Item 2 is to take oral evidence as part of our stage 1 scrutiny of the Land and Buildings Transaction Tax (Scotland) Bill. I welcome to the meeting David Melhuish of the Scottish Property Federation, Michael Levack of the Scottish Building Federation and Mr Philip Hogg of Homes for Scotland. We will move straight to questions, but first I thank you for being here 10 minutes earlier than scheduled. The first item was dealt with much more quickly than had been anticipated, which means that we have even more time to interrogate you.
Just for clarity, I point out that we do not support tax avoidance in any way. If our submission contains the inference that we support tax avoidance in some way, please take my word that that was not the intention.
Other witnesses can also comment. I asked Mr Hogg that question because of what his organisation’s submission says, but other witnesses should feel free to comment. Equally, when I ask other witnesses questions, Mr Hogg should feel free to answer to answer them.
It might be an obvious thing to say, but, as someone who has worked closely with HM Revenue and Customs over many years on a host of initiatives to assist the construction and property sectors in navigating their way through the current complex system, I know that its experts acknowledge that the tax arrangements to do with land, property and construction-related activity are among the most complex tax arrangements that we have. If the bill represents a start in giving us an opportunity to have in Scotland a fair and simple system that avoids unintended consequences and which is simple to operate and to understand, that will be most welcome across the property and construction sectors.
There is sometimes the danger of a knee-jerk reaction to concerns about anti-avoidance. For example, the 15 per cent rules coming in under the current stamp duty land tax will affect everybody involved in residential property for the next two years, including in Scotland, when an investment is made in high-value residential property by a non-natural person. Neither the Scottish Property Federation nor the British Property Federation opposes that idea in principle, but, unfortunately, the legislation has accidentally caught genuine property investment businesses. It has taken three or four months of quite hard work to explain that to officials in HMRC, as Michael Levack indicated. Our argument has been accepted by HMRC and changes will be made, but not in time for the legislation coming into force next month.
Okay. Mr Hogg, you also state in your written submission:
We must take note of the overall economic circumstances. The total number of housing transactions is dramatically lower; it is probably 40 or 50 per cent lower than at the peak in 2007. However, we have a growing population and a growth in the number of households on housing waiting lists, so there is pent-up demand.
But to get the same amount of tax revenue, the number of transactions would have to double. Otherwise, the Scottish Government would lose considerable revenue, which would impact on the services that it provides. What evidence is there that there would be that level of transactions? My understanding is that the banks’ unwillingness to lend and the general economic uncertainty have more of an impact than stamp duty at this level.
We need to widen the discussion beyond just stamp duty land tax. We know that housing transactions have a significant multiplier effect on the overall economy. The housing market generates economic activity and employment. The discussion must be much wider than just looking at the number of housing transactions. We must think more broadly than that and look at the overall economic impact. The transactions in themselves may not create a neutral net effect, but their multiplier effect provides a much greater benefit to the economy. That is why we are keen for there to be some broader thinking.
I do not disagree with that at all, but what I am concerned about is whether the increase in the number of transactions would outweigh the reduction in tax revenue. That is the issue for me.
You have identified the constraint that we are talking about and the uncertainty that arises around it at present. As we understand it, that is still being negotiated between the Scottish Government and the United Kingdom Government. The volatility of this tax makes that a difficult target to achieve with any form of certainty. It is only about two years until the tax comes into force, so time is running out.
We should also consider the volatile nature of returns under the existing tax regime as a result of the current volatility in the property market. There is concern about the overnight reduction to the block grant from the UK Government to the Scottish Government when the new system comes into place. We should consider whether there is a need for some transitional arrangements to ensure that the block grant calculation is done on the most realistic, up-to-date figures.
Yes, indeed. The Finance Committee often comes across that issue when people want more money to be spent but we do not get information on how savings can be found elsewhere.
Yes. The feeling is that, although simplicity in the tax will have a benefit in that the tax will be understandable and clear to everybody, it will not always be fair. In efforts to ensure that, for example, reliefs are introduced for positive purposes or to incentivise certain parts of the market, it is inevitable that a certain amount of further complexity will be introduced.
The more complex the system is, the more chance there is that larger companies, which have the resources and the wherewithal to pay for experts, will find ways to minimise their obligations; small and medium-sized companies that operate in property markets might not get the same benefit. The more complex a system is, the more chance there is that highly paid advisers will come up with systems to try to flout or bend the rules.
Yes. I think that a reason why professionals outside the Scottish Government who work on such matters are so excited about the bill is that the current system does not work effectively and is full of holes, and they think that the bill gives us a chance to address such matters.
May I make a suggestion about how you might get accurate information about the current tax take and what it might be? Our organisations can perhaps work with officials to think about what-if scenarios, based on fairly accurate data that we can get from our members on real activity, rather than theoretical work in the field—you would probably learn more from the other panel members’ organisations.
Thank you. Mr Levack, you talked about simplicity but, in its submission, the Scottish Building Federation made the fairly radical suggestion that
I think that all parts of the construction and property industry are looking for a way of stimulating activity. One tax will not present all the opportunities to provide that stimulus, but it struck us that much more needs to be done on energy efficiency. We would never want to get into a position where we were pitting new build against current stock, but we need to do something to encourage and reward people who are spending money to maintain their buildings and bring existing stock up to more modern standards of energy efficiency.
That was a good example from Michael Levack of my previous point.
This issue is an interesting one that provides the opportunity to push forward on other policy areas. Yesterday, I watched with interest the coverage of the update in Parliament on the carbon emissions targets. The area gives the new homes industry equal measures of concern and opportunity. The Government proposes higher standards for new build, for reasons that we understand. I will not go into the debate on whether those standards are disproportionate, but you will sense from the way that I am speaking that we think that they are.
I will stick with the same subject, with a question for Mr Levack. In his written submission, he describes his proposed scheme as comparable to the system of getting an MOT for the car. That is an interesting analogy, although, of course, the person who pays for an MOT is the owner or user. I congratulate the Scottish Building Federation on at least making a positive suggestion, but I would like to explore it further. Under the proposal, who would pay for the assessment of whether a property is energy efficient?
It would be the owner. I appreciate that, when such proposals are made and no such system is currently in place, everybody will say “Oh. Another tax, another burden.” However, I think that we must reflect on where we have gone as a society over the past 10, 15 or 20 years, particularly when bank finance was readily available. If we consider the existing housing stock, many of us meet friends, family, colleagues and others who have built up little portfolios of property for themselves. However, what seem to be seriously lacking are people being prepared to maintain their buildings. There are all sorts of ramifications from that, including at the worst end—without wanting to scaremonger—major structural faults that can impact on the safety of tenants, people living in or using the properties, and those passing by.
Sadly, of course, the Scottish Government does not control VAT at this moment in time.
It depends whether we look at it as paying more or as paying the published rate but getting relief if certain measures are undertaken to improve the energy efficiency of a building.
I agree with your perspective entirely, but I wonder whether the tax relief proposal would be an efficient way of doing what you describe. My perspective is that people will not look at it in terms of brass tacks. If undertaking the necessary repairs to their home will cost more than their increased tax liability or what they will pay if they do not qualify for a discount, I wonder whether they will they undertake that work.
We could express similar views on energy performance certificates and the reports that are done when people are preparing to sell a property as we have done on zero-carbon homes relief. Perhaps the suggestion that I have called an MOT is just about moving slightly on from where we are.
Thank you very much.
What we have to understand is that we need a housing market in which we have equal movement between all steps on the ladder or all stages of the chain—you can use whichever description you want to.
You refer to the availability of stock, which involves two issues: the current stock and the new stock that comes on line. Your members are in the business of building houses. We have already heard that the current set-up acts as a disincentive to the building of homes that would be valued around the marginal rate. It is clear that the tax regime can influence the building of homes as well as movement between existing stock. Are you saying that the new tax is not likely to affect the construction of new stock in any great way?
Because we do not yet know exactly how the tax system will be structured or what rates will be set, it is almost impossible to answer that question but, from the information that we have and the information that we are aware of, we want to propose a system that does not create blockages and which is fair for all.
It will obviously depend on the final details, but can this form of taxation influence the new-build market as much as the market for existing homes?
It could go both ways; it could incentivise or it could disincentivise.
But it can influence it—I was not really asking about incentivising. I suppose that you have answered the question.
Yes.
Thank you.
I want to pursue one more point about zero-carbon or low-energy housing—or however we are describing it. The point was made to us in a previous evidence session that the standard can be set at one level with people getting relief or some other incentive, but raising the level, which I hope is what we are trying to do, is quite difficult to build into legislation. Would it not be much simpler just to give people a grant and leave the tax outside the zero-carbon issue?
A grant to whom?
The builder, the purchaser or somebody who is adapting their house.
We have to understand the consumer psychology around low-energy or zero-carbon homes—whichever phrase we care to use. As much as all, or most, people seem to think that ensuring energy efficiency is the right thing to do and that we should be going in that direction, we have to face up to the reality that it is very low down the list of new home buyers’ priorities. Most new home buyers do not take a great deal of interest in the energy efficiency of the home. It is taken as a given; they assume that the home is energy efficient.
That would suggest that tweaking SDLT—or, rather, land and buildings transaction tax—would have virtually no impact, given that energy efficiency is already low down the priority list and we are talking about varying 5 or 6 per cent.
That is where the dilemma lies. Although construction costs will increase progressively to achieve zero-carbon or low-energy homes, the buying public and the lenders do not place any value on energy efficiency. For example, let us take home A, which is built today and is super energy efficient, and home B, which is right next door and is 100 years old. The valuers and the lenders will value them on an equitable basis, using normal comparables such as the size of the home; they will not reflect the energy efficiency of the home.
Would it be a big incentive if someone knew that they would pay less for their energy bill?
No. The reality is that it makes very little difference to the majority of home buyers. I know that that might sound odd and contradictory, but it is a fact. Our members who have undertaken serious marketing or other activity to try to sell on the basis of energy efficiency tell us that it does not feature particularly highly in new home buyers’ considerations. Buyers assume that the home will be energy efficient and that there will be lower bills, but that is not in itself a reason to purchase.
Right. I will move on to another area. The suggestion was made earlier—I think it is in some of the papers—that a simpler system would be popular, but there was also a suggestion that we do not want to move too far away from the UK system in case the developers get confused. How do we balance those suggestions? Are you saying that if the system is much simpler we do not mind if it moves far away from the UK system, or are you saying that you would rather have a bit more complexity if that meant that it was closer to the UK system?
The view that I have expressed this morning is that we want simplicity, but I am saying that from the point of view of a trade body representing builders—the construction part of the sector—and indeed solely from a Scottish point of view. Without being flippant, I would say that I am not particularly bothered what happens south of Hadrian’s wall or whether there is a difference. The point that I made was that, if the system is complex, small and medium-sized operators in this market might not have the wherewithal to employ very expensive consultants to navigate their way through it.
Okay, that is helpful. You are quite clear that you want a simple system. Do the other witnesses agree?
We fall into the realms of perception here—that is a problem. Major investors on the commercial side of things know that they have had a top rate of stamp duty land tax of 4 per cent, which has been in place for quite a long time, and it is at the same threshold for the various kinds of property that they deal with. If those investors are told that the system is potentially moving to 4.4 per cent but that that is not quite the whole picture because the tax will be levied on a progressive basis, so that they might only pay 4 per cent above £250,000 and 3 per cent above £150,000 or so, they start asking what that means for their values. That takes us into the realms of perception, which would be a slight concern.
Another idea that has been mentioned a few times is making the system competitive—we hear phrases such as “incentivising the market”. Does that basically mean that you would prefer a lower tax?
Philip Hogg identified some reasons for that earlier, which very much apply to the commercial world. In a sense, the plc boards have always been a dominant player in Scotland. Those boards make decisions on where to make their investments, and nowadays those decisions can fall on ever smaller margins. I am not saying that the tax rate is the one decision breaker—it is one among a number of factors—but our members want to be as competitive as possible in the UK with regard to the proposed tax.
“Competitive” means different things to different people. This might not be the case in property, but in some sectors having an educated workforce is seen as a competitive advantage. We might face a choice of an educated workforce and higher tax or a less educated workforce and low tax. Are you neutral on that? Do you have a preference one way or the other?
The proposed tax will only ever be one among a range of factors. The employment workforce, the quality of life for that workforce, the attractions that bring people to Scotland, connections, locations and accessibility will all be big issues in the decision whether to locate in Scotland or, say, Newcastle. All we are saying is that, if it comes down to the margin and a small percentage or a few points of a tax can make a significant difference, a higher rate might lead to a decision for an investment to go elsewhere.
Without wishing to sound flippant, I guess that I am speaking on behalf of home buyers and the general public, and none of us, intuitively, wants to pay any more tax than we need to. It is hard to imagine anybody who would not want to do anything that would reduce our tax. I refer back to—
I totally disagree with that. There are a lot of people who want better services and are prepared to pay more tax. Yours is one view, but I do not think that it is necessarily right across the population.
If I can finish my point, I was going to say that if people paying less tax in stamp duty, for instance, stimulates much broader activity in the wider economy, which generates tax income or other income for the Government, that needs to be explored. Creating jobs, taking people off welfare and creating economic activity might—I say only might—have a net greater effect, and some exploration could perhaps be done into that.
And might that be linked with higher income tax to compensate?
Why?
You said that if we boosted the economy we would get more tax. We would need to bring in more tax somehow in order to compensate for the loss of land and buildings transaction tax.
If it creates jobs and takes people off benefits, they will be paying income tax, which could have a net positive effect, as well as there being other benefits such as increased take from corporation tax as businesses become more productive.
With regard to trying to stimulate some activity in the construction sector, it is important that there is a discussion not only of the level of tax but of the timing of how the tax is paid over the lifetime, as it were, of a major commercial transaction. I am not qualified to go into the nitty-gritty of the issue—that might be more David Melhuish’s field.
Michael Levack touched on the timing of the publication of the rates and the thresholds of LBTT. The Government’s current position is that those will be published in September 2014, when the draft budget is published, and will impact from April 2015. Presumably, your members want those rates to be published as soon as is practicable—today or tomorrow, even. Being objective about it, what do you think is a fair and reasonable date for the publication of at least the top rate, if not everything else? Is September 2014 okay? Is it too late?
Some of our members are developers as well as contractors, but I will speak only from personal experience. I would say that people who take views on larger commercial transactions, which can take years to get the first shovel in the ground, would think that the length of time from September 2014 to April 2015 is not particularly long, particularly if there is a more radical shift in the look of the scheme and the structure of the tax. We would prefer there to be a minimum of 12 months between the publication and the impact, and if we could get towards 18 months, that would be preferable.
Do other panellists have fixed views on that?
The financial, legal and process time for a typical home purchase—if there is such a thing—is typically three months. That is the usual length of time between someone signing a registration form and them getting the keys to their new home. Of course, you have to add in time for the home-search process that comes before that, when people are looking around to find a property that they want. Therefore, it would not be unrealistic to suggest that a typical timeframe for the process, starting from when someone considers that they want to move and ending when the transaction is completed, is 12 months.
Does the SPF have a view?
I would say that deals and transactions that might take place two years away—certain high-value and major development investments—are probably being considered right now. As early as possible an indication of what the top rate will be would be helpful.
The SPF’s paper raises concerns about licence agreements potentially being caught by the tax. Can you expand on that point?
I believe that HMRC has considered the licence arrangements a number of times and veered away from that. The key problem is the sheer scope of licences that might be caught or not caught, or might be caught unintentionally. A lot of licence agreements can be done for perhaps seasonal reasons, such as kiosks and other facilities for Christmas in shopping centres.
That is helpful.
For us, the concern is to do with forward funding, when we try to attract institutions into supporting development. Again, that relates to the well-known comments about the lack of debt finance for property development and investment right now. The institutions are seen as an alternative source of finance, but our concern is that the measures that are proposed in the bill could constrain that activity severely. We will certainly be looking to take up that issue.
Homes for Scotland mentioned sub-sale relief in its written submission. Mr Hogg, do you want to expand on that?
Yes. Our paper mentioned a lack of clarity on that relief. At the point of writing the paper, I had not seen any of the information that you mentioned. I am not aware of that, so I am not exactly sure where we are on the issue.
Part-exchange schemes could be caught under that measure. In effect, the property would be taxed twice.
Finally, I return to Philip Hogg and Homes for Scotland. Another relief that you touched on in your written submission was registered social landlord relief, which I think you thought ought to be broadened slightly to reflect the current marketplace. Again, will you expand on that?
The residential property market is undergoing fairly significant changes in tenure. To put the issue into context, traditionally, the market tended to be polarised between people living in social rented properties and owner-occupiers. Because of the lack of availability of mortgages in recent years and the other issues to do with the property market that we have heard about, we have found that a much more fragmented range of tenures has come on board, including shared ownership, shared equity and mid-market rental. To stay in business, many developers and home builders have had to rejig their business models and provide a much broader range of tenures, so the polarisation has blurred in many respects.
The calculation of how much money should be taken from the block grant in 2015 because it is assumed that that is what the existing tax brings in will be crucial.
The £65 million figure includes cases in which people have bought leases or leases have been assigned, so around £45 million of the figure is, in a sense, a transaction to buy a lease, because someone needs to get out of a lease arrangement at the time. Even then, I think that revenue closer to £25 million was suggested as being attributable to leases at that stage of the consultation. More recent figures have been published, because there have been further extrapolations of the HMRC data, and the figure is now a bit closer to £16 million or £17 million. On actual leases themselves, we are talking about around £16 million or £17 million.
Does anyone else want to comment?
I do not have the figures to hand, but I remember that when the announcement was made that the power would be moving to the Scottish Government I tried to do some research and get the figures. The figures were not readily available, and the information that I got—I think that it was probably more than a year ago—was not particularly current, because there was quite a time lag. I will dig out the figures when I get back to the office, and if we have comments I will feed them into the committee.
I have some data here—I am not sure whether it is the data that Michael Levack meant. That data shows a more than 50 per cent reduction in residential transactions in 2010-11, in comparison with 2007-08. The revenue from residential transactions was £340 million in 2007-08; that dropped to £165 million in 2010-11.
So, in that sense, it might not be difficult to get the residential part correct. Will you explain the unusually high commercial sales figure in Q4 2010? It seems to be dramatically higher than the figures for the other quarters that the Scottish Property Federation has specified.
At the end of Q4 2010, we had not re-entered recession. A lot of unusual transactions simply took place at that time. In that quarter alone, the commercial property sales figure—from which the bulk of the revenue would come—was about £832 million. However, in every quarter since then, the sales data from Registers of Scotland has on average been about £400 million. In the last quarter, for which we received the figures just yesterday, sales were £330 million. As an indicator of the revenue that would be obtained, sales figures suggest that, in the years since Q4 2010 and in a number of quarters that ran up to it, the revenue take would have been significantly lower than that in Q4 2010.
My next question will be quite general, given that a lot of the detail has been covered. If we assume that the UK Government gets a credible figure that is more or less correct, I assume—from reading between the lines and reading your submissions—that you would really like a reduction in what is collected.
I will make what is probably a personal point. We have debated the fact that, although it is okay to reduce income from one tax, that must be balanced by something else going up. We all understand that; that relates to balancing the books, which is certainly not easy at the moment.
Are you arguing that we should not have it at all, then?
I am not going to be drawn in to comment on such a ridiculous proposal. There are lots of taxes that we would all like not to pay. I think that we have all recognised in giving our evidence that none of the measures will cure everything. They are part of a wider suite of complementary policies that we hope will stimulate activity in the construction and property sectors. What I am saying is that we should perhaps take the chance in Scotland to establish a closer link with what any money that comes in from LBTT—whatever rate it is set at—will be spent on, so that people understand when they buy a home what the money will go towards.
So you would like a hypothecated tax for—
Yes, rather than the money just going into a pot and people not understanding the connection.
That is a wider argument, but fair enough.
I have two points. First, on the VAT issue, commercially, there would presumably be some kind of revenue, but I suppose that our comment is and always has been that we just think that it is wrong that we have a tax that is based on another tax, so there is double taxation. Secondly, on the relief issue, a lot of those reliefs are in play now, so they are already integral to the forecasts that are made and the revenue that is collected. That will perhaps reduce the concerns about giving money away.
Speaking from a residential perspective and not a commercial one, I note that we are talking about an item that every one of us needs—a roof over our head. It is not a discretionary item—we have to have it. In looking at how we can best put roofs over people’s heads, we need to think about the broader picture. If we make home ownership more difficult and more expensive, people will be forced to look backwards towards the Government or the state providing housing for them. The need has to be met somewhere, so it makes sense to make home ownership available and accessible for those who can afford it and want it, and to enable resources to be directed towards those who choose not to or are unable to buy a home.
On that point, you said earlier in response to John Mason that if we were to reduce the amount of LBTT it will stimulate the economy and there will be fewer people on benefits, but of course this Parliament would take the hit in terms of its revenue; the income tax and VAT that would be generated would go to the UK Government. We would still have a reduction in income, which would mean that we would have to reduce our services, and that is assuming that the balance was equal or even positive. I do not think that any information has been provided to the committee to suggest that a reduction would provide a level of stimulation that would exceed the loss of revenue to the Scottish Parliament.
I certainly would not be able to provide such macro-level statistics and analysis, which are outside the remit of our core skills. However, the work that has been produced in the past shows a multiplier effect of about 2.84, which means that every home that is built creates 2.84 jobs. Logically, if we build homes that people need to live in, it creates jobs, takes people out of unemployment and off benefits, and puts roofs over heads. It is therefore a virtuous circle, in that regard.
Everyone would agree with that view, but we are trying to pin down whether reducing LBTT from 1 per cent to 0.5 per cent will have the effect that you described.
I cannot provide you with that sensitivity of analysis. We do not have it.
We will explore other avenues on that. Thank you.
In earlier evidence sessions, the potential for the new tax was met with a certain amount of enthusiasm. I feel that it will provide opportunity; I think that there was at least a hint of that, if not the use of the actual word, in all the written submissions. However, what I am hearing today is slight nervousness about a change from the UK system. The attitude seems to be “Don’t upset the horses.”
To answer your first question, we have an opportunity to make the progressive system more fair and to remove the slabs. I think I said in my submission that certain homes are just uneconomical to build; there might be legitimate market need for them, but building them just does not stack up economically. There is therefore an opportunity for the progressive system to remove the logjams and the artificial peaks and troughs. As I said earlier, there is also an opportunity to incentivise low-energy, low-carbon homes and to send the right signals to consumers.
I will just add to Philip Hogg’s point. Time and again our organisations have asked the Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors—the valuers—why it cannot reflect energy efficiency improvements in the value of properties. Its answer is that it does not make the market, but reflects it. The point is that people are not attaching a significant enough value to energy efficiency improvements for it to make that decision. I do not know whether the committee will speak to RICS, but I encourage you to do so, because I do not think that you can differentiate taxes on interest in property from the value of the property, and RICS has the valuation professionals. That supports Philip Hogg’s point—the valuations are perhaps not where we would wish them to be in terms of reflecting energy efficiency improvements.
We need to do a lot more on energy efficiency in terms of changing people’s culture and behaviour, in relation both to new build and to existing stock. I mentioned earlier the total lack of impact so far of the green deal; I do not hold out much hope for it changing things. We have to look at every policy that can contribute in some small way to changing the culture in relation to energy efficiency.
Picking up on David Melhuish’s reference to RICS, I point out that one of the five themes of the Government’s sustainable housing strategy, which was published last year, was financial-market transformation—in other words, getting the financial market to reflect energy efficiency in homes. That is exactly the point that David Melhuish was making. When we ask lenders why they cannot value or lend on properties on the basis of their having higher or lower fuel costs or higher or lower energy efficiency, they always respond that there is no evidence that, just because a home has lower running costs, the cash that would be released would or could be used to fund a mortgage repayment. According to them, they cannot factor in that value. Until we break that logjam of new properties being valued at exactly the same rate as old ones, the cost of building new properties will make their construction unviable. We desperately need that financial market transformation to ensure that a property’s running costs are reflected in its value. We are not there yet; I am sad to say that we are long way off. It will take major movement for it to happen but, once it does, it will make the market more reflective, which is why all of our submissions raise the issue.
You mentioned yesterday’s statement on the report about climate change targets. Last week, we had a debate on fuel poverty. The realities will have to be dealt with, and the industry needs to contribute more to changing the culture that allows such things to happen. After all, we are talking about the future. Every other European country is concerned about these issues.
I reiterate that, as we state in our submission, we are broadly supportive of the general direction and theme of the proposed changes.
In fact, the Scottish Building Federation joined forces with the existing homes alliance Scotland to address the very point that Jean Urquhart has made. Actually, we were a founder member of the alliance along with other organisations that look at, for example, fuel poverty. We might seem like odd bedfellows, but we are examining the existing housing stock and work very closely with Government on the issues. This is not just about grant funding; we need to think about a host of issues, including the public perception that has just been mentioned. That said, we are very clear that we do not want to get into a debate and argument about new build versus existing stock; we need measures on both, but they need to be proportionate and to reflect the current economic climate.
For clarification, I note that in the section entitled “Progressive versus slab approach” in his submission, David Melhuish concludes:
I am in no doubt that, administratively, the system will be introduced for both residential and commercial property; the statement simply reflects the fact that most commercial transactions hit the high band. I was more putting a question mark over the necessity for such a move in the commercial sector, given that this kind of progressive system deals with the distortive impact on the residential property world.
That is helpful.
I believe that the Government’s initial consultation asked about the tipping point at which such decisions become more affected by tax. It might become a significant factor in and influence very high-value commercial transactions involving major investors; as I said earlier, it will be one of a range of factors that we need to be careful about. What the differential in any rate is or might be could have significant consequences in, say, £50 million-worth of property transactions; all those factors might start to stack up and, because of the tax cost, an investor might wish to look elsewhere. I repeat the caveat that it will be one of a number of items that will be taken into account, but the pressure on us from investors and developers is to seek at least to match the UK rate to ensure that that kind of differential is put out of play.
I do not have any specific information, but one general theme has arisen in conversations that we have had. First of all, we need to understand that in the new-build market, which I am speaking on behalf of, the total output of new homes in Scotland is heavily dominated by three or four big plc home builders that are based down south. Typically, those major organisations, which as I have said provide a good chunk of the homes that are provided, will at the start of the business year have a fund of £X million to invest in land and will allocate land or spend depending on where they think they might get the best return for their investment and thus satisfy their shareholders. They will then challenge each of their businesses throughout the UK to put forward projects and demonstrate the return on investment for them in what is effectively a tendering process in which the projects that are thought to give the best return on investment secure the funding.
That was helpful.
I thank colleagues for their questions.
I cannot quote those figures offhand.
What will the margins be given the cost of land, labour and whatever in London? Surely the most significant factors will be demand and the ability of banks to lend to prospective buyers.
Costs will be higher, but so will the respective selling prices. The margins are certainly important. In the past two or three years, some national home builders have—rightly or wrongly—withdrawn from activity in Scotland and have decided instead to concentrate their efforts on the south-east, where the market is somewhat more insulated and, indeed, is completely different in that it is directed more towards foreign investors and other forms of available cash.
Thank you for that.
The number of such transactions has very much fallen, but I think that at the moment a figure of £10 million and upwards would differentiate that kind of transaction significantly from high-value residential transactions, which for taxation purposes would be around £1.5 million to £2 million; I believe, for example, that a £2 million transaction triggers the 7 per cent tax rate. Although there are far fewer commercial transactions, they tend to be of much higher value with regard to investment sales.
With regard to the graph in your submission that shows the value of Scottish commercial property sales—which I understand you took from the Registers of Scotland, so you might simply be presenting it as it was presented to you—the quarter-to-quarter presentation of the figures makes it look as if the situation is much more unstable than it turns out to be if you compare the same quarter in different years. Although there has been roughly a 24 per cent reduction in sales over the piece, a comparison between quarter 3 in 2011 and quarter 3 in 2012 shows virtually no difference whatever. Would it not be better to present such figures on an annualised rather than quarterly basis to get a clearer picture of what is actually happening?
Certainly. I can tell you that the situation has stabilised. Before the crash, there would have been about £6 billion-worth of transactions whereas the figure now is a quarter of that, at about £1.2 billion.
It would be interesting to see annualised figures.
We can send them along.
As I have said, I think that they would give the committee a much clearer picture.