulator who is also by statute the customer champion, and we also have water customer consultation panels, which are intended to canvass customers' collective, rather than individual, views. If we move towards a commission rather than a commissioner—which the bill proposes and which, as our submission says, we support—the question arises of where customer issues should go in that structure. We must be absolutely sure and clear about who is responsible for what.
Do you have any thoughts about who should be responsible?
The panels have been a success. When we talk to customers throughout the country, we find that the panels are well respected for their ability to capture collective views and feed them into the various processes, whether that is through consultation or directly to the WIC. However, at present the panels do not have any teeth and they have only one member of staff plus the convener and the members. I do not want to put additional costs on customers, who pay for the WIC and the panels through their Scottish Water bills, but by strengthening and clarifying the panels' role, customers will have a more direct voice.
Is that because there is no intimate link between the general public and the water consultation panels? It could be that the public do not know that they exist or what their role is.
It is partly that and partly the fact that, if you have a complaint about how Scottish Water is operating, the water customer consultation panel has no locus on that matter at all. Jon Hargreaves is absolutely right. I would like the economic regulation to be separated from customer representation in general and specific circumstances. If we are not simply to tear everything up and reconstruct it all from scratch, the only way to do that is to accept that what the bill says about the replacement of the commissioner by a more broadly based commission is right, but something must be done to balance that on the customer side. Since the water customer consultation panel already exists, it would be better to redefine what it is for rather than to reinvent the wheel and come up with an entirely new structure. Further, as Jon Hargreaves says, there is a model for that down south.
I am conscious that we have only another 10 minutes scheduled for this part of the agenda and that we have not yet touched on whether the bill has got the regulatory system right. Earlier, one of our witnesses said that the bill sets you up to fail. Do you agree with that assessment?
Absolutely not. I said earlier, in a different context, that we are essentially the delivery mechanism for water and sewerage services across Scotland. We operate in a regulated environment and we will operate in the way that our regulators tell us to. We have already been operating in a way that has made the industry in Scotland much more efficient now than it was two years ago, and we will continue to do that. Frankly, we do not recognise the concept of failure.
I do not think that our previous witness was criticising Scottish Water. The comment was more to do with the framework of the bill. Given the different roles that Scottish Water has to play, others have raised its long-term stability. The crucial factor seems to be whether the price assumptions that are set at the start enable you to run a stable business in the long term. There is a wider political issue as well as some specific issues.
That is right.
I would quite like a detailed response on the issue.
New risks are created because of the bill. The wholesale business and the new retail business have different risks.
It is useful to have dealt with that in detail, because Nora Radcliffe raised the issue with the previous witnesses. Does she have anything to add?
I seek reassurance on issues such as data requirements and whether the data are robust enough to progress efficiently and effectively. Previous witnesses raised that point. The amount of resources that are put into management information systems are also an issue, because that takes away from fixing pipes and so on. Will the witnesses expand on that?
I think—and I give the water industry commissioner credit for this—that two years ago the Scottish water industry did not know a lot about the condition of its assets, what its customer base was and so on, but an awful lot of effort, and therefore an awful lot of money, has been spent on correcting that deficiency. You cannot run a regulated industry without the correct data. Looking forward into the next period, we will be looking for substantial sums of money to continue building and improving the data. If we do not, we will just go back to where we were. It is a bit like painting the Forth bridge: if you stop painting it for a few years, it costs a lot more to catch up.
On the specific question of whether we have sufficient data to make the separation, it is helpful that the market is not going to open until 2008. The principal data that we need are cost data. If there is clarity on what is wholesale and what is retail, and there is a clear division between the two, we will have a clear view of the costs attributable to wholesale and retail long before 2008. We have a reasonable view now and that is what we are able to give in evidence to the committee. If the definitions of wholesale and retail are clarified, I am confident that the opening of the market in 2008 should not be a problem.
Okay. We are running over time—
I have two more questions.
No, not two extra questions. I want to close this evidence session. We will have to hold back several issues for future witnesses and for the minister, such as debt, pricing and the definitions of wholesale and retail. We will come back to those points in subsequent weeks. I thank the witnesses for being prepared to answer questions for slightly longer than our previous witnesses. It has been extremely useful to us.
Meeting suspended.
On resuming—
Previous
European Issues