The next agenda item is our fifth evidence session on the bill. I welcome Alan McCreadie, deputy director of law reform at the Law Society of Scotland, and Jim McLean, a consultant at Balfour and Manson and also representing the Law Society of Scotland.
Some witnesses have told us in evidence that the introduction of a minimum unit price would cause Scotland to be in breach of European law. Can you explain what that law is trying to achieve?
That is a reference to articles 34 and 36 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union. The EU is trying to ensure that there is interference with imports and exports only when there are certain justifications for that, and in no other circumstances.
Is it the main purpose of those articles to prevent a member state from discriminating in favour of home produce or against produce from another member state?
Yes. It is to stop trade barriers being erected that do not look like trade barriers at first sight, but that operate as such. A relevant example is Germany’s law on beer purity. The law was such that beer could be made only from female hops and water and no other ingredients. If it was made of anything else it could not be called beer in Germany. The European Court of Justice said that such a law was completely disproportionate and that people could be perfectly well informed by a labelling system.
Does that lead me to believe that minimum pricing is not discriminatory because it applies to any product, no matter where that product is made?
Minimum pricing might not discriminate, but it can affect the market. Minimum pricing would be considered as raising an article 34 question because it denies to the exporter possible cost advantages and the ability to price a particular product more competitively. There is an issue. The question is how that is dealt with.
The last part of this question is how that interacts with the public health aspect. What weight is given to public health?
Article 36 deals with that leg of the question. The rule against restrictions on imports
Finally, I will ask you, but not as lawyers—perhaps you can keep a wee legal hat on—whether the measure that the Government is trying to proceed with is all to do with public health?
I think that it is a health measure, but the difficult question is whether it is proportionate. Given the context and everything that led up to it, it would be difficult to say that it is not a health measure. It is not one of those measures in respect of which people say, “Ha ha, I’ve found the answer. I can protect this industry by calling this a health measure.” The context and history of the bill suggest that nothing was further from people’s minds. The really difficult question is that of proportionality.
Thanks very much for that.
Do you wish to add anything, Mr McCreadie?
There is nothing that I can usefully add. The matter hangs on the interpretation of article 36 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union and the proportionality issue.
Okay. Thanks very much. Opening up that matter right away has been helpful.
I want to follow up on the points that Gil Paterson made.
That will be useful, as a number of others want to come in on the issue. I hope that we can cover the area properly.
A comment was made about excise duty and raising prices. If, as seems likely, the United Kingdom Government declines the Scottish Government’s request to use the Scotland Bill to transfer to it powers on excise duty, what pricing alternatives realistically remain for the Scottish Government? European law generally points towards taxation being the preferable option, but the Scottish Government will not have that power. Jim McLean said that excise duty could be raised, but we cannot do that, because it is a reserved matter. Realistically, what can we do?
It is important to focus that issue. Under European Union law, the question is about trade with a member state, and the member state in question is the United Kingdom, although we are talking about just a part of it. The internal arrangements in a member state and the granting or withholding of powers in it are of no interest at all to European Union law. It is of no consequence that the answer to the question why duty was not raised or why loss leading was not banned is, “Because we couldn’t.”
If the UK Government said that it would not put up the price, are you suggesting that that would be us—we would be stymied and we could do nothing?
No, I am not suggesting that. I am saying that the question whether minimum pricing is an appropriate and proportionate response to a perceived problem that complies with article 36 relates to trade into and out of the United Kingdom and does not concern the internal arrangements in the United Kingdom. The question whether such a power should or could exist is different and would not be addressed in litigation on the measure.
One test of proportionality will be the price itself. You have outlined some of the initial problems and where a challenge might come from.
A process of review—possibly continuous—would be needed to see that whatever was being done remained proportionate, if it had been considered proportionate in the first place. I will expand on that slightly. One difficulty is that, as far as I know, nothing quite like the proposal has been tried, although some measures in Canada have not been a million miles away from it. That means that people cannot point at evidence and say, “This is what happens when you have a minimum price.” What can be done is modelling, which has been done, with a great deal of care.
My second question is about the operation of the measure. I do not know whether the convener wants to take other members first and come back to me.
We will keep on the current theme, if you do not mind. I will of course let you back in later.
I will ask a question back to front, in a way. The committee has received an interesting report from the Subordinate Legislation Committee that makes the point that it is that committee’s responsibility to establish not just whether the bill could be within the Parliament’s legislative competence but whether it is within that competence.
Lawyers often come up against the fact that they are telling people how to manage an element of legal uncertainty rather than giving certainty. I do not think that certainty is on offer in this regard. In what way could the measure be notified?
I understand from evidence that we have received from other parties that it would be open to the Government to notify the European Commission of the intention to implement the policy, which would allow the Commission to determine ahead of the policy being enacted whether it fell within the competence of the Parliament or contravened any of the trade barrier laws to which you referred a moment ago.
There are some obligatory notifications. If the measure involves state aid, for example, there would be an obligatory notification, but there is no state aid in this case because there is no transfer of resources except from the consumer.
To sum up that position, if we were able to notify the Commission of the policy intention, its opinion might offer the Parliament further reassurance, but it would not offer the Parliament certainty. Ultimately that certainty will be established only if the policy is subsequently challenged in court.
I think so. It is always possible that the Commission might react by suggesting what might be modified or done to make the policy more palatable; it is not unknown for that kind of conversation to happen. Ultimately, however, it would take litigation to get an absolute, 100 per cent definite view.
Thank you.
I have had sight of some correspondence from the Commission—I am not at liberty to say between whom at this point—which says that the proposal is:
I am aware of the obligation to notify a technical regulation, but I am not sure why people think that the proposal is a technical regulation. “Technical regulation” means:
The Commission certainly takes a different view—
So it would seem—
I presume that the Commission will be asked to comment at some point.
The Government will take its own advice on that. As I said, I do not see a basis for an obligatory notification under directive 98/34/EC. As you said, someone at the Commission has taken a different view. I have come across people arguing about the obligation in other contexts, so I am not surprised that someone has raised the issue.
At the end of the day, it will be up to stakeholders to go before a national court and say that a technical regulation has been adopted without previous notification. From what you said, I understand that the stakeholders would have to prove, first, that the minimum pricing proposal was a technical regulation—they would cite the Commission’s support in that. If they proved that it was a technical regulation and notification had not been given, the national court might strike it down.
Indeed, but, as I said, I find it difficult to see how it would be argued that it is a technical regulation, because it has nothing to do with the substance of the product or permitting the product to be on the market at all; it is purely about the price at which a product may be sold.
Thank you.
In relation to competence and barriers, is there any link between minimum unit pricing and tobacco, in the context of article 36 and the health aspects of measures? If we continue to look at the potential health benefits of minimum unit pricing, will there be any alignment with what has happened on tobacco pricing and measures that try to restrict the use of tobacco for the sake of people’s health?
There have been cases on tobacco—I think that that is what you are alluding to—from which has emerged the idea that it is not enough simply to assert a health point. However, those cases were not to do with articles 34 and 36 of the treaty; they were about compliance with the tobacco duty directive, which is structured significantly differently from the alcohol duty directive. In the structure of tobacco duties, the freedom to set a retail price is a given. Therefore if someone introduced a minimum price for tobacco they would upset the way in which the duties system is supposed to work. That is not true of alcohol, so I think that there is a difference.
So there is no direct alignment between the two.
No. There are obviously resonances and ideas that flow between them but, on the direct point that the tobacco cases were on, the position on alcohol is not the same.
In your submission, you referred to the Tobacco and Primary Medical Services (Scotland) Act 2010. What point were you making about tobacco and its relation to minimum pricing?
It was a competence point.
We understand that taking such action was within the Parliament’s competence, but what was the link that you were making with minimum pricing?
That was not so much a European point as a devolution point. There is a view in some quarters that the reservation of consumer law to Westminster affects the issue. The way in which it has been put is that here is something that affects the sale of goods to consumers. The issue of the scope of that reservation has been before the court, in the Imperial Tobacco—
It went before the Court of Session as part of a petition for judicial review on the competence of the Scottish Parliament.
That case is under appeal, but an interesting judgment was made on it, which included a remark about the reservation of consumer law being about the terms of sales rather than the environment of sales. That is true. In that context, I see exactly what Lord Bracadale was driving at.
That is helpful but, for the benefit of the non-lawyers on the committee, what was Lord Bracadale driving at?
He was driving at the idea that a consumer law reservation does not have anything to do with whether you can have vending machines and so on, which is to do with the sales environment. A consumer law reservation is about the labelling of products, the information that is provided and, primarily, the terms and conditions of supply to a consumer. It comes through in the judgment that he had in mind things such as the Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts Regulations 1999, which mean that certain exclusion clauses, liability exclusions and so on that might be possible in a sale of goods that is negotiated between businesses are not acceptable in a consumer contract. That was the kind of area of law that Lord Bracadale had in mind.
That was helpful.
I would hesitate to rush in with a view one way or the other. I have sought to identify the issues. Much will depend on how impressed people are by the arguments that only minimum pricing can meet the particular objectives and that duty or a ban on loss leading could not. That is the main issue.
Your written evidence states that the issue is not just about compatibility with the EC duty directives, because minimum pricing could have an impact on the free movement of alcohol. Will you explain what you meant by that?
That was another way of putting the same point—it is not a separate point.
Everyone is quoting acts and legislation, so I will quote a Law Society submission. It states:
That was a heavily condensed passage. The question was raised at some stage as to whether there is a competition law issue. In my view, there is not a competition law issue because there is no voluntary involvement in the price setting. The policy memorandum that accompanies the bill contains a remark about article 101 and, I think, article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union. The point is that, if the industry was involved in price setting, there would undoubtedly be a competition law issue, but it is not involved. Because the price is state imposed and is obligatory or compulsory and because the measure is a real exercise of state power rather than rubber stamping, there is no competition law issue.
Does the Scottish Government have that power?
Competition is a reserved matter. If it had been a competition matter, that would have exceeded devolved powers. We take the view that it is not a competition law issue.
We heard from Professor Stockwell, who works in Canada, to which Jim McLean referred. The situation there is different, because the Government controls everything. The wholesale supply of all alcohol is done through the Government, and it sets the price. One interesting point that Professor Stockwell made was that there are 5,500 products.
The idea being that, if minimum pricing had a disproportionate effect on imports, that would itself be discriminatory?
Yes.
I think that that is an aspect of the proportionality issue. In a court case, one of the things in the background, which is not always avowed, is whether a measure is really a protectionist exercise. As far as I am aware, that has not featured in any debate on this matter. If anyone thought that, that is the kind of inquiry that they would want to make. I would think that the Scottish Government would find it pretty daunting to try to go through 5,000 or so products. If it were true that imported products might be more heavily affected, that would not be irrelevant, but it would not be the complete determinant.
You say that going through 5,000 products would be a daunting task, but if any ban is going to be properly enforced, the Government will have to do that anyway, so that it can decide which are above and which are below the minimum price.
If you say that the minimum price is X, there is an enforcement issue, and you will have to find out whether it is being sold at X. That is very much like the other kinds of enforcement issues that arise in this context, is it not?
But the Government will have to check every product on the shelf to ensure that it is not breaking the law, if the price is 45p a unit or whatever it is going to be.
I think that Alan McCreadie can answer this point.
That is a licensing issue, as far as I understand it. The Law Society is pointing out that, if minimum pricing becomes law—if it meets all the challenge to do with competence and European compatibility—a practical problem will arise around enforcement. A breach of the minimum pricing legislation will not be an offence. The provision is an amendment to the mandatory conditions of licence, and there will be practical issues to do with enforcement, as those conditions are enforced by licensing standards officers on everyone who has a licence to sell alcohol.
One of the concerns of the Commission will be whether the measure could prevent new competitors coming into the field—in other words, whether it might interfere with the market in a way that would prevent a highly efficient producer coming in and offering its product, which is identical to an existing product, at a lower price. Could that be an issue here?
That is the issue that makes this a European law issue at all. The fact that someone might not be able to get the full benefit of their own efficiency is the reason why there is an article 34 issue in the first place. Everything that I have read on this seems to accept that that is an issue. The question is whether there is a health answer to it.
The Law Society’s evidence talks about whether people who sell alcohol might be encouraged to sell larger measures, which might bring them in breach of the 2005 act. Why do you raise that point?
Again, it is just a practical point in relation to something that might come up if we have a minimum unit price. Under the mandatory conditions of licence, it is regarded as an irresponsible promotion if you are seeking to encourage someone to buy a larger measure. I appreciate that this point applies only to the on-trade, but it might arise in a situation in which there is a meal deal, and the price of the food that is served is brought down to meet the statutory minimum unit price of the alcohol. In a situation in which the price of the food is reduced to a great extent—which it would have to be, if the price of the meal deal is to be kept the same—it could be assumed that the customer is being encouraged to buy, as part of the meal deal, alcohol that they might not have bought otherwise. As I understand it, because of the changes in the Alcohol etc (Scotland) Act 2010, the mandatory condition of a premises licence applies only to the on-trade.
I suppose that you are therefore anticipating the possibility of a market response that might take people into ordering larger measures.
There may be a market response whereby the statutory minimum price is included in the meal deal. I would put it no higher than that.
In the final part of your evidence, you said that section 2 is redundant, but in the course of our discussions so far it has emerged that we might not wish to regard it as such in our evaluation of these matters.
We said that it is redundant in that it means nothing in terms of the 2010 act because that does not apply to minimum pricing. We appreciate that that was an issue at stage 3 of its passage. As regards the current bill, it is debatable whether there should be a sunset clause, or even a review clause, to monitor the effects of minimum pricing and whether it is properly targeted as a health measure. That is a matter that parliamentarians might want to consider.
You said that if the EU opened the door to this kind of measure and it then proved to be ineffective, the EU would be somewhat disappointed that it had done that. Would the addition of a sunset clause be likely to influence matters on the European side?
I think that it might. There is some question as to whether the full sunset review would be required, but an acknowledgement that this is a moving target and that evidence will be created would be extremely helpful.
Can I clarify this point? Dr Simpson talked about various brands. If minimum unit pricing is to be based on volume and strength in terms of proof, can we not ignore the branding aspect?
I am not sure whether that was the point.
I was not suggesting that the Government was making a specific attack on a brand but that the practical effect of the minimum unit price might be to exclude, disproportionately, a very efficient producer who is an importer. In other words, the practical effect of the policy might be to discriminate disproportionately against importers, and it could therefore be seen as an import control measure.
My point is not about specific branding but the strength of the alcohol in terms of volume. If minimum pricing is based on that, I cannot see how it would involve any discrimination because it would apply right across the board.
It would apply across the board, but that board might have more importers than native producers. This involves an article 34 issue, and that might form part of the argument. For me, however, the nub of the matter is whether this is a genuine health measure that is justifiable on the basis that it can do things that could not be done by any of the apparent alternative measures.
Have the licensing officers had any difficulty in enforcing the multiple discount ban or the smoking ban?
I have no information about that, although I could certainly find out. I do not know how well the discount ban that was brought in by the 2010 act is working in practice. One could ask local authorities, because they employ the licensing standards officers.
As far as the smoking ban is concerned, all you need to do is go past any pub and see everyone standing outside.
I certainly have anecdotal evidence in that respect. I frequent pubs from time to time myself and have noticed as much.
Of course, I am talking about smokers, not drinkers. Most pubs are free of pollution from smoking.
I think that that is a policy issue.
You are a lawyer—give me your views on that question.
There are two lawyers present, Richard, so you are in danger of getting two opinions. I am sure that both views will be personal.
With the greatest respect to the Law Society and lawyers, the fact is that if I have 10 accountants, 10 lawyers or 10 whatever, I will get 10 different opinions.
We are trying to help with a risk assessment, but we are not the people who are taking the risk. Is this an appropriate time to mention where or how this might be litigated?
I am sorry—what did you say?
I do not know whether a corollary of your question is how this might be litigated. After all, a procedural aspect that should be kept in mind is that the European Court of Justice likes national courts to do their work. It likes them to examine the assessment, look at the facts, reason the thing through and come to a view whether there is compliance, proportionality and all that sort of thing and, whenever it can, it says that national courts should just get on with that. Frequently, however, national courts do not do so. When that happens, the European Court of Justice in effect says, “Well, if no one else is going to do it, we’ll have to,” and does the work instead. Wherever this goes, if there is litigation, it will be incumbent on the Scottish courts to ensure that everyone concerned has gone through the arguments fully and that there is an opportunity for a really thorough analysis because it will make the job of whatever court reviews the matter much easier.
So in your personal opinion if this bill were to be passed and then contested it would be contested only in Scottish law courts and the House of Lords and might not go to Luxembourg.
It might not. However, given what I heard earlier, if the Commission has taken a view that there should have been a notification, it might intervene and take it to Luxembourg. In that case, the matter would be out of everyone’s hands.
Thank you very much.
Is the measure more likely to be challenged if the minimum unit price is set at, say, 75p rather than 45p and if it is linked to inflation? Does it all depend on impact? If a challenge resulted in our having to reduce this almost to a token measure in order to get it passed and implemented, would that not render it almost meaningless as a health policy?
If it were a token measure, that would probably count against it legally.
Right.
There is going to have to be a demonstration of the likely modelled effect of various possible price rises. As far as I can see, in the absence of actual evidence, modelling is all that can be done. It is really a kind of benefit analysis—if we fix the price at that, it will do this; if we fix it a bit higher, it will do that—and we need to analyse all that and draw conclusions about the balance between interference with trade and social benefit. That will be quite a task.
Last week, one of the key players in this—the University of Sheffield—made it clear to us that, although it can provide information, the setting of the minimum unit price is ultimately a political decision.
It is, but it is made within certain constraints of evidence-based objective justification for whatever price is being suggested.
Given how subjective some of the evidence is, it is a difficult issue, but does support for minimum unit pricing from the medical profession—and, from a criminal justice perspective, the police—have any weight and help the argument for such a move? Indeed, might the support primarily of the health profession—after all, health is the important element in all of this—move us away from any prospect of a challenge?
The health profession thinks that there is a problem and that this looks like a way of dealing with it. The question whether the response is proportionate is not a medical issue.
But people in the profession have to witness and deal with the impact of excessive drinking.
No one is contesting the notion of excessive drinking as a social problem. The question is whether the bill is an appropriate response to it.
As members have no more questions, I thank both gentlemen for attending this morning and the Law Society for its previous input and the written evidence that it submitted this time round.
I welcome our second panel of witnesses on the Alcohol (Minimum Pricing) (Scotland) Bill. Nicola Sturgeon, the Cabinet Secretary for Health, Wellbeing and Cities Strategy, is accompanied by officials from the Scottish Government: Donald Henderson, head of the public health division; Marjorie Marshall, economic adviser on public health; and Edythe Murie, principal legal officer for health and community care.
Thank you, convener. Good morning to the cabinet secretary and her officials.
I am sorry, Gil. In my rush, I did not offer the cabinet secretary an opportunity to make an opening statement. I believe that she has one.
It is in your hands, convener. I am more than happy to say a few words of introduction.
I think that that would be better. My apologies.
That is all right. Thank you for the opportunity to give evidence to the committee today. I have followed your stage 1 consideration of the bill with interest, so I look forward to our discussion.
Good morning again. When we had a session with supermarket witnesses, I took it from what the Tesco representative said that supermarkets could see some benefits for consumers. Did I detect a softening up? Probably.
The question is interesting. I recognise very much that there is no single opinion in the supermarket sector—there are variances in opinion. Some supermarkets have supported the policy more than others have. I am keen to continue to work with supermarkets and the wider industry—that comment applies to the entire alcohol industry, although I am directing it to supermarkets at the moment. None of the motivation behind the policy is an intention to damage legitimate business interests. The alcohol industry is extremely important to Scotland. Our intention is to deal with the harms that are done by alcohol misuse.
The difficulty is that, as you highlighted, the controls in the Canadian model are somewhat different. However, every business, no matter how big it is, gets left with unsold stock. I am sure that Tesco and all the other supermarkets would love to find a way to sell all their items at the full price. However, I believe that the Government is thinking in the right way about how to address some of the problems. The fact that the cabinet secretary has said that she will consider the issue sends a good signal to people in the marketplace that we are considering the problems that might arise from minimum unit pricing.
As I said, I am happy to do that.
Good morning, cabinet secretary. May I turn to the issue of the social responsibility levy? A number of people have concerns about the fact that the firms that will be affected by minimum pricing might have a windfall of more than £100 million. We have suggested that we may recoup the cost of dealing with alcohol misuse. In that regard, I note the figures that you gave for the costs to the health service. The Scottish Government indicated previously that it did not intend to take forward the levy. Would you consider introducing the levy to take money from firms that will make more than £100 million and invest it in the health service?
I will introduce my answer with a few observations. The Parliament and the predecessor committee discussed this issue at some length when we considered the previous bill. I conceded then, and I concede now, that we want to find a route to deal with the issue.
I have two more questions. There are plans for an all-Ireland minimum price for alcohol. Last Thursday, there was a meeting between the Northern Ireland Minister for Health, Social Services and Public Safety, Edwin Poots, and the Republic of Ireland’s Minister for Health, Dr James Reilly, and Minister of State in the Department of Health, Roisin Shortall. They are hoping to agree a minimum price, and they are watching Scotland closely. What is your view on the proposal?
I have spoken to Edwin Poots about the proposal. During the past couple of weeks we have heard a lot about the world watching Scotland, for different reasons. Whatever the reason, it is a thoroughly good thing that the world is watching.
Various organisations say—you yourself have said—that there might be a legal challenge to the legislation. Witnesses from the Law Society of Scotland told us this morning that the measure might be challenged in the Scottish courts and might go to the Supreme Court, but they thought that a case might not go to Luxembourg. What is your view on a legal challenge?
Any act of the Scottish Parliament is potentially subject to legal challenge—that is a fact. The legislation that introduced the ban on smoking in public places was challenged in the courts, and the more recent legislation on display bans is still being challenged in the courts. This is simply my opinion, but I hope that if the Parliament passes the bill, people who might be considering such a challenge will respect the will of the Parliament, because we will have made a clear decision.
I associate myself with what you said in your opening remarks about the whole issue of alcohol misuse. I will not spend time debating the merits of the policy, but I will ask about one or two consequences of it.
First, I absolutely agree with Professor Brennan. We discussed that issue in the predecessor committee, in which Richard Simpson and I had many exchanges. The Sheffield study involves modelling: there is a lack of hard evidence around minimum pricing because no other country has done it in the form that we are proposing. However, the Sheffield model certainly points us very firmly in the direction of believing that it will have not only an impact, but a significant impact on the harms that we see from alcohol misuse.
I am interested to know where it may lead in policy terms. Colleagues have discussed the evaluation in strong terms, and they will possibly do so in their questioning, so I will leave that to them.
I am open to persuasion on that point. There was a sunset clause in the previous bill, which I proposed in one of my various attempts last time round to persuade people to give the policy a chance.
Thank you. It is certainly not my style to try to hit you with anything, cabinet secretary. I will leave that issue there.
Should the issue of notification arise, it will relate to the regulations, as we have already introduced the bill, which will be a piece of enabling legislation. Our firm view is that we are not obliged to give notification of the measure, by which I mean the bill and the regulations that will follow from it. In short, the reason for that is that the directive relates to standards for products. The measure is not state aid, nor is it setting a standard for alcohol. If, for example, we were to set regulations on the content of alcohol, they would fall within the definition of a measure that required notification. However, the measure that we are discussing does not set a standard. We are clear about that, and my understanding is that the UK Government agrees with our interpretation.
I understand that, and I couched my question in those terms. I am interested to hear you say that, notwithstanding the fact that the Government does not regard itself as being obliged to undertake notification, it has not ruled out the possibility that it might choose to do so.
We might come to the conclusion that, for a range of reasons, it is better simply to notify the European Commission. As I said, I have not ruled that out.
I thank the cabinet secretary for providing a draft of the latest Sheffield report, which is helpful. The tone of her introductory remarks was also helpful; she has taken a balanced view of the Canadian situation, which gives us information, but is different from that in Scotland, because in Canada wholesale supply and prices are controlled by the Government. Minimum pricing has been applied differentially not just to different types of alcohol, but to different products of the same type. Other than that, we have only the econometric model, backed by a lot of opinion. I think that it was Bertrand Russell who said that opinion, however frequently repeated, is still not evidence. Therefore, the cabinet secretary’s balanced and measured approach is extremely welcome.
I would be happy to comment. I am not making any judgment when I say that I was very clear about what we were passing—indeed, I recall discussions in Parliament about the restrictions and the limitations of what we were passing. Before I go on to those, I make it clear that I think that the legislation that we passed was a big step forward and that it is good. We went as far as we could on the discount ban in that legislation. It was because of devolved and reserved competence issues that we could not go as far as we perhaps wanted to. The fact that the regulation of price indications is reserved took us into difficulties in having what I would describe as a comprehensive discount ban. Even if we had been able to go that far with the discount ban, I was always of the view—I remain of the view—that a discount ban will be most effective when it is used in conjunction with a minimum unit price. If we have a minimum unit price, that will give us the optimal situation of those two policies working in tandem.
Thank you for that.
As was the case with the previous Sheffield report, the updated Sheffield report—I appreciate that perhaps not all members have had a chance to study it in detail—shows that the impact of a minimum unit price increases as we go up the scale from moderate to hazardous drinkers. That is the case at most of the prices that are identified. The overall impact and the impact on particular groups depends, to some extent, on the level at which the price is set.
I want to put on record the fact that the new Sheffield report shows that the effect is greater for hazardous drinkers as a whole than for hazardous drinkers in the 18 to 24-year-old group, which is the group that I was concerned about, with their binge drinking, their part in the night economy and the damage and crime that they commit.
Unless the convener wants me to, I do not want to delve into the fine detail of the Sheffield report, because I think that we would quickly start to lose each other. The fact that the impact on the hazardous drinkers as a whole would be greater than the impact on a certain sub-group of hazardous drinkers is not an argument against the policy. As I said, it is an argument for ensuring that the policy is part of a wider approach.
The revised Sheffield report shows that there has been a slight reduction in the effects on alcohol consumption that are predicted by the model—given a 50p minimum price, the reduction is 7.8 per cent instead of 8.7 per cent. That is, I presume, at least partly due to the increases in VAT and duty that were brought in by the Labour Government and, again, by the coalition Government. Of course, we know that, in April, there will be a further increase of 7.2 per cent—that is, the rise in the retail price index plus 2 per cent, which is a policy that the coalition has continued. Would it not have been helpful to have at least asked the University of Sheffield to say whether that might cause a further reduction in the likely gain from the introduction of minimum unit pricing?
To be fair to Richard Simpson, I think that he made the point himself that the reduction that he is talking about is slight. When it is put in the context of the problem that we face and the harms that I spoke about earlier, it seems even slighter. Richard Simpson is right that one of the reasons is price changes, but it is not the only factor. The other inputs that Sheffield updated were consumption data, purchase data, price, distribution data, mortality data, hospitalisation data, latest crime statistics data and labour force survey data. Sheffield took into account a variety of updated factors in order to produce its report.
I will move on to the mechanism for changing the minimum unit price. I asked the cabinet secretary about this in my previous role as a member of the Subordinate Legislation Committee. From all the evidence, we know that if the minimum unit price were to remain the same, the law of diminishing returns would affect the effectiveness of the policy. There must therefore be a mechanism for changing the price. Will you take us through your thoughts on how that will work?
I think Drew Smith asked me the question when I attended the Subordinate Legislation Committee. Two broad options are open to us. I dare say that there are variations on both, but I will stick to the broad options, at the moment. First, we could use an inflation-linked mechanism that went up in line with RPI or RPI plus a certain factor. Secondly, we could commit to reviewing the policy biannually or every five years. We are still considering what the best approach would be. Professor Stockwell has said that an automatic link to inflation would be best because the increase would happen automatically and people would get used to it. That argument has some force. Canada, of course, does not have to deal with EU law; we, on the other hand, are not necessarily sure that an approach whereby the price simply rose with inflation would retain proportionality, as is required by EU law. For example, inflation could be going up and consumption could be coming down.
That is extremely helpful. We have discussed the matter with other witnesses, and it seems to be reasonable to take that approach, for the reasons that you have outlined. Some witnesses suggested that the price should change much more regularly than you are considering. At what stage will Parliament know what your plans are?
Regarding reviewing of the minimum price, I am happy to give the committee a commitment that before we get to the final stage of the bill we will come to a final view on our approach, because Parliament should have the chance to reflect on and comment on that. As with setting the price initially, it will be a balanced judgment; it is important that we get it right.
Would you go as far as to say that you agree with Dr Rice that the mechanism is more important than the price that is set?
I have not seen exactly what Dr Rice said about that. The mechanism is equally important but I would not, to be fair, say that it is more important, because how we initially set the price is how we initially pitch the policy. However, it will certainly be important thereafter to keep the policy and the price up to date. That is why it is right to give the committee the commitment that we will come to a final decision before we get to stage 3 of the bill.
We welcome your invitation to respond on the matter, but it gives us a wee bit of a challenge because we have not considered it specifically, so we will need to discuss it, perhaps in today’s post-evidence session. Are there any other questions?
I will return to the social implications of minimum unit pricing. Your opening remarks on the consequences of abusive drinking were quite disturbing. To do nothing would be wrong. Dr Simpson said that some of the impacts of minimum pricing would be minimal, but that would be better than nothing.
Yes, I agree strongly with that. To be clear, I do not believe that the impact of minimum pricing would be minimal. To be fair to Dr Simpson, I am not sure that he argued that either; he argued that the impacts of minimum pricing are variable, which is a fair observation to make.
I return to why the Scottish Government is introducing the measure in the first place. When I look at the highly respected updated econometric modelling from the University of Sheffield, it strikes me that one of the most telling estimates in that document is the number of lives that would be saved in the first year of minimum unit pricing, which is estimated at 33. That is 33 human beings whose lives would be saved and 33 families who would not lose a loved one. It is important that we remember that when we discuss the policy. I will ask two questions. I understand that there are other factors, and we have heard about the need to demonstrate proportionality when setting the price and justifying the policy to the European Union, but will you consider carefully the number of lives that would be saved when you arrive at a minimum unit price? Secondly, when will you announce the minimum unit price?
The straight answer to your first question is yes. The relationship between a particular price and the harm reduction that results from it is a central factor. That is why we have set such store by the Sheffield report. As you indicated, that report is not the only factor that we take into account—we need to consider a range of other factors, such as alcohol price—but the modelling in it that suggests the benefits that would flow from set prices is a key part of our consideration.
Finally, I will ask about the public health levy on large retailers. We know from experience—Richard Simpson was eloquent on the subject earlier—about supermarkets’ ability to get round, if not the letter of the law, then at least the spirit and intention of the law, in their behaviour. What measures are you putting in place to monitor the effectiveness of the levy and to ensure that the supermarkets do not seek to undermine it? In answering that, will you touch on how the Government envisages the money will be invested to tackle alcohol misuse and take forward the specific measures in the alcohol framework?
The public health levy that John Swinney introduced is part of the business rates regime, so there are clear criteria for those who are subject to it. It is important that the levy be applied according to those criteria, and it will be. The income goes to local authorities and the measure is part of the approach that we have tried to take to assist local authorities, working with their health partners, to be more preventative in how they spend money. As with all our policies, we will monitor the impact of that.
Given the session that we have just had with the Law Society, are you getting into deep water there? Do we need to be careful in looking not just at the health outcomes but at supermarkets’ pricing policies or, as you mentioned earlier, whether it is unfair on smaller supermarkets that big ones can beat them competitively through selling drink? Is that dangerous territory for us? Does it take us out of the health agenda?
No. I say with respect that we are getting into that territory, convener. I argued earlier that because a minimum price for alcohol will apply regardless of where alcohol is sold and regardless of the type of alcohol, one of the side benefits—it is not the motivation for the policy, but it is a benefit—is that it levels the playing field between the corner shop and the big supermarket. At present, the big supermarket can cut the price of alcohol and absorb the costs elsewhere, but corner shops cannot do that to the same extent, so they can find themselves under severe competition from supermarkets. The minimum price policy will, as a natural consequence, level that playing field.
That is a bit contradictory, though, in terms of the outbreak of corner shop supermarkets and the need to sell alcohol at a higher price in some of our poorest estates. The bill will not prevent them from making a business out of it.
Sure—but the point is that the minimum price will apply across the board, so nobody will be able to sell alcohol below that price. That will level the playing field. Corner shops are already, by and large, more expensive places in which to buy alcohol. Minimum pricing will not make them cheaper, but will make the bigger retailers more expensive.
You referred earlier to engagement with Europe and your proposed visit there. What preparation have your officials and officials in Europe done to make the policy more accessible and to sell it to commissioners and European officials?
The aim is not really to sell the policy to commissioners. The view of commissioners and the Commission is influential but, ultimately, it is not the Commission but the courts that decide whether something is legal. Our responsibility, on which we have expended and will continue to expend the bulk of our efforts, is to get it right in setting a price that ensures that the policy complies with European law.
That is entirely sensible. As you have said, Canada does not need to take European law into account, but we do. I am not an expert on engagement with Europe, but I know from experience that it is wise and sensible when we are pursuing a policy. I have heard many a minister and cabinet secretary explain in the Parliament that, although they did not have a definitive legal position on a given issue—I am thinking of competition and ferries, which affected my constituency—they had a strong opinion from commissioners. I presume that that will be part of your discussion next week and that, before you go to Europe, your officials will have had some engagement on and discussion about what minimum price would be proportionate and what mechanism would be proportionate to keep the price relevant. Is that the case?
There is on-going and regular engagement between Scottish Government officials and European officials. That is right as we move through legislating and, I hope, into implementing the policy.
As I said, such engagement is entirely sensible, but the consequence is that Europe will influence the general policy. It would be silly to have discussions with officials otherwise. You are going out to Europe next week, the preparations have been made and you have some idea of what the Commission will say about the minimum price that will be set and about the mechanism. I presume that you agree that the paper on evaluation plans post-minimum pricing would also be helpful. Will you share with the committee the nature of the discussions that have taken place and the parameters that have been discussed?
The Commission is not going to say to us, “Set a minimum price at this level and you’ll be fine; set it at that level and you won’t.” That is not the nature of the discussions. The discussions that we have had and will continue to have will, along with all the other things that we are considering, be part of the process of reaching our view. I am clear in my mind that minimum pricing is not prohibited by the European Union but that there are certain tests that we must pass. The discussions will be part of the process that we will go through in coming to our decision, but they will not be the only part and we are not going to have the European Commission be definitive with us about where we should set the minimum price.
I understand that completely, but I take it that we are agreed that the EC will influence the debate, otherwise what is the point of you and officials visiting the Commission? What is the point of having detailed discussions if they are not genuine? Having the discussions is entirely sensible, cabinet secretary.
I know. I always do my best to be helpful to the committee, but I am not entirely sure what you are asking me to say beyond what I have already said. As I am sure members will appreciate, part of the reason for my visit is courtesy in order to keep the Commission and other interests in the European Union up to date with the development of our policy and the factors that we are taking into account. Yes, another part is to hear any observations or comments and, although I think that it is unlikely that they will give us advice, if they were to do so, we would hear it. All of that will, of course, become part of the decision-making process in which we are engaged, but it would be wrong to say that engagement with Europe or my meetings next week will be the deciding factor.
You continue to use the phrase “deciding factor”. I am suggesting not that the discussions will be the deciding factor but that it is entirely sensible to have them and that the European commissioners will influence the outcome of the Government’s policy. It would be daft otherwise, would it not?
Okay. I am genuinely trying to be helpful here; I am not trying to be adversarial with the convener in any way. It might be easier to answer the question about the influence that the discussions might have after I have had them. If it would be helpful to the committee, I am certainly happy to update you in that regard.
Thank you, cabinet secretary.
On the point that the convener has just made, I am sure that the European commissioners have an opinion on everything. They might even have an opinion on how to save the euro—probably or hopefully—but I do not know.
As the committee knows, I want to be as helpful as possible, but I do not necessarily want to read out the ministerial code. The committee knows the constraints on my discussing the content of legal advice. The same position applies to us in that regard as has applied to previous ministers in previous Administrations. I assume that the committee has had access to the very detailed summary of what we consider the legal position to be, which I provided to the predecessor committee when it considered the previous bill. It ran to, I think, about 10 pages of detailed advice. If members have not had a chance to look at it, I certainly advise them to do so because it is a full description.
Thank you.
Can I move us on to evaluation? I very much welcome the information that we have received from NHS Scotland and the movement on the study to be done by Queen Margaret University and Professor Chick, so that there will be a control group in Newcastle, which is what Professor Stockwell also recommended in response to a question that I asked. Of course, that relates to harmful drinkers, which I fully appreciate are the group that the doctors want to affect.
I absolutely take your point about hazardous drinkers and, although I do not know whether it will be possible to carry out the sort of work that you suggest, I am happy to ask NHS Health Scotland to find out. I will also ensure that your point about the evaluation of low-income groups is factored into evaluation plans.
Although I accept some of those points, I point out that the lowest two of the seven socioeconomic groups have a much higher death rate from alcohol cirrhosis. My personal experience—and none of the doctors has contradicted this—is that many of the people concerned start in higher-income groups with a good income, a house, a family and employment. When they become really harmful drinkers—and start, for example, to drink the 197 units a week mentioned in Jonathan Chick’s study—just about every one of them will have drifted into the lowest-income group by the time of their death. I have challenged the college on this on a number of occasions but it does not seem to know the answer. It has not said that that is the case, but it thinks that it might be a possibility.
I answered that earlier.
I am sorry—I must have missed that.
We hope to name the price at stage 2 but certainly before we reach stage 3.
We all accept that our relationship with alcohol could at times be much better. Do you accept that some of our past education and awareness programmes have not been particularly effective? If so, can we do anything to make education and awareness more effective in relation to the minimum pricing proposals?
The alcohol framework suggests a lot of different initiatives to tackle alcohol misuse, and education is an important one. The honest answer to your question is that the success of previous educational approaches has been variable. I am a great believer in the importance of education in all of this but experience tells us that it will not solve the problem on its own; indeed, if that were the case, one might assume that the problem would be on its way to being solved by now. Education is really important and people better qualified than I am are able to suggest the best ways of approaching young people and pitching these messages in the most effective possible way. It has a huge role to play, but it must be part of a bigger package that, in my view, must include pricing.
But it is something that you are happy to promote and see more of.
Absolutely.
As members have no more questions, I thank the cabinet secretary and her officials for their attendance. We now move into private session.
Previous
Subordinate Legislation