Official Report 234KB pdf
We move to agenda item 3, on the rural development programme. The minister has been joined for this item by John Hood from SEERAD, whom I welcome.
I am grateful to have the opportunity to bring the committee up to date on the consultation exercise. This meeting is an opportunity for me to hear the committee's views before—I stress before—I come to final decisions. The consultation has just closed, but we must still assess the responses. This is therefore a timely meeting.
Am I right in saying that the consultation is on the alteration to the rules, rather than on whether current funding to agri-environmental schemes should be increased or decreased?
Yes. The consultation is on the rules that govern the operation of the schemes.
At paragraph 2.7, the paper states:
As I said, my problem is that we are now in a much trickier situation. I agreed to the current scheme of modulation as a direct consequence of having secured in negotiation the offer of matched funding from the UK Treasury. It seemed that given the levels of modulation that were being postulated at that time that Scottish rural development would, on balance, benefit from modulation, in particular if that would secure additional matched funding.
From what I gather, the enthusiasts for further modulation are few and include possibly Mr Fischler, certainly Lord Whitty and presumably Margaret Beckett, but not the vast majority of Scottish farmers. Are you concerned that, if the Department of Environment Food and Rural Affairs pursued a pro-modulation policy—even up to 20 per cent, which is a figure that has been mentioned—that would take Scottish agriculture down the wrong path? Would SEERAD be able within EU rules to pursue a different policy by instituting variable modulation rates?
A number of member states—not just Mr Fischler's—are minded to seek a substantive change from pillar 1 to pillar 2 and have not closed their minds to doing so through modulation. The real issue is not whether there is disagreement between ourselves and our counterparts in England about the way in which we apply the policy, but whether modulation becomes the policy of the European Commission because it is favoured by a majority of member states. There are two serious considerations for me, as a Scottish minister. First, I would not want that modulation to be in addition to the current domestic arrangements. Secondly, as I have explained at length, it is important to me and to Scottish interests that the prescriptions that are available within the rural development regulations are suitably expanded to allow us to use the moneys that become available within pillar 2 for the benefit of more farmers and, I hope, to facilitate the implementation of instruments such as land management contracts.
We have been talking about agri-environment schemes. Can we move on to talk about less favoured areas?
Yes. Let us do that.
My concern is about the organic aid scheme. It is suggested that the organic aid scheme should be limited to hill farmers who have already identified a market for finishing their stock. That would be off-putting to many hill farmers, given the fact that it takes several years to transfer a business from ordinary farming to organic farming. To say that farmers must, before they can even start to go down that road, identify someone who will buy their stock, is asking them to do something that is nigh impossible. Nobody would be willing to draw up a contract with a farmer at that stage, when they are so far from the goal of having organic produce to sell. Have you given any thought to ways in which that problem could be overcome? What assistance will be available from the Executive to put hill farmers in touch with new applicants to the organic aid scheme, who would be involved in finishing? Will that be left to the farmers, which would create a huge barrier?
It will be left to farmers. The genuine disappointment is that we appear to be spending considerable sums from the organic aid scheme on certain hill farms where, frankly, the existence of other inputs is difficult to discern. In other words, it is almost impossible to identify which practices had to change on certain heather hills where no artificial fertilisers were used. It is not clear what environmental benefit is gained from that.
Is it your intent to focus on the lower-ground farmer—the arable farmer?
No. If it can be proved that there is a requirement on any farm, we will listen. We are not excluding people, but we are slightly concerned about the way in which things have developed. If the relevant society—the Soil Association, for example—says to someone on an upland farm that it is not prepared to give organic accreditation and that a conversion period will be required, we look at that. We want to be clear that there is a genuine environmental issue to be addressed—in other words, that there is evidence of the use of non-organic material. If that is the case, it is fine. The farmer will qualify. We are saying that we are not content to spend money and to get halfway down the hill, only to discover that there is no linkage and that the product is sold as a non-organic product. That does not represent value for money for the public purse.
I want to pursue the matter. As you know, most hill sheep are usually sold at local markets to dealers who move the sheep on to lowland farms for finishing. How do we address that situation? You talked about helping hill farmers to identify lowland farmers who could work as part of a chain. How far are you willing to go to help them to do that? That is where the barrier arises. If the hill farmers do not receive assistance because they do not usually have contact with the finishers, as that is usually done through a dealer, how can we put the chain together?
I do not have a precise answer. We are wrestling with that issue. We cannot have a situation in which someone wants to sell an organic lamb and simply puts in on the market. We must find people in the marketplace who are interested in dealing in organic lamb. We must identify those people before identifying which part of lowland land we need to direct assistance to in the conversion period, which is the other side of the equation that must be solved to complete the chain. It is not easy, but I hope that you recognise that the situation at the moment is extremely unsatisfactory and is not producing the amount of organic product that we should be producing.
I understand that. I do not have a problem with the aim but, unless we intervene to put people together, the effect of the policy will be to discourage people and create a barrier to conversion. We need to change the way that the market works for organic farming to get those people together. If we do not do that, we might as well forget about developing organic farming in upland areas.
We are keener on sorting out the other end than on abandoning the whole enterprise. I am much keener to get downstream and find people on the lowland ground who will deal with upland dealers and will allocate ground and have that ground converted for the purpose of producing organic produce. We have some work to do in that area. As I said, we have had constructive discussions with the societies responsible for organic accreditation, and that is beginning to generate some ideas on how we can deal with the issue. When I present my final proposal, I will have to fill in that bit.
Remembering my former employment, I recall that the most successful organic producers of lamb and beef deal directly with the supermarkets, buyers and abattoirs, rather than going through the traditional store market chain.
I have a question about the new LFA proposals. I understood that the idea was to disengage subsidy from production and to move from headage to hectarage. I must admit that I have not fully studied the new grazing categories, but it appears that category A and category B, which have the lowest stocking densities, will be very much worse off than farms with high stocking densities. That appears to be counterproductive to your original aims.
I do not think that that is right. As part of a wide-ranging consultation process, we found unanimity throughout the country that the former highland upland and lowland and southern upland and lowland classifications did not make sense and were not transparent to farmers in relation to how they recognised their own land. The scheme that is proposed addresses the carrying capacity of the existing land. The advisory committee drew up that new classification and believed that it was a fairer and more accurate reflection of the division of land within Scottish agriculture. Once those categories are drawn up, the percentages for the carrying capacity of the land can be applied. If you study those rules carefully, you will see that the proposal certainly does not disadvantage farmers in an obverse way.
I was talking to one or two farmers who thought that they could work out at this stage what their levels were going to be, and they appeared to be very much worse off than they would have been under the previous set of proposals. Bearing in mind the fact that the initial talk was about not having winners and losers, I was extremely worried by the latest set of proposals, particularly as they affect those in the Highlands and Islands.
I would have to see specific examples before commenting. When we made the proposals, we produced models illustrating the extent of winners and losers. Our modelling, by area office, indicated not only that the proposals were more specifically targeted but that they reduced, both in quantum and in amount, the total number of winners and losers. In addition, the proposals put quite a severe cap on the number of big winners at the top end. One of the objectives was to achieve a greater degree of equity and fairness throughout the country. In so doing, we narrowed the range of both winners and losers.
If I may speak as a South of Scotland MSP, one of my concerns about the original LFASS, which is backed up by the figures, was that it had the capacity to move a certain amount of input from the south of Scotland to points further north. I accept that the fragile area was designated for a reason, but will there be further shift of capital from the south and east of Scotland to the north and west, or has equilibrium been reached?
There will certainly not be any further shift. There was an inevitable shift in attempting to deal with the more fragile and remote areas. In the south of Scotland, because of the stocking densities and the rather different upland-lowland distribution, I believe that the new land classifications will go a long way towards addressing the anomalies that used to obtain. Perversely, people in the upland areas of the south seemed to be more disadvantaged as a result of the removal of the consideration of stocking densities. The introduction of land classifications that relate to the carrying capacity of the land, although not specifically to stocking densities, will go a long way towards addressing the problem.
I want to come back to the LFASS. Unlike Jamie McGrigor, I have not had the opportunity to run through the figures, but I welcome the building in of fragile areas. That is a great step forward. Why is a base reference period required, given that the scheme could be updated year on year? Do you want the moneys that are available from the scheme for each farm to remain constant? That might mean that no change in farming practice is required or that changes might be made that are not in keeping with the scheme.
I have a clear idea why we want the base reference period, but given the specific nature of the question, I will take the question to avizandum and reply to the committee. I have a niggling doubt about the last part of the question.
Members have no more questions, so I will wrap up the session. I have a question on the rural stewardship scheme and capital expenditure. Last time around, in order to spread the money as far as possible, you removed items of capital expenditure from the scheme. In your introductory remarks, you mentioned that, to facilitate that, you would try to spread capital payments over a number of years. Will the likely number of applications to the rural stewardship scheme allow you to do that, given the limit on the amount of money that will be available for the scheme? Will the restrictions on the organic aid scheme free up enough money for the rural stewardship scheme?
The organic aid scheme is unlikely to free up money. I aim to focus and target that scheme so that it gives better value for money. Rhoda Grant raised the fundamental issue of how that can be done. The intention is not to reduce the funding that is available through that scheme, but to deliver better outcomes. Although there have been additions to domestic funding and an increase in the funding that is available from modulation, demand has also increased.
I share that hope, minister. I thank you and John Hood for the large amount of time that you have spent with us this afternoon.
Previous
Integrated Rural Development