Good afternoon and welcome to the Finance Committee's 12th meeting in 2008, in the third session of the Scottish Parliament. I ask everybody to turn off mobile phones and pagers, as they interfere with our broadcasting system.
I am an architect in private practice and a board member with the Scottish Government's advisory group Architecture and Design Scotland. Through that role, I have been involved in working on both sides of the table, with client bodies and as a consultant, in many public procurement projects. I also have the role of Scotland's national health care design champion for Architecture and Design Scotland, which involves working with health boards throughout Scotland and the health directorates to consider how to raise the quality of design in public procurement for health care buildings. That has given me a good insight into the factors that are involved.
My colleague Graham Williams, who is sitting behind me, and I are divisional directors in Mott MacDonald's programme and project management wing. Mott MacDonald is a global management, engineering and development consultancy. Our paper reflects our experience in capital investment projects, including engineering infrastructure projects and public buildings, that are procured with public and private sector finance. The paper relates largely to procurement, rather than funding issues. We have provided an objective higher-level assessment of the strengths and weaknesses of the various available routes, including a general appraisal of the pros and cons of public and private sector finance. However, we did not address recent developments in the private sector funding arena—we will leave that to other contributors who are more expert in the field.
I am managing director of Keppie Design, Scotland's largest architectural practice and also one of the oldest—it is more than 150 years old. Having researched the practice history, I found that we started off doing schools following the passing of the Education (Scotland) Act 1872. Charles Rennie Mackintosh was the third partner in the practice, and he was involved in some school design at that point.
Is there any evidence of a direct connection between different procurement approaches and service quality?
From my perspective, it is quite possible to provide high-quality services whichever procurement method is applied. To return to my opening remarks, it requires management discipline to achieve that. If management discipline is applied, quality services will be derived.
I concur with Mr Ledger that it is possible to gain good levels of service across the range of available procurement routes. The main failing point in a number of those routes lies in the initial briefing periods and in the concentration on the level of design and on quality aspirations. It is a matter of how the different procurement methods support that through to the eventual service delivery. There is some evidence from the research that Architecture and Design Scotland has carried out that certain procurement methods provide more support than others in that respect.
I agree that there is no panacea—that no one procurement method is suitable for every project. The key thing is how the public sector side communicates with the private sector side. If there is a true partnering, in which the strengths of both sides are combined and the public sector is clear about its requirements and about affordability, the private sector can respond. The whole point about modern procurement methods is that they provide holistic delivery of design, construction and, possibly, maintenance. Value for money is important over the whole life of a building; it is not just about getting buildings finished and open.
I apologise for being delayed—I was at another meeting.
That question very much relates to the history of Architecture and Design Scotland, so I would like to respond. There is certainly evidence from PPP projects that we have reviewed—particularly some school projects, on which we worked with different agencies around Scotland—to show that many failed to live up to expectations in terms of the service and quality that have been delivered. As I said earlier, the issues around the levels of design quality are not solely attributable to PPP. However, the PPP process—certainly in its most recent form—exacerbates problems with early engagement around the briefing and the enshrinement in the process of aspirations. Although the process purports to allow a good degree of engagement between design teams and consortia and client bodies, there is not necessarily the level of engagement that might be found in a traditional process.
I agree with everything that Gareth Hoskins said. How we regard projects depends on what we compare them with. Just about anything that we do nowadays is better and lasts longer than the schools and hospitals of the 1960s and early 1970s, when the priority was to secure the cheapest capital cost.
Mr Ledger said that strong management discipline is required to secure a successful outcome for customers over a project's life. Is there evidence that certain procurement methods are more likely to result in strong management discipline? I think that Mr Hoskins suggested that there is such evidence, but he did not elaborate on that.
In practice, when the PPP/private finance initiative route is taken the banks impose the discipline on the client, whereas when the public sector funding route is taken it is up to the client to impose that discipline on himself. Neither method need necessarily be linked to strong management, which is possible in both methods.
"Strong management" can be paraphrased as "strong leadership". Whether the procurement method is traditional design and build or PPP, there will inevitably be a better result if there is strong leadership from the client. However, PPP and design and build routes disengage the direct connection between the client body—the leadership and management side of things—and the design teams who develop the qualitative aspect.
Very few public bodies, whether they are health trusts in England or local authorities, get the chance to develop a large project, so their skills tend to be limited. The central Government organisation is then required to help with advice. We tend to find that, in Scotland, where central Government is closer to local government, we get better results than those that come through in England, where the national health service is an enormous organisation. Some of the improvements and advice that come from central Government in England tend to get lost along the way, before they get to health trusts. It is important for central Government to play a part in the sharing of knowledge from one project to another.
On the management of projects, particularly in the health board work in which I am involved, we are certainly finding problems in the disconnection between policy aspirations and day-to-day delivery and management of the processes. There is very much a disconnection between quality and design ambitions and aspirations for each of those projects among the people who are responsible for delivering and controlling the processes on a daily basis.
My questions are on slightly different subjects. My first question is in two parts. Lindsay Glasgow, who, believe it or not, is the asset planning manager for the City of Edinburgh Council, stated in evidence to the Education, Lifelong Learning and Culture Committee on 16 April:
I will address the second point first. It is clear that PFI/PPP contracts are much less flexible during the operational phase than traditional or design and build routes. To my mind, the PFI/PPP route works best when there is a simple project with easily measured outputs, a client who knows what he wants over the long term and who is unlikely to change his requirements, and a private sector that is largely unencumbered in the delivery of the services. With a 30-year contract to deliver services, the client is effectively called on to define what he wants and how he will operate for the duration of the contract, which might be difficult in certain cases.
One problem is that we have been asked to deliver a huge number of hospitals and schools in the past 10 to 15 years. It might be nice to sit down and talk about every detail of every school, but the promise was made in 1998 that 100 new hospitals would be built in the UK by 2010—the figure will be 140—and schools tend to be dealt with in bundles, because each local authority wants all its schools to be upgraded quickly. That involves a compromise—the lack of the personal touch that it would be nice to have. As designers, we must accept that society wants many new facilities quickly—one local authority does not want to feel that it is falling behind another. We need to devise methods of consultation and design to achieve the best that we can.
I will answer the question about the level of engagement. It is evident from the projects that Architecture and Design Scotland has reviewed that a traditional process involves much more engagement than does a PPP process. On the whole, that results in buildings that are more in tune with their users and are better adapted to suit their needs—buildings that are more bespoke.
Several members are waiting with questions, so I ask Alex Neil to be quick.
My next questions are about Mr Stark's submission. Will he briefly give us more information on the local improvement finance trusts in English primary health care that involve private funding and public equity?
On the latter point, other witnesses later this afternoon can say more about the finances, but I presume that the return is the whole-year PFI costs. One benefit of modern procurement methods is that they do not consider just the capital costs. To keep a building operating for 30 years costs about five times the capital cost. The real cost of a hospital includes the cost of the doctors, nurses, medical equipment and so on, which can be well over 100 times the capital cost. It is important to get the correct design, construction and maintenance solutions if the facility is to run efficiently.
We have just come back from a research visit to Belfast last week. Northern Ireland health estates is running a similar process whereby projects are bundled together. As David Stark said, that approach allows the design team to develop working relationships with the client bodies, to begin to trust people and to understand the aspirations. In the examples that we saw, there were certainly much higher levels of design quality and final user satisfaction than are evident in Scotland.
Mr Hoskins mentioned a trip to Shetland and said that the local engagement there was more impressive than is the norm. We are going through a similar process in my constituency, and there has been concern about the level of engagement with parents and pupils. I suspect that schools differ in that respect from hospital builds. Is there anything that militates against innovation in such projects in relation to the take-up of energy efficient technology or the use of energy generation technology? We were told in previous evidence sessions that PFI does not like technology risks. Given that biomass schemes have proved to be mature and reliable in other parts of Europe, it is difficult to understand why technology risk is an overriding concern. Do you regard that as a downside to the PFI route? Is the take-up of such technologies behind where it ought to be? What can we do to improve take-up in that respect?
The PPP sector is reluctant to use some of the technologies that you mentioned because of the potential risk. The technologies are not tried and tested, and the companies involved are responsible for long-term maintenance, so there is a little reluctance. That is often because of insurance and maintenance issues. In some projects—David Stark might talk about some health projects—there is a push to use other technologies because of the maintenance benefits. I think that Glasgow southern general hospital was mentioned, and the matter has been discussed in that project. Traditional projects certainly allow us to explore those aspects much more.
I was going to mention another project, but the new Forth Valley hospital, in which we are involved, will have a lot of innovative features. In fact, the innovations will be found not only in that project because they have been developed over a number of other hospital projects. Most of us have now been through three or four hospital or school programmes. We are carrying forward the best lessons that we have learned on one project into the next—there should be gradual improvement.
In general terms, transferring risk to the private sector will influence the cost of a project. The private sector has to price the premium for the risk that has been transferred. The more difficult the risk is to manage, the higher the price will be. There is a case for doing what happens in railway construction projects. In general, the railways come in for tough criticism, but if Network Rail is introducing a new signalling system, it will implement it for the first time not on a busy mainline railway line, but on a branch line. When the new system has bedded in and has been proven to work, Network Rail will roll it out elsewhere on the network.
The Mott MacDonald submission mentions optimism bias. Mr Stark's comments that the public sector holds the whip hand in being more demanding and innovative were interesting in that regard. Other witnesses have talked about the difficulty of establishing the precise risk. Although some technologies might be untried and untested in this country, that does mean that they are untried and untested anywhere. It is therefore up to those who bid for projects to demonstrate why they deem the risk of engaging with technologies to be so much higher than when using more traditional methods.
In the briefs that many consortia receive, they are not asked to go for that level of ambition. Nowadays, the briefs that councils send out to design teams or consortia often refer to sustainability but fail either to define what that means or to set a level of aspiration.
Is that because consortia tend to say that that will up the risk profile and impact seriously on what councils are trying to achieve within their cost limits?
Not necessarily. We see that happening in traditional and PPP projects. Nowadays, sustainability is invariably a requirement in traditional projects; it is seen as the thing that every brief must have. However, the poor level—or lack—of knowledge in many in-house public sector development or estates teams about technologies means that councils are not in a position to take their aspirations further.
I will comment on optimism bias. The introduction of new technology is susceptible to optimism, but we are really talking about innovation or a novel application of existing technology, rather than technology that has been proven in a different sphere. There is a difference.
Mr Stark mentioned, and his submission notes, that the ideal ratio of long-term maintenance costs to original capital spend is 5:1. Can you give examples of how that can be built in as good practice over the life cycle? Have you worked on any projects in which that has occurred?
Obviously, it is built into whole-life contracts such as PFIs as part of the requirements. The building is funded by the private sector, which needs to ensure that the investment is retained. Unfortunately, with traditional funding, there is always some political imperative, and the maintenance budget is usually the first to be raided.
The whole-life cost angle and the emphasis on maintenance and operations are firmly linked in many people's minds with PFI and PPP, but it does not need to be like that. There are other models in which the client can contract for design, construction, operation and maintenance without securing private finance.
One of the issues with design is that it is often just viewed as the bit that is needed to make the buildings look pretty. The reality is that designing a building well is about making it efficient. If we do our job properly, we should consider the building's life cycle and whole-life costs. That is very much the focus in projects—or it certainly should be—in terms of taking a coherent and holistic design approach. The issue is to embed that within the project briefing and consider the capital costs that are allowed for in order to fulfil those ambitions. Scotland seeks grade A listed buildings, but often punts them at C listed level. Our funding aspirations need to be higher in terms of meeting life-cycle costs.
Alan Ledger is correct that there is no reason why maintenance cannot be built into a contract without funding. As part of the open-book partnering process that I suggest in my submission, the contractor-led supply chain is chosen early and works with the public organisation to identify the costs as the project evolves. Maintenance costs can be added later. In fact, if it is decided that public funding is not available, a funding competition can also be held. That means that when you start a project, you do not have to specify the amount of private or public funding that is being used.
I am interested in whole-life maintenance. Even the very poorly designed schools and hospitals from the 1970s that Mr Stark mentioned might have stood the test of time had they been maintained better, but often that did not happen, because, as you pointed out, other priorities arose and central Government perhaps did not allocate as much money as it should. In such situations, maintenance budgets are among the first to be examined.
I am laughing because surely it should be the inherent political responsibility of all sectors of government, no matter which parties are involved, to maintain their building stock.
Well, had that been the case, we might not have had some of the disasters that we have had over the years. Perhaps it should be the responsibility of Government, but self-evidently it has not been.
I have to say that that was thrown back at us pretty quickly.
The answer is to have a long-term contract, although it should be market tested every five years or so, which is what happens at the moment.
As I said earlier, clients can procure, design, build, operate and maintain contracts without private finance. Indeed, that already happens in certain sectors. Of course, in order to do that, you must ensure that the industry has the necessary capability. However, as it is simply about removing the finance element from PFI and PPP contracts, the capability obviously exists. Clients have to use the discipline that I mentioned earlier to ensure that contracts are let on the basis of best long-term, whole-life value for money.
If politicians were to think in the medium to long term, many things would be improved.
On the culture side of things, many—indeed all—lottery-funded public projects have to set out a revenue and maintenance programme for operating the facilities in question to secure not only that funding but funding from other external sources. Local councils have had to pledge funding for a number of years to cover on-going operation and maintenance costs.
To draw this session to a close, I ask our adviser, Nathan Goode, whether he wishes to make any comments or observations.
I thank the witnesses for their extremely interesting evidence and would welcome views on two key points that have emerged. First, how do we secure and enhance procuring authorities' knowledge to ensure that the lessons of previous procurements are learned? Secondly—and related to that—are there specific areas in which the process of evaluation and bidder selection to identify a preferred partner could be improved to support that knowledge?
Somehow, central Government needs to ensure that the information and knowledge get to the commissioning authority. As I said earlier, that happens better in Scotland than in England because the Scottish Government is closer to local government, but it still does not happen well enough. Central Government also needs to support the commissioning organisation in doing enough preparatory work. If that is not done before the project starts, and the bid process is commenced with all sorts of uncertainties, and the public sector client does not understand what it wants, it leads to disaster. Central Government should therefore support the local agency in the exploratory work that can be done before the process starts.
The private sector generally views knowledge management as vital. I suspect that the private sector might put more effort and investment into that than the public sector does. Key to that is having a process that feeds back the lessons that have been learned from projects so that succeeding initiatives do not go to the previous bid inquiry document, for instance.
It is evident from the work that we are doing with health boards throughout Scotland that boards that have professional architectural and surveying knowledge within their teams are much more informed and prepared when they produce briefing documentation and business cases. However, such knowledge exists only in a minority of boards.
Under NHS ProCure21 in England, the client goes to a contractor with a budget and says, "What's the best quality that you can give me for this amount of money?" To me, that seems better than picking the cheapest contractor.
I thank David Stark, Alan Ledger and Gareth Hoskins. Gentlemen, your experience and expertise, which have been in evidence today, will be useful to the committee in its inquiry. Thank you for your contribution today.
Meeting suspended.
On resuming—
On our second panel of witnesses, we have Alan Fordyce, the managing director of Robertson Capital Projects; Ian Rylatt, the managing director of Balfour Beatty Capital; and Steven Tolson, the director of Ogilvie Group Developments. I will give each of you the opportunity to make a brief opening statement.
Robertson Capital Projects is a privately owned Scottish company that specialises in investment in and delivery of PPP projects. I also sit on the board of twelve separate special purchase vehicle companies.
I run the infrastructure investment business in Balfour Beatty, which is one of the United Kingdom's largest construction companies. Our roots are very firmly in Scotland and, within the next 12 months, we will celebrate our 100th anniversary. We still have a lot of key businesses in Scotland—we have here a civil engineering business, a construction business and a mechanical and electrical business. We employ between 4,000 and 4,500 people in Scotland, of whom between 500 and 600 are involved in PFI.
Ogilvie is a medium-sized Scottish business, turning over some £200 million. We are active in PPPs for schools in Stirling, Falkirk and Clackmannanshire and are also involved in important non-PPP public projects in areas such as regeneration and social housing.
We have heard evidence that the bundling of PPP and PFI projects can be a barrier to smaller Scottish businesses entering the market. We have also received evidence that smaller firms are a valuable part of the supply chain but need to work in conjunction with larger firms in order to access key top-end delivery and management skills. What are your views on the future of the Scottish market? Are there any difficulties in key skill areas? If so, what are their implications for securing value for money? How can such difficulties be overcome?
You are right to say that it is difficult to attract local or smaller contractors into the market. The economies of PFI really work only when a larger project is being procured. There tends to be a bundling of schemes in order to get cost efficiencies. If the costs of PFI could be reduced, that would allow smaller contractors to participate, which we would welcome. As a larger contractor, we tend to find that we are involved in bundled projects and that, because of the scale of the work, we have to subcontract out to local contractors, which have the necessary skills.
Ogilvie is participating in joint ventures in the Scottish market. Some of the largest projects in which we are involved—the schools projects—are joint ventures with other smaller businesses; we try to bundle ourselves, as well as the product, together so that we can compete on a level playing field. It goes without saying that the supply chain is willing to work with us. Skill levels on our side have improved significantly. Like the public sector, we engage with consultants, where appropriate, to fill holes in the advice that is available to us.
It depends on what you mean by bundling. Like the other companies that are represented here, we have handled projects on our own, as joint ventures and as part of the supply chain. In our view, the optimum number of projects in education is six to eight, not the 25 to 30 projects that were included in the previous Glasgow and Edinburgh school schemes. That view is not based solely on our experience of construction—there are certainly enough contractors available to do £200 million or £300 million projects. As the previous panel suggested, the difficulty is having the required level of dialogue with the public sector about design and details. It is almost impossible to have that dialogue on more than six or eight projects.
I want to ask about two issues. First, a number of witnesses have suggested that competitive dialogue is problematic. I understand that the practice originates from the European Union. Are there ways of getting round the problems that have been created by competitive dialogue?
Competitive dialogue is a European initiative. It consists of guidelines rather than a set of instructions that tell us what we must do. We are currently bidding for a project that involves competitive dialogue and NPD. Because of the competitive dialogue element, we have tripled or quadrupled our bidding costs, which are now several million pounds. It is the only project for which a company such as Robertson Capital Projects will be able to afford to bid at that level this year. The bidding costs represent a significant drain of resources from the company. We have pointed that out to our public sector client. Unfortunately, because he was dealing with three bidders, he needed to have more design team meetings under competitive dialogue than he had days during the bidding process. Gareth Hoskins mentioned earlier that three design team meetings a day twice or three times a week are needed. Therefore, there is also a phenomenal requirement on the public sector. During the bidding stage, probably three times as much time is needed if three bidders are being dealt with.
I concur with everything that Mr Fordyce has said. As I said earlier, we have assessed the costs under competitive dialogue to be three times what they were under the invitation to negotiate. It is difficult for a Scottish company of our size to manage such costs. We are already assessing where we will go from here in participating in the sector. We are delivering on three PPP projects and we have gained substantial experience with our partners. It is therefore a great shame that our overall participation in the sector is now at risk as a consequence of the change. I entirely accept that competitive dialogue is an EU matter, but there is a tendency to approach the process as if one were reading a book and looking only at the fine print—the rules and regulations. I am not saying that one should avoid the rules and regulations, but one should consider their spirit and interpret them appropriately. From my experience, that remark applies to certain public organisations, although less so to others.
On Elaine Murray's first question, competitive dialogue has increased big costs. It is most prevalent in the UK—I refer to the BSF procurement programme that is going on in England, which has reduced competition. Partnerships for schools have been proactive in adopting a variation of competitive dialogue. Not all bidders are asked to develop a design for the first rounds of bidding at least. The more expensive big costs are left until later in the process to attract more people in.
I would like you to elaborate on NPDs. I presume that refinancing is caused by a lack of access to equity, which would be the norm for a PPP. Is that correct? If the NPD model replaced PPP, different models could be available for different partners. If NPD is part of a mix, is there still a threat? NPD might replace PPP as a form of funding, rather than co-existing with it.
There are three main differences between NPD and PFI. First, there is a capped rate of return. Secondly, there is full transparency in that the public sector has a director on the board—or perhaps two directors, one a charity director and one an independent director who deals with refinancing. Thirdly, there is the change to refinancing—it is not just refinancing of senior debt but refinancing of senior and junior debt. Junior debt is, in effect, our equity portion or risk capital sum within the project, and if that junior debt is refinanced, it is more or less the same as a forced sale. We would therefore have no economic interest in the project whatsoever at that point. A company such as ours, doing long-term maintenance on projects, would have no say on the board.
Ogilvie tends to consider PPP projects—or any projects—while wearing more of a contracting hat than an operational hat. Work on operations tends to be done by a partner. Our view on these issues may therefore be slightly different from the view of a company such as Mr Fordyce's, which works in operations as well as in construction.
We are very happy with the terms and conditions for NPD projects. We bid for the project for Aberdeen schools and were delighted to do so.
Convener, could I come back in? I handed over without meaning to do so.
That is allowed.
It was a forced handover.
It gave me more time to consider.
All three speakers have mentioned joint ventures. Will you comment on the possibility of moving towards joint ventures involving the public sector—either directly or via arm's-length companies run by the public sector?
As I said earlier, we are doing that at present south of the border with LIFT projects and with the building schools for the future programme. That work involves, more or less, the elements to which you refer. The private sector has 60 per cent, the public sector procurer has 20 per cent, and local government has 20 per cent. On that basis, we get almost the same outcome as from an NPD. There are capped returns—that is, the private sector and the public sector share the returns. There is also full transparency at board meetings, as all members have full voting rights.
The answer is yes. Ogilvie is involved in such partnerships. We are currently working in partnership on a project under a limited liability partnership banner. It is a 50:50 joint venture with Fusion Assets Ltd, which is now owned wholly by North Lanarkshire Council—it was owned previously by the council and Scottish Enterprise Lanarkshire. In that project, there is a management agreement; the public organisation recognises that the skills of operating on a day-to-day basis lie with us. All matters are decided at member level—they would be decided by a board within a company. Everything is shared 50:50. We like that, because it gives us a level playing field. There is good discipline in the project. There is political involvement at member level. It is a case of so far, so good. The project is a regeneration project, rather than a PPP, but there is no reason why it could not be any financial model that you wish it to be.
To reiterate what Alan Fordyce said, we are bidding for BSF in England, which has exactly that model. If you are contracting with someone to deliver, you have to ensure that they have the accountability and responsibility to deliver. BSF does that, because it still puts all the responsibility on the private sector. If you have too much of a joint venture arrangement, responsibilities can get fudged, which is a mistake.
You have all highlighted the increasing cost to the competitive dialogue process. Mr Tolson alluded to profits that might be seen as unreasonable. In previous evidence sessions, we were told that the PPP process has evolved and that the public sector might now be a more informed purchaser. One of the most consistent criticisms has been the lack of transparency in terms of the costs and returns to the private sector. Do you agree that there could perhaps be more transparency to improve public confidence in what is being delivered? If so, how do you see that evolving?
We would encourage public sector participation in a schools project. One of the Dundee schools in which we were involved is due to go live today. The public sector, in the form of one of the council's officers, has a seat on our board. We are delighted with that. The officer has access to all board papers and financial papers, takes part in all the board meetings and is a fully included member. We have heard evidence from previous witnesses about the super-profits made through PFI. We have 17 projects and I have not seen any super-profits in any of them. They are transparent. The financial models are there and can be fully reviewed. We would have no hesitation in sharing the financial information with all our partners. A lot of those issues have already been taken care of in the existing PFI model, where each member has an authority observer stakeholder representative. They are able to be represented at SPV board meetings.
Transparency can be a good thing and there has already been a lot of it. Many projects in recent history have been bond financed, which requires an offering circular containing a lot of financial information to be published and put instantly in the public domain. However, if we are to have transparency, there should be a level playing field. Not only the winning bidder's bid should be available; everybody's bids should be available, including those of the second and third-placed bidders, so that every bidder gets an equal view. Otherwise, there is a danger that the winning bidder will constantly have his numbers assessed by other bidders, whereas they are not getting the same treatment.
Transparency keeps coming up and is obviously an important issue. As we have discussed, we get transparency through joint venture. We have no problem whatever with the open-book approach. We apply that approach in the private sector partnering arrangements that we have with certain clients and it is equally appropriate with public sector clients. In general, there is no reason why we cannot provide such information. For the record, I inform the committee that we have not made super-profits either—that is a matter of hearsay.
I return to the costs of the competitive dialogue process. In this country, we have a tendency to blame EU rules for everything. Is there any evidence in the UK that some, or the bulk, of the additional costs that arise through competitive dialogue are self-imposed, rather than driven by European compliance requirements? Are you aware of comparisons with countries elsewhere in the EU that might show us whether the UK or Scottish Governments are unnecessarily adding burdens in implementation of compliance?
In my opening remarks, I talked about the process in itself—whether it is competitive dialogue, PPP or non-PPP. I have been involved in examples of all of them. There is an overly fastidious focus on processes. I find myself endlessly filling in forms and wondering what their real purpose is and how they will make the project better. The forms are not about the project per se, but about how we might do X, Y or Z. To be frank, our track record and those of our competitors speak for themselves in that regard. We should cut out that part of the process.
The three main elements in bid costs are staff, legal work and design. If there is a continuous market—one that can be seen coming—a company can reduce staff costs because of economies of scale. The BSF programme is driving bidding costs down—every time we do a project it is cheaper than the previous one. Legal costs come down as a result of standardised documentation: the more PFIs that are developed, the more standardised documentation there is. Most of the costs from the competitive dialogue process come from design issues. If authorities were willing to adopt a more standard school design throughout an area, only one design would be needed, rather than five or six designs if there are five or six bidders.
I concur with much of what my colleagues have said. As Ian Rylatt said, the costs are self-imposed. I suggest that the bulk—90 per cent—of the additional costs are purely for design. For guys like us, and from the public sector perspective, competitive dialogue means that if two bidders are in competition, they will fully design a hospital or a bundle of schools to the stage at which they are ready to go through the planning process. That is a complete waste of money for one of the bidders. Having two separate bidders, knowing fine well that one will not go forward, is a drain on public sector resources because it means that 50 per cent of what the public sector team does is a waste of time.
I have been looking at a presentation from a Balfour Beatty PPP/PFI seminar, which appears to fly in the face of what we have been told today and a lot of what we have been told previously. First, in relation to risk and uncertainty, one slide, on the risk assessment and management of PPP/PFI projects, describes the income as "low volatility"; the capital costs as "fixed"; the operating costs as "largely fixed"; the financing costs as "hedged"; and the inflation as "income RPI formula". It concludes that PPP/PFI projects have
I guess that those questions are pretty firmly addressed to me—I am happy to answer them.
I am looking forward to Mr Rylatt's explanation.
That presentation was made primarily to Balfour Beatty shareholders. On the first slide that Alex Neil referred to, we say to our investors that that is very much a feature of our portfolio. We believe that we are a market leader and that we are good at managing risk, and that we can therefore deliver cost certainty in a project. However, cost certainty is not guaranteed—there are lots of examples of companies that have not delivered cost certainty. There are elements of efficiency that we have delivered in our projects that other companies have been unable to deliver. Until now—tomorrow is always another day—we have been very good at managing risk.
My point is that you are telling your shareholders a completely different story from the one that you are telling us. The conclusion of the first slide is that there are
We believe that that is true of our portfolio. Balfour Beatty has historically been good at managing risk, and we plan to be good at managing risk tomorrow. We believe that our projects deliver highly profitable cash flows.
Does your £250 million profit for a £15 million investment represent good value for the public purse?
You have to take into account the time value of money. If you look at simple nominal cash flows, that is what it will show over a 30-year period.
I quoted the internal rate of return because it takes account of the nominal cash flows and the discount: it came out at 18 per cent after tax.
I am happy to answer that question, as well. The number that you are referring to is the nominal cash flow. If you look at the real cash flow, we are earning a return of about 14 per cent. We are unsuccessful in a lot of the projects that we bid for, and the cost of running my business is circa 2.5 per cent. I have to manage a group of shareholders who are looking for a return on their investment, and I guess we are paying them the weighted average cost of capital of the group—let us say that that is 8 per cent. If you divide those numbers up, I am making roughly 4 per cent for taking the risk that I take on a PFI. That is extremely good value for money, given the risks that we have to manage. As we say to our investors, we will deliver you that 4 per cent premium because we are good at managing the risks.
In that case, are you not misleading your shareholders by telling them that you are making all that money? You cannot have it both ways.
I do not think that we are because our shareholders realise the costs that we have in our business—they realise the trade-off between risk and reward that we earn for them.
If you want to add any further information in written form, please do so. Are there any other questions?
I made a point about risk, uncertainty and profiteering. I am not convinced by that, having seen the slide from the Balfour Beatty presentation. There is an internal story and another one for people like us.
You might wish to follow that point through, Mr Rylatt.
It was a public presentation that was made to shareholders. We do not have different stories; we have one story.
I offer something of a balance in relation to the equity input and the profit that might be earned. Suppose that a project goes over budget and over time and you do not manage to achieve what you want to achieve and do not manage to deliver what you have been contracted to deliver. Is the risk that you as a bidder are exposed to limited to your equity investment or could it be higher?
Typically, it is limited to the value of our equity, but you must recognise that by the time a contractor gets to its equity, it has had to burn through a whole load of other contingencies. Typically, the contractor in a PFI project will have far greater liabilities under its liquidated damage or termination provisions, so it has to burn through that first. When that is done, the equity provides another layer of what is, in effect, a cash-collateralised performance bond that has to be burned through before the company fails, ultimately. It is not the only method; a layer of guarantees sit below that, which usually go way beyond what would be found in a normal, conventionally procured project.
A special purpose vehicle company is, by its nature, set up to deliver one project, so it would take a catastrophic event for a project to fail. We have heard today about examples of companies going bust, ceasing to trade or running into construction difficulties. As Ian Rylatt said, if that happens in the construction period, good risk management from banks will ensure that risk is transferred to the contractor.
Mr Tolson?
I have nothing further to add.
As there are no more questions from members, I ask our adviser Nathan Goode for any comments or observations.
There have been a couple of references to different types of partnership model, such as BSF and LIFT, and to standardisation. Does the panel feel that the industry is best served by standardisation or by the proliferation of models?
I have never been a great supporter of standardisation in life. "Horses for courses" is my answer to the question. It depends on the type of project. Some projects will fit well with standardisation—schools have been referred to—although hospitals fit less well. It is possible that health clinics might fit well with standardisation, but they might not. You have to look at the project and work out the process from there, rather than do it the other way round. In achieving value for money, scaled economies must be sought for the benefit of both the private sector and the public sector. I would not jump to one methodology alone.
For me, the issue is single-point accountability. If you are going to enter a contract with someone, you must ensure that they deliver and you must give them the responsibility to do so. Most people will now be happy for that to be done in an open and transparent way. We fully support that approach.
As my colleagues do, I think that we are happy to consider what is best for the project. With the Scottish NPD model, I suggest that it might be worth considering the BSF/LIFT models to attract similar elements.
We do not want to be continually reinventing the wheel.
Meeting suspended.
On resuming—
I welcome our final panel of witnesses: Jo Elliot is deputy chief executive of Quayle Munro; Dylan Fletcher is a group board director of Forth Electrical Services Ltd; and Andrew Gordon is chief executive of Canmore Partnership Ltd. The witnesses may make brief opening statements.
Unlike many of the companies from which the committee has heard today, Canmore is not exactly a household name. We do only PFI/PPP public use infrastructure projects and we have been around more or less since the inception of PFI/PPP.
The name Canmore nevertheless has very good Scottish roots.
That is deliberate.
Good afternoon. I sit as a director on the board of Forth Holdings Ltd, which is a holding company dealing mainly in facilities management and construction-related activities. We operate a lot in the PFI market as well as in the traditional facilities management and construction markets. We are a family-owned business that employs about 1,500 employees directly.
My firm is Edinburgh-based. We are investment bankers and PFI has been our principal speciality since it started, which, for us, was in the early 1990s.
We have heard quite a lot about the NPD model. You have all been involved with that in some way. Does the NPD model provide better value for money than conventional PFI/PPP models?
From our perspective, one of the main differences between NPD and traditional PFI is the financing. Our business has invested equity in about six projects in Scotland and one in England, but we have probably worked on more than 25 projects throughout England and Scotland. Our main business is construction and facilities management, not financing, so for us there is not much difference between the NPD structure and traditional PFI. Construction procurement is the same for both types of project, as is facilities management. The NPD structure affects the financing of a project, and we do not see a huge difference between the two types of project unless we have an equity subscription within a project.
From an economic point of view, I find it difficult to see how the NPD model can deliver higher equity returns in an efficient market—and we are operating in an efficient, competitive market. We need certain returns to offset the risks that are involved in a project. If the NPD model has the effect of capping those returns, we must bid for higher returns in the first place. As a matter of principle, I find it difficult to think of the NPD model as the panacea. We are arguing theoretically about NPD models; from a practical point of view, we must remember the 800 or so other projects in the UK that are not NPD. As yet, it might be too early to tell as far as NPD models are concerned. There have been two or three projects in Scotland to test, but we have to wait and see.
I suspect that, if the Government was prepared to accommodate bidders' concerns about an important but subsidiary element of NPDOs—the refinancing aspect—a sufficient number of bidders would accept the capping of return, which is what I think that the NPD model was meant to be about. It is sad that successive projects have not openly tested the NPD model against classic PFI. If they had done, we would know the answer.
You have partly answered the question that I was about to ask. The previous panel expressed concern that the development of the NPD model was making it less favourable to bid for projects in Scotland than elsewhere. Is the concern about NPD replacing PPP, rather than about the NPD model being used as an alternative funding method alongside traditional PFI?
That is probably the case. We operate in a competitive market in the UK. If any bidder who operates across the UK is offered a better deal somewhere else, he will take what he thinks to be the better deal—unless he is very loyal or very stupid. The Government has to perform a balancing act. It must claw back the best deal that it can without having an uncompetitive number of bidders. We do not need, say, eight bidders; we need only enough to make a competition. Some would argue that that means two, three or four.
I agree with Andrew Gordon in many respects. We recently completed the Falkirk schools using an NPD model and we are a competitor of Andrew Gordon's in Tayside. As I said, our business is predominantly construction, although we have equity investments in some projects. The structure that was used in Falkirk is not favourable for an NPD model. Forced refinancing is one sour aspect, although most of the market is quite happy with the rest of the structure. If there was some way in which we could amend NPD models slightly, that would provide a favourable structure from the market's point of view.
What sort of amendment do you have in mind?
Forced refinancing, which Alan Fordyce mentioned, is probably the biggest single aspect that should be amended. Capped returns are another aspect, but I think that people accept them. I think that everyone realises that the large returns that were produced by the early PFIs when equity or sub debt was sold on have been replaced with more competitive returns. People are probably quite comfortable with capped returns and a sharing mechanism with the public sector—that is not a big deal.
A great deal of effort is invested in winning a bid—and from an investor's point of view in getting the money out—but if there might be forced refinancing we must put a value on an investment without knowing how long we will be able to hold it or what the ultimate return will be. Given that we are talking about managing money that is ultimately owned by pension funds and so on, such investment is very difficult and can be countenanced only within a portfolio of more normal investments—that is not a stable or encouraging position to be in.
I think that Andrew Gordon suggested that there was less competition for the Tayside mental health project because the NPD model was being used. Please correct me if I am wrong, but I understand that there have been very low levels of competition for recent PPP projects throughout Scotland. For example, there were only two bidders for a £100 million project in Dundee. Perhaps the lack of competition has nothing to do with the NPD model but is because so much is going on.
If you are in the PPP business very little is going on. Very little new stuff is happening. There is a flat market—
If that is the case, why were there only two bidders for the Dundee PPP project?
I was talking about Tayside. I can tell you that six to eight potential bidders turned up at the open day, and every potential bidder who did not bid did not do so primarily because of NPD. I know that because I asked them. What I said was based on knowledge.
We were involved in Dundee, and I can offer a different explanation. When Dundee came to market the construction industry was quite busy. There was a lot on—not just PPP but other projects. Dundee is probably regarded as being slightly out of the central belt—
So is Tayside, then.
I accept that; I am just suggesting that NPD was not the only factor. The Dundee market was quite buoyant, which might be another reason why the project did not attract a number of bidders. However, NPD probably puts some bidders off.
Can you clarify which projects you are talking about? It is not crystal clear.
The Dundee project is a bundled schools project. The Tayside project is a mental health project.
The miles to Dundee seem pretty short.
On risks, when someone acquires the equity in a PFI project they are accepting the residual risk over 30 years of the cash flows coming through, as projected in the financial model. Of course, we design the financial models and contractual structures to lay off as much of the risk as possible. If we did not do that, financing projects 90 per cent with bank debt would be impossible. Traditionally, 90 per cent is bank or bond finance and 10 per cent comes from equity, so we are talking about the riskiest slice. Why do we want to gear it as much as possible? Because that reduces the cost of capital. The first point is that we are talking about the returns on only 10 per cent of the total capital cost.
Would indemnity insurance be far cheaper than the expensive arrangement under PPP and PFI?
I do not rule out that possibility, but we try to put together the cheapest possible bids so that we win. If an easy way of insuring such risks existed, I would like to think that we would have found it by now.
We can consider the history of PPP/PFI, which has been going for some time—for nearly 11 years under the London Government. In Scotland, four projects have gone sour. In East Lothian, the private sector picked up the tab. Buying out the PPP and PFI contracts for the Skye bridge, Inverness airport and West Lothian College projects cost the public purse an additional £70 million. Given that only four projects have landed in such difficulties, where is the risk? Is that not a bit of a creation?
Risks are things that might happen. As my submission says, the fact that risks do not materialise often means not that they do not exist, but that we are highly incentivised to ensure that they do not happen or to lay them off.
The issue is the cost of dealing with those risks. A normal consultancy business always carries the risk of giving the wrong advice. If it does not have indemnity insurance, it can go out of business, but the cost of that insurance is fairly modest, because the risk is not great. Why do PPP and PFI projects not operate on that basis?
If a cheap and easy way existed, I would like to think that we would have found it.
Is insurance not cheaper and easier?
No, because such risks are not insurable. Contractual disputes, which are the bane of everybody's life in the early stages of a contract, are not insurable events. They arise because unpredictable things happen and must be worked through diligently to obtain the best deal.
I believe that you have been involved in a lot of refinancing of PFI and PPP projects. What return do you obtain on refinancing?
We have not been involved in many refinancings, but I will answer anyway. In effect, refinancing means borrowing against the future cash flows from a project. It concerns reducing the cost of the senior debt and advancing the returns by gearing up the project further. That is done when the project's risks are judged to have reduced. After a project is commissioned, the consensus is—and I believe it to be the case—that its risks are substantially reduced.
Absolutely, so when a project is refinanced, you pocket quite a wee profit, do you not?
The profit that is made reflects the successful management of risks. It is part of the reward for a successful project.
In the projects that you have been involved in, has the profit that has been made been shared with the public purse?
We have not completed any refinancings. However, in the projects of which I am aware, the profits have been shared with the public purse.
In the cases in which the profit was shared, was the original risk shared?
No. Thank you for that intervention.
Canmore Partnership's written submission states:
Mr McCabe reminded me of the asymmetry of the situation. We go into a project hoping for the best, but if the worst happens, we know where the risk lies. When the thing is up and running smoothly, the problems of ground conditions and all the other things that can go wrong in the project no longer exist. There is a difficulty if the public authority puts up its hand and says, "You've done very well. You've made money because you've run the project skilfully. Actually, we'd like some of that profit."
We have some experience of projects not running smoothly.
The answer to the question "What are the risks?" is that they are the things that go wrong, and things do go wrong. Elaine Murray quoted our submission, which quotes KPMG. When you put Ian Rylatt on the spot—brilliantly—he could have answered, "Metronet." Balfour Beatty lost tens of millions of pounds when things went wrong with Metronet. If you asked the shareholders of Jarvis whether PPP can go wrong, they would say, "Yes—every day, as far as we can see." The studies that have been done show that things go wrong—that is the risk.
I agree with Andrew Gordon's comment on forced refinancing. We are discussing risk transfer and value for money. Apart from the financial aspect, there is clear evidence from the construction and operating side that, under PFI, projects are completed on time, within budget and to the desired quality. Whether the quality is set correctly at the outset is an argument that Gareth Hoskins would take up, but when we compare completed traditional projects with completed PFI projects, there is clear evidence that the PFI projects meet the criteria.
Andrew Gordon partly answered my question in his description of son of NPDO. Looking further ahead to the Scottish futures trust model, some of the written submissions and the oral evidence that have been presented to the committee have indicated that lack of certainty and detail is a problem. Could the panel members flesh out a wish list of what that detail might contain? Building on Mr Gordon's point about the impact that NPD is having on the market, which was echoed by other panel members, do you feel that there is a point at which decisions about the Scottish futures trust will need to be taken? Does the Government need to put PPP/PFI back on the table, or else investment will dry up?
A wish list. Who wishes to start?
We talked about the difference between the NPD model and the PFI model, without considering the SFT. The NPD model is not unfair—it actually works; there are just one or two aspects of it that do not work. Putting it in the bin and moving to the SFT after 10 years of continuous improvement—having now reached the NPD stage—would mean throwing away a lot of good work to move to something completely different. Only time will tell whether that is right, because the model is untested, but throwing away what we have done for the past 10 years and starting again would be a big move.
Uncertainty is a problem. We might have got it wrong: we thought that the Scottish futures trust was primarily a funding mechanism. I do not know how it works as a funding mechanism, but I do not know how lots of things work. I did not come up with the futures trust; it would be good if someone who came up with it with were to tell us how it will work as a funding mechanism, or whether it will not work in that way at all.
Will you hazard a guess at how long we can continue in a state of limbo?
I suppose that the people who live here will leave last. How long they will stay, I do not know.
We must be aware that the PFI/PPP industry has moved on a great deal in the past 10 years. It was invented in the UK, of course, and has spread through large parts of the developing world. It comes in various flavours, but as a concept it is not a British aberration; it was developed here and widely adopted elsewhere.
I recognise that there is an international market these days. To what extent have NPD models evolved in other jurisdictions? What benefits or flaws have been identified elsewhere?
I am not aware of any other NPD models. An example of the new thinking that the SFT might involve is consideration of how long private sector money should be invested in a project. If we say that the time of major risk for a project is during construction, why must the private sector's money be left in that project for the full 30 years? Perhaps the state should buy it out after a period. That kind of thinking is potentially fruitful.
I have nothing to add to Jo Elliot's comments, which I support.
I am not aware of NPD in any other jurisdiction, but that is not a surprise. In many ways, NPD is a logical iteration of classic PFI/PPP, which is a UK invention. If NPD is got right, it could deliver better value for money—hence the frustration that exists. Much of NPD is on the right track, but it is pushing too far. It appears that an unwillingness to contemplate change and some kind of accommodation may derail it.
We have reached the end of this three-panel session. I thank our final panel of witnesses for their presence and their contribution.
Meeting suspended.
On resuming—