Corporation Tax
Good morning and welcome to the sixth meeting this year of the new Scotland Bill Committee. All those present should turn off their mobile phones and BlackBerrys as they interfere with the sound system. We have received apologies from David McLetchie and Nigel Don, and I am pleased to welcome to the meeting Derek Mackay, as Mr Don’s substitute. James Kelly and Stewart Maxwell will have to leave at some point to attend other committee meetings, but they will be back as quickly as possible so that they do not miss anything.
Don’t rush. [Laughter.]
Our first panel of witnesses—Ben Thomson of Reform Scotland; Garry Clark of Scottish Chambers of Commerce; and Martin Togneri of Scottish Development International—will give evidence on corporation tax, and I invite each of them to make a short statement to the committee. Perhaps we can kick off with Mr Thomson.
Certainly. I hope that committee members have received a paper that we published last week called “Devolution plus: Reform Scotland’s evidence to the Scottish Parliament’s Scotland Bill Committee outlining a new tax and spending framework for Scotland”. I am very happy to talk about corporation tax, but I point out that we have consistently made it clear that, used in isolation, it is a very blunt instrument if you are seeking to create an environment in which there is more fiscal responsibility or more incentives for MSPs to perform. You need a basket of taxes that you can move up or down to create the right sort of environment for Scotland’s economy. As I have said, corporation tax can be used, but it is a blunt instrument if used alone.
Over the course of most of this year, but particularly over the summer, Scottish Chambers of Commerce has been consulting its members on corporation tax. We gave evidence to the previous incarnation of the Scotland Bill Committee in the third parliamentary session and have looked at some of the issues that emerged in that committee’s report, specifically increased borrowing powers, air passenger duty and corporation tax.
Before Mr Togneri makes his opening remarks, I should point out that he is formerly of Scottish Development International. I am sorry about that, Mr Togneri.
You saved me pointing that out myself, convener. I do not represent the organisation any more, but I certainly used to work for it.
I ask committee members to indicate if they would like to ask a question and the panel to indicate if they wish to chip in on anything that is being discussed with a colleague. James Kelly will open the questioning.
Thank you, convener. Good morning, panel, and thank you for coming in this morning. There is no doubt that the discussion around corporation tax has developed. As Mr Clark said, he consulted his members over the summer. There has been more scrutiny of the impact of how powers over corporation tax would be used, and the evidence shows that the impact of devolving corporation tax would be adverse. Those who support it have tried to move the debate on by saying that it is about devolving the power, as opposed to about the impact. What are the panel’s views on that? Is it correct to try to separate the two issues or do panel members see them as being combined, in the sense that one needs to consider not only devolving the power over corporation tax but how it could be used in future before reaching any decision on whether it is correct to devolve the tax?
From our members’ point of view, what is done with the tax is far more important than where the decision-making powers lie. Whether decisions are made in one part of Government or another is less important. If we have localised setting of corporation tax rates, we could gain a localised advantage in terms of overall business taxes, which is attractive. However, there would be costs involved in devolving corporation tax and co-operation required from HM Revenue and Customs and others. The costs are real; the benefits are potential. Our members’ view is that we have to strike a balance and consider whether we will really see corporation tax rates at a level that will generate better economic prosperity in Scotland. At the moment, that is still only potentially the case. We do not know what politicians will do in five, 10 or 20 years’ time—neither do politicians.
I totally agree with Garry Clark that it is important to look at the details, but I do think that the question is in two parts, which I think is what James Kelly was asking. We would separate the devolution of the powers from what you get; otherwise you are in a situation where you are not really devolving the powers, because you are forcing the result on the person to whom you are devolving power. The first step is to devolve the range of tax powers. Let us face it: corporation tax is only £2.6 billion out of a £59 billion total spend of public sector money in Scotland, so we are talking about only 4.4 per cent of total Scottish Government spend—quite a small amount of devolved powers.
I agree with most of Ben Thomson’s points. The devolution of the power must be treated differently from the expectation of what will happen once the power is devolved. Whichever level of Government the power remains with, decisions will be taken about what the appropriate corporation tax regime should be in association with decisions about other fiscal measures. One needs to decide whether to devolve the power on the basis of where decisions about it are best made as opposed to on the basis of anticipating what the outcome might be—that is for the democratic process to decide.
What is your view on the evidence that has been submitted to the committee to date and other evidence in the public arena on this area and is it adequate to make an informed decision on whether we should go down the road of devolving corporation tax powers?
In my specific area of expertise, inward investment, the bulk of the evidence is very strongly in favour of devolving the power. Smaller economic systems have a strong track record of increasing their competitiveness for inward investment if they have control over the corporation tax rate and use it to create a differential between themselves and the locations with which they normally compete. A huge range of benefits apply in that regard. The evidence that various interests in Northern Ireland have submitted to various parliamentary committees about the potential to kick-start, as they put it, the Northern Ireland economy by virtue of lowering the corporation tax rate is quite compelling.
The question divides into two: there is devolving the powers and there is the rate of corporation tax that is used. On devolving the powers, our argument has always been that the more you devolve tax powers, the more you make that level of Government responsible and accountable through having to raise the tax that it spends. We would therefore argue strongly that you devolve the powers.
Our members have diverse views on the benefits of devolving any tax. They take their own views, and we do not have a collective view on the principle. However, they agree that the prospect of lower business taxes is attractive.
Martin Togneri talked about the corporation tax rate in the Republic of Ireland. We have heard from others that corporation tax has been one of a number of aspects of the Republic of Ireland economy that has attracted businesses such as Microsoft. However, the Scottish Government does not at present propose to reduce the rate in Scotland to 12.5 per cent, which suggests that it is not realistic to think that we would attract the same kind of benefits.
Scotland has been successful in attracting inward investment over many years. Without looking in detail at the figures for the years since I left SDI, I cannot comment on the split between new inward investment projects and expansion inward investment projects. However, from what I have read, Scotland has continued to be successful in attracting inward investment. Scotland provides a competitive environment in comparison with many locations.
Nevertheless, many foreign companies choose to invest here, despite the level of corporation tax.
I have just a quick one in answer to your first question. Everyone can produce evidence—the Holtham report, “Rebalancing the Northern Ireland economy” and the southern Ireland report on corporation tax—and we can probably conclude that it is inconclusive; people can always make their argument work. Scotland has had good success in attracting foreign companies, but those have often been subsidiaries. We berate the lack of headquarters in Scotland—because when times get tough, headquarters tend to be strengthened. Corporation tax also has an impact on certain sectors and headquartering. Manufacturing might be less affected, but the finance sector is certainly affected, and hedge funds and investment funds tend to go to other places. So, there is a geographical and sectoral bias in relation to corporation tax.
Corporation tax, when used as the only measure, probably is a blunt instrument, but it is an instrument. It is best deployed as one of a range of measures and much of the evidence, particularly in the summary of the paper submitted to the committee by Professor Hughes Hallett and Professor Scott, is that corporation tax has a particular impact on economic growth rates, particularly in small economies, and a particular impact on employment. Therefore, although it is one of a range of instruments, it is a particularly potent one. Given that it is best used in combination with other tools and not in isolation, whether to devolve power over it is a question that is analogous to having a job to do that needs a hammer, a screwdriver, pliers and a mallet. If the job could not be done without them all, you would not deny yourself the hammer because you could not do the job with the hammer alone; you would say that you need the hammer and the rest of the tools.
On volatility, over the past five years—albeit that, even in Scotland, we have been in a deep recession—corporation tax receipts have varied between £2.5 billion and £3.5 billion per year, according to “Government Expenditure and Revenue Scotland”. The variation is substantial and, in making spending plans, the Scottish Government must work out how to plug that gap. Therefore, corporation tax would be best set within a range of taxes.
I ask for quick responses to Mr Baker’s next question, as we have a lot to get through.
I will be very quick, convener. The position has been taken that the question whether the power should be devolved is separate from the question of the rate of corporation tax that should be set. Is there, at least, a strong likelihood that devolving power over corporation tax either to Northern Ireland or to both countries at the same time will create tax competition within the UK?
Although the threat of a race to the bottom is often raised in discussions about devolving corporation tax in a variety of regimes, academic evidence from Switzerland and the US suggests that such a race does not exist; that worry is simply not borne out by experience.
Sometimes decisions are made irrespective of what the corporation tax rate is. For example, a business that has chosen to invest in the UK might continue to invest in London or the south-east of England for a number of reasons, some of which have already been outlined, rather than to invest in Scotland simply because corporation tax here is a little bit lower.
Given that it represents only less than 5 per cent of the total tax take, we must not get carried away with the idea that corporation tax is the be-all and end-all. I do not think that it is a very good tax. After all, businesses are going to become more global in their manufacturing, distribution and where they are headquartered, and that will happen irrespective of national boundaries. Corporation tax is becoming difficult to pin on corporations that are, more and more, choosing to pay tax wherever they want in the world—which, of course, will be in environments that have the lowest tax. I see that all the time in businesses; indeed, I am dealing with Luxembourgish and Belgian companies on exactly that issue.
My one caveat to Ben Thomson’s remarks is that transfer-pricing regulations limit the degree to which companies can use low-tax regimes for brass-plating. Microsoft might well pay a huge amount of its corporation tax in Ireland, but it also undertakes a huge amount of its European activity in that country. It is a major research and development and software manufacturing hub, but that would not have been the case had the ability to move profits between regimes not been regulated by transfer-pricing measures. Microsoft cannot enjoy a low-tax regime with a brass-plated operation; it has to conduct real economic activity in order to get the benefit.
We could debate that point for a long time.
Not just now, Mr Baker.
Indeed, convener.
I am interested in compliance issues. Mr Togneri kindly gave us some information about inward investors; he said that they are used to dealing with different countries around the globe and so have expertise in dealing with different compliance regimes. What about indigenous businesses? What is your experience—from hearing from your members and from your work—of the additional compliance costs on indigenous businesses within the UK, which perhaps have operations in Scotland as well as in England, Wales and Northern Ireland?
Others probably have more expertise than I have on domestically headquartered companies. My take is, first, that domestically headquartered companies have to comply with a whole range of taxation and other compliance issues—not just corporation tax—so to submit the necessary returns to satisfy a devolved regime’s corporation tax requirements would not be a hugely significant extra burden. The real issue is that successful domestically headquartered—I prefer that term to “indigenous”, which always makes me think of fauna and flora—companies tend to want to expand internationally very quickly when they are relatively young. The specific issue with regard to corporation tax is that successful domestically headquartered companies in Scotland also operate internationally and therefore have to comply with a range of corporation tax regimes in the countries in which they operate. I really do not think that compliance costs are a big issue.
Compliance costs need to be taken in the round. Obviously there will be compliance costs in the devolution of income tax to Scotland through the Scotland Bill, too. There will be additional costs in administering the tax in Scotland, which will ultimately be passed on to the taxpayer. The costs will be more or less burdensome on different businesses, but they are a real issue.
On a scale of one to 10, how anxious would you say your members are about the compliance and complexity issues?
They are not hugely anxious. As I said, the disbenefits could be vastly outweighed by the benefits.
Often, the primary focus in relation to tax seems to be on the actual rate of tax. Two other things are equally important to businesses: simplicity and service. I do not know how many of you are familiar with “Tolley’s Tax Guide”. I have had to deal with it and I can tell you that it is now three times longer than it was 15 years ago and the font has gone down from 12 point to 10 point, so my reading glasses have had to be magnified.
Given your experience of “Tolley’s” over the past 15 years, the direction of travel is towards more complexity. Do you really believe that that will be turned around if taxes are devolved?
There is a real appetite among the electorate for somebody to come in and say that the taxation system is far too complicated. I will have to check the statistic, but I think that something like 85 per cent of MPs have to get an accountant to do their self-assessment tax returns. I certainly have to get one, because it is just far too complicated. People will see real benefit in someone saying that they will cut through all that and simplify the tax system. Parliament might not take them, but if it had the devolved powers to do those things, that would be one of the benefits that could be offered both to corporations and individuals.
There has been a desire to do that at UK level too, but the opportunity has not been taken because there has also been a desire to target and close loopholes to make the UK tax regime more effective. I am not sure that Scotland would want to be any less targeted—or would it?
That is a UK failure.
The UK has a problem with its historical legacy. As with software, there is a problem when we keep adding more and more. A previous Chancellor of the Exchequer was—dare I say it?—good at creating lots of taxes, certainly in the business world. We have tax incentive schemes with all the bells and whistles that sound good but which have reams of complications underneath, which confuses businesses. We are starting to see some of the problems with, for example, enterprise zones, business expansion schemes and film schemes. Those are slightly coming back at us, because they are so complicated. There would be a benefit if a political party said that it was prepared to create a much simpler taxation scheme. Scotland has only 5 million people, and it would be much easier to introduce a simpler scheme during the setting up of a new system than it would be to introduce it to a historical system with all its complications.
Mr Clark mentioned HMRC, and Mr Thomson then said that it was “a guddle”. That is concerning because, from what we understand, we will be dependent on HMRC in relation to income tax, corporation tax and all sorts of revenues. We understand that the Office for Budget Responsibility has more of a relationship with HMRC than it does with the Treasury, even. How robust is HMRC?
Almost daily, our members raise issues with us about HMRC. However, it is part of the framework that the bill sets out, and it would probably be part of the framework for any devolution of corporation tax. Given that that is the environment that we have been placed in, we need to ensure that HMRC works better. I am attracted by Ben Thomson’s wish for a move to a far less complex tax regime. That would be vastly appealing to our members, even with the same rates of tax. If the system was more straightforward, it would certainly cause fewer problems. It might encourage businesses to site here if they could comply easily with the local tax systems. Our members regularly have issues with HMRC, so it needs to work better. In recent years, it has made moves to improve its customer service although, judging by some of the e-mails that we get, that has not necessarily borne fruit.
Those are some of the practicalities, but when HMRC comes out with total figures, can we trust them?
I am not sure that I am qualified to comment on that.
Does either of the other gentlemen feel qualified to comment?
If you are looking for statistics, one that I read in a paper—so I am not sure that it is totally true—is that HMRC has the lowest employee satisfaction of any Government department. That might be symptomatic. Two large departments were merged. In principle, it is good to have greater co-ordination, but the historical factors in trying to merge existing departments have created a bit of a dinosaur. That is similar to what happened with the Financial Services Authority.
Is HMRC collecting the tax that it should be collecting?
There are various reports on the amount of taxation that is not collected properly, although I do not have the statistics on that. Two problems have been identified in the press: HMRC has been widely criticised for taxing at the wrong rate and for having to give rebates. Those difficulties are symptomatic of an organisation that is not firing on all cylinders. As I said, the system is a bit of a guddle.
I do not think that I ever heard inward investors complain about HMRC’s requirements being particularly difficult to comply with. If anything, the most frequent complaint about tax authorities that I heard from inward investors was about the US Internal Revenue Service. Most of them happened to be US companies, which complained—to me, certainly—more vociferously about having to comply with the IRS’s requirements than they did about having to comply with those of the HMRC.
Some of our accounting members have said to us that if HMRC adopted a slightly more flexible approach in its dealings with businesses and individuals, it would probably collect a lot more tax rather more quickly than it does at the moment.
I have a couple of quick questions. You will be aware that the income tax proposals in the Scotland Bill rely on Treasury forecasting. What do you think about the Treasury’s reliability in forecasting accurately the amount of income tax that would be generated by Scotland in future years?
I have never rated Treasury forecasts as being particularly good. Statistical analyses would show that Governments are not particularly good at long-term forecasting.
I agree with almost everything that Ben Thomson has said. Treasury forecasts have been notoriously unreliable for many years—especially recent forecasts, as we have seen. Obviously, the United Kingdom coalition Government’s proposal to raise the threshold for paying income tax towards a £10,000 base affects the calculations on how valuable the proposed devolution of Scottish income tax would be.
Is it the case that there would not be one-off negotiations at the start but, rather, there would have to be negotiations almost every single year because of arguments about forecasting, changes in rates and so on? In effect, there would be an on-going argument about what exactly the figures should be, as Mr Thomson said.
I agree. If you were going to pass across a tax, you would want to give across the whole power so that things were clear and simple. The Scotland Bill would create on-going tension between the Treasury and the Scottish Government around income tax. There is always tension between the Treasury and the Scottish Government, as the Treasury sets the budget, but there would be tension around not only the setting of the budget, but around creating the formula. The formula would have to be continually adjusted, and both sides would see that continual adjustment as something of a black art.
There seem to be two possible solutions. The Treasury could have some responsibility to the Scottish Government or the Scottish Government could have some responsibility to the Treasury, but there is no proposal to that effect. The Treasury would remain responsible solely to the UK Government. Alternatively, there could be a cleaner and simpler system in which all the tax was transferred to the Scottish Parliament, so there would not be arguments about such things. You hinted at that.
The basis of our philosophy is that the level of government that is responsible for spending a particular tax should be responsible for raising that tax. Under our proposals, if responsibility for national insurance and VAT were given to Westminster and all the other taxes were devolved, there would be a clean and simple system that would cover what Westminster had to spend on Scotland—on defence and aspects of welfare and foreign policy financing—and which would leave Scotland to raise what it would spend. That would make things nice and clean, and we would not have the Barnett formula. If the Barnett formula has to be continually readjusted, we will always run into the difficulty of the Treasury and the Scottish Government having to find a way to readjust it to fit what happens in reality.
That is correct. It illustrates why, at the moment, it is very difficult to take a hard and fast position on any of the proposals in the Scotland Bill or the additional proposals outwith it. That is one of the reasons why we and our members are keen to continue to engage in the debate for as long as it takes.
Richard Baker referred to a PricewaterhouseCoopers report that underplayed the significance of corporation tax as a motivator for inward investment. That is quite interesting, because last year PricewaterhouseCoopers produced another report on corporate taxes and economic growth which found that, right across the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development countries, corporation tax had a very significant effect on a number of investment decisions. I know that we have talked about the headline rate of corporation tax, but what is interesting about the earlier PricewaterhouseCoopers survey is the effect that lower corporation tax had on research and development, capital formation and entrepreneurial activity. What do you think corporation tax could achieve in those areas?
There is no doubt that corporation tax will have an effect to a greater or lesser degree; much will depend on the rate. The rate’s being equal to the Irish rate of 12.5 per cent would clearly have a stronger influence on business decisions than its being the notional rate of 20 per cent that the Scottish Government has talked about in recent weeks.
My experience and knowledge of the matter, as far as it goes, is that lowering corporation tax is generally beneficial to economic growth and employment generation. On its specific impact on things such as research and development or entrepreneurship—this comes back to the point that others and I have made already—it is probably best not used in isolation. I believe that lowering tax would have a beneficial effect on R and D and entrepreneurship, but so would other things.
All sorts of reports have been produced. The one thing that hits me between the eyes is that, despite all the problems in southern Ireland, the biggest thing that they have clung to, against fierce opposition in Europe, is that they want to keep their corporation tax low. If they did not feel that that was absolutely vital to their economic growth they would have given it up, given the pressure that they were under. To me, that really hammers home the point that low corporation tax is important for economic growth.
I was struck by the evidence in Mr Clark’s submission that some of his members had commented that they had lost contracts to Irish companies because of the lower corporation tax there. Can you expand on that? Was it quite a significant problem?
We have had quite a lot of that, particularly over the past year and particularly in the construction sector.
I see. I take it that that would be exacerbated if corporation tax were to be devolved to Northern Ireland, too.
That is quite possible. It has certainly been apparent in the construction sector and is manifesting itself through our procurement system.
Over the summer, HMRC published a paper on corporation tax in which it estimated that it raised £2.6 billion in Scotland, but it then suggested that lowering the rate according to the Scottish Government’s proposals would wipe out that £2.6 billion—it basically did not calculate a beneficial effect from lowering corporation tax in Scotland. What do you think of the idea that the £2.6 billion would be entirely wiped out?
I tried to work out the numbers. They are inconsistent. If the whole tax take is £2.6 billion, it should not go from £2.6 billion to nothing if the tax is reduced from 26 per cent to 12.5 per cent; something should be collected. I do not think that anyone has got to the bottom of the figures. I can only suggest that one figure excluded corporation tax on oil companies—I think that the £2.6 billion excluded it—and the other did not. That is the only reason I can possibly give, but you probably need to ask HMRC for the reason.
The only light that I can shed on that debate is to say that a methodology that does not take account of the potential benefits, but only of the costs, is flawed.
I have specific questions for each of the panel members.
On whether anyone argues that there should be fewer levers, it depends what the objective is for the Scotland Bill. If we start off by asking how we create the best system to incentivise MSPs and others to work most efficiently, it is theoretically sensible to have a basket of tools. However, if the objective for the bill is to deliver as few powers as one can get away with, devolving only one or two taxes makes sense.
What is your definition of “quiet”?
As has been highlighted, we have talked of the existing dangers to our economy from construction companies in Ireland winning contracts in Scotland, as we look to move into a rebuilding phase in the economy. Any increase in differential with Northern Ireland might exacerbate that problem.
But do you accept the premise that to be responsive, we must have the power, and that it would be better to have it in advance of the difficulties than after them?
If we have a lower rate of business taxes, we will be in a far better position to compete.
There is a slight danger of confusion between headquarters functions and high-value-added functions. Microsoft has been mentioned a few times. When it decided to locate in Ireland, it was never considering relocating its headquarters from Seattle to Dublin—
That would be ambitious, even for the Scottish Government.
Nonetheless, we should look at what Microsoft actually does in Ireland. It has a major global centre of software research and development and manufacturing that it would not have without the encouragement of the corporation tax regime.
We have focused a lot this morning on cutting corporation tax but we must remember that we could do other things with it, too. For example, if it were devolved, we could reward socially and environmentally good behaviour.
Gosh, your questions covered a range of topics—and I have 35 seconds in which to answer. I will be as brief as I can, convener.
You clearly believe that these things should be devolved and then made the responsibility of whatever level of government.
Yes, they should be devolved. However, we could also do things more efficiently. If, as your manifestos suggest, you want sustainable long-term economic growth, the fact is that having too high a tax take will impede that. I am very happy to send the committee one of our papers showing a definite correlation between lower tax take and economic growth.
You could of course lower corporation tax if you had the power to do so. Indeed, Ben Thomson has already mentioned the worldwide trend in that direction. It is unlikely to happen but if you had the power you could exercise it to raise taxes.
Historically, our members have had concerns about politicians controlling taxation. When business rates were controlled at local government level, they increased at a higher rate than council tax bills—or, back in the day, domestic rates bills. In its early years, the current Administration made some positive moves on business rates but over the past couple of years there have been a few increases for medium-sized or larger businesses. The suspicion of our members is that taxes can go both ways and that corporation tax could be another example of that.
Thank you very much, gentlemen. We really appreciate your excellent input.
Air Passenger Duty and Aggregates Tax
I am pleased to welcome Amanda McMillan, the managing director of Glasgow airport, and Mr Richard Bird, from the British Aggregates Association. Mr Bird has come along at short notice to replace his colleague at the table—thank you very much for that. I invite you both to make short statements: Ms McMillan, on air passenger duty; Mr Bird, on aggregates tax.
Good morning. Thank you for the invitation to speak this morning. We have submitted written evidence in advance and we are happy to supply any supplementary evidence that is requested today.
Thank you.
Thank you very much for inviting me along. I am from the British Aggregates Association, which is a trade association for the smaller, independent quarry operators. For the past 10 years, we have fought the Westminster Government over the imposition of the aggregate levy. As the matter has come up in Scotland, this is, I hope, an opportunity for me to explain to you the situation concerning the levy.
Thank you. Derek Mackay has the first question; I suggest that we stick to the subject that he raises and then move to the next one to make things simpler.
I am delighted to be the first speaker, in that case. I have looked at the evidence closely; I found the BAA Airports submission helpful, and I direct my question to Amanda McMillan specifically.
That was about six questions.
I have more.
Okay. I will take the general point on the industry first, because it might help to set the context.
That is all very helpful.
When we spoke to the representative from the Scottish Chambers of Commerce, he confirmed many of your points. There are interesting aspects of their evidence that look to the future. They talked about how Scotland is now more dependent on air travel in order to do business. They also mentioned that when high-speed rail is opened up for England, the UK Government’s plan is that it will stop at Manchester and Leeds. The Scottish Chambers of Commerce suggested that that makes it more important that we incentivise air travel to Scotland. Will high-speed rail cause problems that will have to be addressed through APD?
I am not entirely sure that I understand the question. Are you referring to regional travel within the UK?
Part of what those witnesses are saying is that high-speed rail, which will provide a high-speed link to the continent, will stop at Manchester and Leeds and will not come to Scotland. Therefore, Scotland will continue to be very dependent on air travel.
Forgive me—I thought that you were talking about high-speed rail coming to Scotland, but you meant it not coming to Scotland.
To clarify, are you entirely opposed to APD, or do you want it to be devolved so that we might have more control over what we use it for?
I am sorry if I was not clear about that. We recognise that aviation must pay its way. Our opposition is about further increases in the quantum. We are hugely concerned about the current levels and the UK Government’s appetite to grow them. We are against the current levels of taxation, but we are not against taxation of the industry as a principle. We are keen on the concept of devolution because the proposals to date have suggested creativity in the use of the tax in support of the industry. Is that clear?
Yes. If, for example, we were to offer a reduction in APD if night-time flights were rescheduled to daytime to reduce condensation trail impacts and various emissions, would you consider that?
We would be open to any suggestions. That one would have a marginal impact, because we do not do a lot of night-time flying in Scotland. Edinburgh airport is active during the night for cargo, but there are few passenger movements. The same is true of Glasgow airport. We have to look at operating models. People want to be global travellers so, by necessity, that means some unsocial flying times, such as leaving Scotland at 5 o’clock in the morning to get to another part of the world. That is the operating model that makes airlines viable. If taxation were to restrict airlines to a model that was hugely different and not viable compared with that which is available in other countries, I am not convinced that they would settle and come here. The measure that you suggest would not have a huge impact, because we do not do a lot of night-time flying.
A few years ago, the University of Oxford produced a document that suggested the existence of a UK tourism deficit, because far more people were using airports to leave the country than were coming in. The study found that, at the time, for every £1 spent by an overseas resident visiting here, £2.32 was being spent by UK residents going overseas. According to the Press Association report on the issue, the deficit had hit £17 billion. Are you aware of whether that deficit is reducing? Are we successful in attracting people here or do more people still leave the country, which has an impact on attempts to build our domestic tourism business?
It is a complex argument. At Glasgow airport, the majority of traffic is outbound. I do not have the figures to hand, but that translates into the deficit that you mention. However, we must be careful, because there is huge employment at the airport and the business has huge economic value. To my mind, outbound travel is not necessarily a deficit to the country, because it involves our population travelling and doing business.
I appreciate that people need to fly—especially given our Scottish islands. We live in the modern world. However, a report by Sewill in 2005 took account of all the subsidies that airlines receive. Sewill found that every aviation job was subsidised to the tune of £45,000 per year. That was in 2005. Do you have a comment on that?
I have not seen the report, but I would be happy to reflect on it and feed back to you. I am curious about the subsidies that you described, because I am struggling to think what subsidies per se airlines that operate from Glasgow are getting. However, I am more than happy to take a look at the report and respond in writing, if that is appropriate.
Thank you.
There is a circle to square in relation to the economic benefits and environmental impact of air travel. APD was established not as an environmental tax but for revenue-raising purposes. How can the aviation industry square the circle and ensure that it is appropriately taxed, given its benefits and disbenefits for the economy?
I understand that APD was intended as an environmental tax. As you rightly pointed out, it has moved away from being that and now seems to be more of a blunt tax on the industry. Reports that I have seen suggest that some £2.2 billion goes into the Exchequer from APD, which, based on calculations, is in excess of the environmental impact of aviation. The industry is paying its way, albeit not through a mechanism that is based on environmental considerations.
You argue that APD in the UK has been pushed so high that it puts you at a competitive disadvantage compared with other European countries. Is there a comparator country that you can point to? Is there a small northern European country that does better than Scotland in that regard?
I direct you to the evidence that we submitted, rather than get into point scoring. The table on page 6 shows the variation across Europe. It is quite hard to show what happens, because there is not a universal language on the issue—it is not as if the tax is always called APD. There are different types of taxation.
Fundamentally, you are in favour of the devolution of air passenger duty as long as it is cut. Is that correct?
Yes. It is always a bit nerve wracking to discuss devolution, because it does not give us any certainty about what will happen. The last panel of witnesses pointed that out as well. We are supportive of a more pro-aviation approach to APD, which is certainly how devolution of the tax has been described so far. A devolved APD would align itself to Scottish aviation more appropriately, which is why we are supportive of it.
Aside from the pros and cons of devolving air passenger duty, are you confident that devolving it would be compliant with EU law?
EU law is definitely a concern. The route development fund was suspended because of EU law and some of the creative ideas for using APD may be subject to similar rules.
Obviously, when we pass legislation, it has to be EU compliant. We cannot pass a bill and hope that it is compliant.
The message that I need to get across today is that, even if APD is devolved and we cannot be creative, the quantum is already excessive in comparison with other European countries. Therefore, our primary concern is not to have that quantum increased.
Thank you very much, Ms McMillan. We move on to questions about the aggregates levy.
The levy in its current form is probably dead in the water. When we heard that the Westminster Government was talking about devolving it to Scotland, our first reaction was that, by the time it was devolved, it might not exist. We felt that we should warn the Scottish Government that it may be being promised something that no longer existed. That is still valid. As I said, we have a court case in which we hope that a judgment will be given within 12 months.
Let us say that the EU issues were resolved and that the aggregates levy was devolved to Scotland. What is your organisation’s view of what Scotland should do with it? I think that I know the answer to that.
You would have to make it fair. You cannot tax one guy and not the other; everyone must be taxed at the same level. We live in a democracy, and our complaint is not with the aggregates levy as such but with the fact that the Government taxes some companies and not others based on geological outcome, which is a complex system. As I said earlier, it is a bit like taxing whisky and not gin.
I should warn you that a representative of the Scotch Whisky Association is sitting behind you.
That is why I made that comment. Everyone then understands exactly what I am talking about. If the Scottish Government brings in an aggregates levy, that is fine—that is its job. All that we ask is that the levy is fair. If it will be a finance-raising measure, that is fine, but do not cover that up by suggesting that it is some sort of green tax and try to hide behind that. Let us be open about it.
Let us assume—this is full of assumptions—that a fair tax was imposed. Do you think that the revenue from that should be hypothecated to, for example, green projects, which you mentioned? Would you like that money to be used for specific projects or put into the general pot?
If we say that 60 per cent of it will go back to Government anyway, one has to scratch one’s head. Roughly speaking, we do something in the order of 30 million tonnes of aggregate so, at £2 a tonne, that is £60 million. As 50 per cent of it is for public works, £30 million will go back into the coffers. You could argue that, if we did not have the levy in the first place, we would build motorways or railway lines. Over the past 10 years, Scotland must have paid £300 million to Whitehall, which would have built the Waverley line with some change left in your pocket.
I must admit that I am not a huge expert on all this. You can perhaps explain it a little bit. You said that granite gets taxed heavily but slate does not. What sort of percentage of value—obviously it is nil at one stage—does the tax go up to?
I will answer your first question first. The aggregates levy does not apply to slate. The idea was that there were hundreds of millions of tonnes of waste slate lying around in north Wales that could be used as an aggregate, so slate was relieved and was not subject to the tax. The fact that, for every 7 tonnes of roof slate that are made, about 90 tonnes are dumped, seemed to make that a bit daft from an environmental point of view. China clay sand in Cornwall and parts of Devon is not taxed either. For every 2 or 3 million tonnes of China clay product, about 20 million tonnes of waste product are dumped down in Cornwall, but that is not taxed.
Is your summary argument that things are a real mess?
Absolutely. The whole thing is a total, complete mess.
And if the Scottish Government took things over, we could not do any worse.
The whole thing is still a mess. I will have a meeting next week. People are now asking about the filler that is used in asphalt, which is exempt, because fillers that are used in paints and chemicals—limestone filler, for example—are exempt. Somebody decided that the filler in asphalt is not a filler but an aggregate, so we have to go down to Whitehall and say, “Well, no, guys, it’s really something to do with the bitumen.” There can be back charging for three years, which would put Amanda McMillan’s runway costs up even more. The situation is a complex mess.
You have convinced me that it is a mess.
I have learned more in the Scotland Bill Committee about aggregates than I ever thought I would. I was going to ask about hypothecation, but you have already covered that, so the next member may ask a question.
Why am I not surprised that the Calman commission suggested devolving a tax that may never be levied?
Yes. To be serious, we could all get around the table and say, “Well, what do we need and where is it best to put this money in?” I am thinking of rural communities in particular. Our industry is a rural industry, so we would like to see money going back into villages and rural communities. I sit on the local community council and know the problems that local authorities have in providing money for extra car parking, play areas for kids and so on. We would like to get involved in that. I am talking about local issues rather than something that is lost in the corridors of power. If we are serious and people want to talk, we would look at the local and communities issues, and see whether we could come up with something, bearing in mind that 50 per cent or perhaps more—perhaps 60 per cent—of all aggregates go back into public works anyway. It seems a bit silly to take the money from rural communities only to put it back somewhere else.
Sure.
At the moment, the legal fees have cost us £900,000. Members ought to be aware of an interesting thing. The lawyers have said—and I have seen this written in European Community official papers—that, with an illegal tax, the money has to be paid back. That is an extremely interesting point. If we go back even three years, we are talking about £1 billion. It will be most interesting to see what happens. Getting back our legal fees would be very nice.
Does Willie Rennie want to grasp the hot potato?
Mr Bird, you have repeatedly said that the issue is fairness, but is the issue really the level of the tax? Is it the overall levy take that concerns you?
It is fairness that concerns me, to be honest. Let us be clear. If the Government had come along 10 years ago and said that it was going to tax aggregates used in construction, that would have been okay—end of story. However, it did not do that; it said that it would tax granite but not slate. We said, “Well, wait a minute. We already use slate in roads. The road to Holyhead was all done with slate aggregate.” The Government ignored that; it did not want to know. The poor guy who had a granite quarry had to pay £2 per tonne—or rather, £1.60 in those days—and the guy with the slate quarry next door paid nothing. The tax was unfair.
If the levy is devolved and you come back to give evidence to the committee, I will remind you that you said that you did not want a reduction in the levy.
I think that we would rather talk around the table. HMRC talked but, unfortunately, it did not listen; it laughed at us and said, “Oh, but you would say that, wouldn’t you?” We said, “Well, look, you are going to get yourselves into one big hole here, guys.” Customs said, “Rubbish. We know what we are doing.” Here we are, 10 years later.
I thank both witnesses for coming along to give us the benefit of their knowledge. We have had an extremely interesting discussion.
Excise Duties
I reconvene the meeting and welcome everyone back.
Obviously, our industry is closely involved in excise duty, so we have widely consulted our members on its devolution. We noted with interest the view in the Scottish National Party’s manifesto, which it thought was in line with our view, that excise duty should be reformed, but there are many uncertainties about the devolution of excise duty and how that would work in practice. That is important to us, given that the UK is our fourth-largest market.
Thank you for the opportunity to give evidence, convener.
I thank you for the opportunity to give evidence today, and I apologise for not submitting written evidence—unfortunately, the timescale between the request appearing and the closing date for submissions prevented me from doing so.
I bet that Patrick Browne is glad that it was not him who produced that campaign.
Just for the record, the British Brewers Association, as it was in 1933, was separate from the Scottish organisation. I am happy to disown that one.
Campbell Evans will not need to sit between the two of them after all.
I thank you all for coming along, and for your submissions. I address my question to Dr Gillan. My understanding is that, if we consider excise in terms of the amount that it raises rather than looking at varying rates, alcohol tax raises a disproportionate amount of our revenue stream in Scotland. You alluded to that when you spoke about putting the money into preventative spend. What type of health programmes could we fund with that money? I understand that in Scotland we raise in excess of £250 million from excise. From a medical point of view, how would you use that money for preventative spending?
There is definitely evidence on that. A Scottish needs assessment was carried out two or three years ago to identify both the number of people who required access to alcohol support services and what was available to them. It found that we were falling significantly short in our provision. I cannot remember the exact figures—I can get them for you—but if, for example, 10 in however many people required access to alcohol support services, our current services were able to provide services to only three or four of them.
I was fascinated by the 1930s material that you quoted. Obviously, the main drink back in those days would have been Campbell Evans’s product—whisky. The recent escalation in alcohol-related harm cannot really be attributed to Scotland’s national drink.
Not at all—and I am sure that Campbell will confirm that. The big problem is cheap vodka. All the recent sales data has strongly identified cheap vodka, and evidence from accident and emergency admissions for acute alcoholic poisoning, particularly of young people, shows that we have a real problem with cheap vodka and high-strength ciders. We do not get anyone turning up in A and E who has had a few malt whiskies of an evening.
Mr Evans, do you want to come in on that point—or will you haud yer wheesht just now?
I should possibly haud my wheesht, but I would rather say that we should address the problem of alcohol misuse, no matter what people are drinking. Everyone must be involved in tackling the issue by changing people’s attitudes and the acceptability of drunkenness, which, as Evelyn Gillan said, was not acceptable many years ago. I do not think that anyone should take any credit; we should recognise that it is an issue that we need to address as a country.
I will bring in Derek Mackay quickly on that point.
I want to ask specifically about whisky. Young folk getting tanked up on Glenmorangie is not the image that comes to mind in the central belt. Why is the Scotch Whisky Association in principle against the transfer of powers from Westminster to Scotland, especially when Westminster already levies a higher charge on the whisky industry?
The fundamental point is that we are unclear as to what the market would look like. As I said, the UK is our fourth-largest market, so our ability to trade within it is important to us. There are a number of companies, large and small, that have a single distribution system for the UK that sees products being put into duty suspension and then released into the market. I presume that that would have to change in some way for an England and Wales market and a Scottish market. None of that has been explained, and the legality of a single rate has still not been clarified. We are operating in the dark in terms of what the Scottish Government proposes, so we look forward to seeing its paper.
Okay. So you would describe it maybe—
No, Derek, it was one question only on the back of the previous one. I will bring in Richard Baker.
We have heard good points about the potential benefits of increasing alcohol duty and, indeed, of reforming the alcohol duty system. Of course, we are here to talk about a specific proposal on excise duty. My understanding of the Scottish Government’s position is that it wants the ability to increase excise duty on alcohol to recover the profits raised from introducing minimum unit pricing. I would like the panel’s views on that because it strikes me as quite a complicated proposal, given that excise duty is levied at the points of production and distribution and the alcohol goes across Europe and the world. I presume that the Government’s proposal would mean levying the duty at the point of sale in Scotland. Would there be significant administrative burdens as a result of that? Do you envisage the proposal working in that way?
I am not entirely sure that even under European law that would necessarily be feasible, because it is all about the movement of the duty, which is paid when the product is released from bond into the market. It can then be sold in an establishment run by one of the members of Patrick Browne’s association, for example, or in the off-trade or in a restaurant. We do not necessarily know where it will be sold when we release it from bond. It could go to a supermarket with a range of shops in England and Scotland, for example. The same problem applies when the product goes into a pub estate. Under European law, duty is paid when the product is released from bond, but it does not necessarily apply to the ultimate seller if it goes through, say, a cash-and-carry.
How could the Scottish Government obtain its policy objective through the devolution of excise duty?
That is one of the questions that we would like to know the answer to.
We are dealing with a complicated issue, but although we are now very far into proceedings on the Scotland Bill, and quite some way into this committee’s proceedings, we have not received a detailed description of the proposal from the Scottish Government. Have you been involved in discussions with the Scottish Government that have given you the detail or any understanding of its proposal? Unfortunately, the committee is working in the dark.
I have not seen any paper that answers these questions.
Some of what you say in paragraph 22 of the Scotch Whisky Association’s written submission is quite dramatic. The submission states:
There is the well-known cross-Channel effect of alcohol going between France and the UK. French duty rates are considerably lower than those in the UK. There is also cross-border shopping for some products between Spain and France and between Italy and France. Where there is a duty difference between different states, there is cross-border shopping and the supply chain is therefore disrupted. That is the sort of thing that we would expect to see here if, as Mr Baker said, one of the plans is to change the duty rate in Scotland so that it was higher than in England. With a porous border and no border controls, goods could move across the border quite easily.
Presumably, if somebody was going to the pub for a pint, they would not go 20 or 30 miles.
Well, lorries drive up and down the M74 and the east coast and there is no reason why they could not be filled with alcohol that would be sold at the back door, which would mean that we had lost control of it. That is one of our concerns, and I am sure that it would be one of Patrick Browne’s concerns.
Have you got figures on how much alcohol crosses over between France and Spain, for example, or how much duty is lost from that?
I am sure that we can look at where those sorts of things happen and come back to you.
If you would, that would be much appreciated, Mr Evans.
There are also opportunities if excise duties are devolved, including the SWA’s own long-standing argument for equivalence for different alcoholic drinks or units of alcohol. Can we foresee a regime being established that addresses many of the threats that you have outlined and that perhaps takes advantage of opportunities? What kind of devolved system would you welcome?
There has certainly been a coming together of the SNP’s stated policy and the long-held SWA policy. However, bearing in mind some of the issues that I have discussed and some of the legal issues that would need to be overcome, that does not seem to apply to the circumstance about which we are being asked—whether a state can have more than one duty rate—which relates to devolution within the UK.
You highlighted particular types of alcohol that were causing problems—vodka and cheap cider. Could the minimum pricing mechanism and excise duty not offer an opportunity to target our difficulties? I believe that Dr Gillan would advocate that they do.
Yes. We ask people in A and E what their last drink was and what they had been drinking over the course of the evening and, as I have said, the evidence is that cheap vodka should be one of our biggest concerns. Industrial-strength cider is also a major concern. There is unfairness in the way in which cider is taxed at present.
European tax rules require all spirits drinks to be taxed at the same rate, so you could not pick one particular spirit and treat it differently from the others.
Would the minimum unit pricing approach not allow us to address that?
As you are aware, we have considerable doubts about its legality, and we have major concerns about the international impact. The situation is contrary to the one we considered in your previous question, where there might be a fine precedent of a reformed duty regime.
I do not recognise the better figures that you suggest are coming through.
Hospital admissions are down by 8 per cent, which is one of the Government’s key indicators, and consumption has flattened over the past five years, so a message about responsible drinking may be getting through—especially when fewer under-15-year-olds are drinking alcohol. There is perhaps something to build on.
We welcome any evidence of changing trends, but I quoted figures earlier showing that our consumption of litres of pure alcohol in Scotland has gone from 11.9 in 2005 to 11.8 in 2010. We are starting to see plateauing. Differences exist between England and Scotland, and there is more evidence that consumption has started to come down in England.
Adam Ingram has started a debate.
I feel that Evelyn Gillan did not give the full story. In calling for a floor price, we also said that excise duty had to be reformed so that there was fairness across the piece. The committee should have the full story.
I am aware that Mr Browne has sat patiently between Dr Gillan and Mr Evans. Would you like to add anything, before I move on to Mr Rennie?
It seems to me that there are two separate issues: control of excise duty, and minimum pricing. Our issue is the convergence of the two. Minimum pricing is about trying to prevent people from selling alcohol for under 45p per unit. If the Scottish Government proceeds with that and gets control of excise duty, our concern is that pubs, which already sell above the proposed minimum level, will have money taken back off them as the perceived benefits of minimum pricing are taxed away, which will mean that pubs will lose out because they will not get the benefits of MUP but will be hit with an extra 50p on the price of a pint. That is the specific issue that we are concerned about, which we are trying to get across.
I will let John Mason in, as he has a quick question on that point.
I would have thought that pubs would benefit from the process that you have described. If the relative price of off-sales is increased, will that not encourage people to use pubs, which I would favour, instead of sitting in the park?
As an association, we do not support or oppose minimum unit pricing. We have a deliberately neutral stance because our members have different views on the issue.
What if something was done on the excise side?
If a different mechanism was used to recover the benefits to retailers of MUP, we do not quite know how that would work. Again, it would be a case of waiting to see what the impact would be. What is certain is that if, as well as implementing MUP, the Scottish Government gained control of excise duty and tried to tax away the benefits of MUP, there would be a 50p increase in the price of a pint in the pub. In our view, it is pretty clear that that would happen.
Dr Gillan, I share your passion about minimum unit pricing and the problem of alcohol. All this may be academic because EU rules may forbid it, so we may be having a pointless discussion. Nevertheless, I am concerned about the complexity of introducing minimum unit pricing and having different systems in the UK for companies that operate across the UK. Have you looked at any evidence around the business impact of that, the compliance issues and managing its administration by the UK or Scottish Governments?
When the medical royal colleges published their first report in 2007, we commissioned two legal opinions. One looked at the licensing legislation and the other looked at potential compliance with EU competition law. The legal advice that we received was that minimum unit pricing would be possible with certain caveats—for example, it would need to be shown that minimum unit pricing was a proportionate response. We think that the Scottish Government could justify that MUP was a proportionate response on the basis of the very high levels of harm from alcohol. The EU confirmed in 2010, in two separate written answers to parliamentary questions, that EU rules do not prevent Governments from introducing minimum unit pricing. However, that remains to be seen.
Can I just correct something? I do not believe that we have ever said that we would make a legal challenge. There is a lot of supposition around that issue. The Scottish Government has said that it expects a legal challenge, but we have not said that we will make one.
Thank you for that clarification.
Mr Evans, can you tell us a bit about the membership of the Scotch Whisky Association?
We cover about 90 per cent of the Scotch whisky industry and are an organisation of distillers, bottlers, blenders and brand owners, so we are at the production end, not the retail end. We have some of the largest drinks companies in the world as members and we have one-man bands who may own a brand but do not own a distillery or perhaps own only one distillery—so we have large and small.
The large drinks companies that now dominate Scotch whisky production will make a variety of other drinks as well.
Drinks of all sorts are made by different companies of different sizes that are in the Scotch whisky industry or which are members of the Scotch Whisky Association.
They will make some of the drinks that will be affected by minimum unit pricing and raised levels of excise. I am thinking particularly of the cheap vodka that Dr Gillan mentioned earlier.
Many of them produce a range of products: many of those products would not be affected by minimum unit pricing, but some would be, depending on the level at which it was set. You should bear it in mind that the proposals in the previous parliamentary session could have hit about 30 per cent of Scotch whisky, so it is not just about looking at other drinks.
Mr Browne, I did not pick up from your written submission what the Scottish Beer and Pub Association intends to do if the proposed power does not come in. I assume that you are as concerned as the rest of society is about the increase in alcohol use and misuse. If excise duties are not devolved and we do not go down the minimum unit pricing route, what part would your organisation propose to play in tackling this very serious problem?
The industry is already involved in a range of activities to try to address alcohol misuse and abuse. It is for the Government to decide what measures to take in that regard. As I indicated, we neither support nor oppose the introduction of minimum unit pricing. The Parliament will make a judgment in due course on whether to proceed with that.
I thank all of you for coming along, which is much appreciated. I suspend the meeting until 2.30.
Corporation Tax
I am happy to reconvene the meeting. We will continue our scrutiny of the Scotland Bill by taking evidence on corporation tax and the creation of a favourable environment for business. I welcome our witnesses, who are Jim McColl, Professor Hughes Hallett and Norman Springford. We had an extremely interesting session on corporation tax this morning, and it will be good to hear more from you.
You would like a short opening statement?
If you wish—you do not have to make one.
I am quite happy to.
Thank you very much. Perhaps Mr Springford would like to go next.
Thank you.
I invite Professor Hughes Hallett to speak for a few minutes on the evidence that he submitted.
Not to be outdone, Drew Scott and I have submitted two lots of evidence. They are both summary statements, designed to review the major issues and the evidence on those issues in the Scotland Bill process at large.
Could I make one more point?
If it is a very quick one, Mr McColl.
It is. I agree with Norman Springford when he says that corporation tax is not of the first importance for entrepreneurs. The level of entrepreneurial activity in Scotland is very low because the critical mass of businesses here is so low. A bigger critical mass creates entrepreneurial activity to interact with those businesses.
Thank you for that. The evidence that we took this morning was primarily about corporation tax, but the three participants were obviously keen to be creating a good business environment in Scotland. Every one of them said that, although they were in favour of the devolution of corporation tax so that a Government would have the right to use that within its country, they also felt that that could be properly effective only as part of what they described as a basket of taxes, with all the tools in the box to give Scotland the best advantage. Do you agree with that?
I will comment based on my accountancy background. The difficulty that I see is that, unless you balance your taxes, the risk of the anti-avoidance legislation and the arguments that will proliferate between HMRC and the rest of the legal and accountancy fraternities will be quite damaging. The cost of implementing any changes might well be self-defeating, in terms of revenue generated.
I agree with that. I would be in favour of devolving a basket of taxes more widely, in the interests of broadening the base and so on. That follows on from my point about the spillovers of one tax on to another. That is probably true more in relation to corporation tax than the others, which means that it is more important in this context.
I agree that it is more desirable to have a basket of taxes. With regard to the 10p variability, you need something to balance that. There would be difficulties, with people classing something as corporation tax instead of another tax, but I am sure that we could have some guidelines and rules to deal with that in the short term.
What would be the optimum level of corporation tax in Scotland? What is an optimum level of corporation tax?
Would anyone like to address that question? I assure you that it does not require a one-figure answer.
No, simply a percentage; that is all.
A good starting point is the Irish rate of corporation tax. Quite understandably, Ireland is fighting hard to hang on to that. If Ireland did not have the large number of businesses that have been attracted there because of the corporation tax, it would be impossible for it to fight its way out of this economic downturn. Only a few weeks ago, I read an article in a Sunday newspaper that said that Google has a £6 billion turnover in the UK and pays around £8 million in tax here. It diverts about £2 billion into Ireland and pays something like 10 or 12 times the absolute amount of tax there, because Ireland has a 12.5 per cent rate.
I do not agree with Jim McColl’s point. My belief is that attracting companies to set up a head office structure in Scotland does not necessarily create growth in employment; it amounts to merely shifting money around. If you are asking what the level of taxation should be, my answer is that it should be set with regard to the unitary system of tax in the UK. Whatever tax rate the rest of the country is using should be the rate that Scotland uses too.
That is another point to do with forecasting: I will not give you a number, because I will certainly not make a forecast about the future.
That is an interesting response from Professor Hughes Hallett. The American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research has—as I am sure that you are aware—done some work on finding an optimal percentage for corporation tax by comparing OECD economies. It concluded that the optimal rate in the late 1980s was around 34 per cent, and that in the early 2000s, it was 26 per cent.
You are right that after a time, as I said, there is a diminishing return: if you set the corporation tax low enough, you will get nothing. There is a question with regard to where the diminishing returns set in; they do not always set in at the same level in different places.
I do not think that the American Enterprise Institute will, despite Mr Springford’s qualities, necessarily be following the Springford rule on this occasion.
No, but I would possibly not spend a great deal of time talking to that institute about its econometric skills.
Okay.
With great respect, your point is irrelevant, as we are discussing whether the Scottish Parliament should be able to set the rate. If it chose 23 per cent as an optimal rate, that would be fine, but at the moment it cannot do any different.
If I believe that devolving the tax rate will create tax competition, it is valid to ask what the process of devolution will lead to.
I thought that that was it.
No, this is it, I am afraid. Even the Scottish Government said in its paper that the perceived benefits that it argues will come from a corporation tax cut will not come for several years. In the meantime, by the Government’s own estimates, a cut of 2 per cent will cost tens of millions of pounds—more than £100 million. The panellists heard the spending review announcements last week. Where in the Scottish budget should the money come from?
It is true that if corporation tax is cut it will take some time for the impact to be felt. That is probably true of many taxes. All the evidence suggests that a benefit of cutting corporation tax is increased investment, in particular foreign investment. That does not happen overnight, but just because a benefit takes a long time to emerge does not mean that it is a bad thing to have it—
However, it is difficult, particularly in the context of the pressures on the budget that there currently are.
Of course things are difficult right now, but corporation tax is one of the few taxes that are likely to raise extra revenue, so if we want extra revenue to spend on various projects, that is a measure that we can use. We will not get that extra revenue from income tax, for example—all the evidence is that there is not the responsive power in that regard. That is a reason why some people around the table might argue against an income tax proposal. They would say that the approach should never be used, because there would be no benefit from it.
Richard Baker talked about the loss of income that would be experienced if corporation tax were cut and asked how, in the tight financial circumstances that we face, we would fill the black hole until the future date at which the money started to come back in—I am paraphrasing. Surely the obvious point is that the Government would not just cut the tax rate immediately; instead, it would announce that it was going to cut corporation tax not this year but in three years’ time, which would give businesses the opportunity to plan for the cut. There would be no immediate, short-term loss of corporation tax, but the Government would have flagged up to the world that lower corporation tax would be coming in. Is that not how a Government would act, rather than cutting the rate immediately and suffering the consequences until business tax receipts recovered?
I was going to make that point. The Government would signal a cut well ahead, which would increase the chances of attracting people who were considering inward investment, who might accelerate their activity or highlight Scotland as a potential area in which to invest. If the cut were signalled well enough ahead, there would be an increase in people looking to Scotland to base their businesses.
I will return to what we are calling the Springford rule—the idea that it is always best to go for a unitary tax rate across the UK. We are in a recession at the moment, but a problem that people across the UK have constantly been faced with has been the economy of the south-east of England overheating. Under the Springford rule, the rate of corporation tax in the south-east of England is the same as it is in Stornoway. How can that be reconciled, given all the advantages that the south-east of England has?
We have either to take a more parochial view and ask what is good for Scotland or to consider what is good for the UK as a whole. Some inequalities might arise because tax raising has different effects in different parts of the country, but the overall effect is still the same.
Are you saying that, if south-east England is booming, that is good for Stornoway?
I am saying that that would be good for the UK—the whole country would benefit. I do not see the advantage of being able to manipulate our tax rates; it would not give us the growth that we look for—I do not see that growth.
If you are in favour of uniformity, are you in favour of the same corporation tax rate across the EU?
No—I accept that different countries have different attitudes. If we are the United Kingdom, that is where our parochial nature applies. We are not members of the European Union in terms of taxation.
You do not recognise the European Union as a country—not many people do. You recognise the UK as a country, but not Scotland.
I recognise Scotland as a country, by all means, but it is part of a unified tax system. The UK should not be involved in the complexities of running separation of taxation.
I will put my questions to Mr McColl, who—
Ms McAlpine, if you paid attention, you would know that Mr McColl has been trying to speak for ages.
Mr McColl might have anticipated my question.
I disagree with what Mr Springford said. Canada, the US and Spain provide examples of successful decentralised tax systems. We operate in all those countries and we have no problems with the different tax rates. In fact, the tax rate might be one consideration in picking where we go in the US.
Unitary rules? Well, as I am the academic, I can deal with that.
Would Richard Baker and Joan McAlpine please stop squabbling in the corner?
We were doing it very quietly. [Laughter.]
Mr Springford, compared with what the other panellists have said, you seem to be saying that uniformity and a unitary system matter more than almost anything else and that, in a sense, lack of growth or missed opportunities for Scotland might be a price worth paying for hanging on to the unitary system. Would that not mean that we lose a competitive edge? That is especially the case given that we will not have a unitary system in the UK if the power is devolved to Northern Ireland. Would that not put Scotland at an immediate disadvantage if the powers were not devolved to this Parliament?
I certainly do not accept the conclusion that the protection of the unitary system is worth any price. I am saying that the disadvantages that a difference in system would make to us, in cost of compliance and the complexities of how the figures would be manipulated and accounted for in the UK, mean that a level of complexity would be built in that would override the benefits that would derive from a reduced level of corporation tax. Furthermore, we are assuming that we are talking about a reduced level of corporation tax—subsequent politicians may say that they would like to raise it. I still say that I would like to see a unitary system and other methods of growth rather than corporation tax being used as a driver for growth.
My second question was what happens if there is no unitary tax. If Northern Ireland has the power and chooses to use it, would we not be at a disadvantage? Would that not be a risk to Scotland?
Yes, it is a risk. That is the end of the argument on that one, as I agree with you.
If Northern Ireland gets the power, you would concede that Scotland should probably have that power too.
Yes, I believe so.
Thank you.
I thank the panel for coming. Mr McColl, I have read in the press that you do not pay full income tax in the UK but choose to do so in Monaco. Is that the case?
That is the case. I am a resident there, but I pay income tax in the UK and I also pay tax in Monaco, which has a different tax system. The system there is indirect instead of direct, which is quite a good system. If you look at the wealth created here by me and my team, it puts into insignificance anything that I might pay if I was a full-time resident here.
It is your view that we should, with a devolved corporation tax, look to lower the tax rate so that your companies would pay less tax.
I am not fussed about my companies. I am looking at the Scottish economy and at increasing the population of businesses here. It is clear that we do not have a big enough business population. That is what generates the wealth; it is private enterprise that generates wealth. You should do everything that you can to stimulate the growth of private enterprise, because that is what will pay for the social progress that we need in Scotland.
Indeed. Thank you.
One observation is that, obviously, tax avoidance is likely to be lower the lower the corporation tax rate is, so I would not have thought that that would be a great problem.
It is a wonderful theory that computers do these things in a nanosecond.
You have to remember to switch them on.
I remind everyone that they do not have to press the button on their console to switch their microphone on—they come on automatically. Mr McColl, did you want to comment?
Yes. I think the opposite is true. As Andrew Hughes Hallett said, anti-avoidance legislation is needed more if the corporation tax rate is higher, because companies will look for a way to reduce it, and they will find a way. However, if the rate is lower, doing that is not worth the effort, so companies will just pay it.
The main plank of my argument is probably about the level of anti-avoidance. It is true to say that, in times of high taxation, the black economy is much bigger than it is in times of low taxation. The argument here is not necessarily about how low the corporation tax is; it is about the differential between the two levels of corporation tax. If the rate was as low as 10 per cent in Scotland but was 15 or 20 per cent in the rest of the UK, there would be serious anti-avoidance, because the differential is greater. To my mind, it is not a case of saying, “Let’s try and put in a few rules.” That is the game that HMRC and the rest of the professionals play day in, day out. Companies will look for a loophole; they will exploit it; HMRC will close that loophole; and on it goes. Anti-avoidance legislation creates a whole new industry; there will be even more opportunities for that if we have a differential rate.
We have talked mainly about rates of corporation tax so far, but there is a suggestion that, if we had control of corporation tax, we could target small businesses, which I think we have fewer of than other places do—we need new ones—and we could target particular industries that are perhaps more important to us, such as the games industry. Does any of you see scope in that area, leaving aside the headline rate of corporation tax?
Yes. I think that it is accepted now that, in the past, the UK economy has focused too much on banking and housing, or property, and that we really need to get manufacturing industry going again. I think that having control of corporation tax would perhaps give you the opportunity to give particular incentives to help to grow manufacturing and attract new manufacturing companies into Scotland.
Yes. [Interruption.] Sorry, it is a knee-jerk reaction to try to switch on the microphone. If you look at the experience in other countries, you see that they nearly always have different rates for small businesses and big businesses or different conditions attached to the rates. Spain has used corporation tax in its different provinces quite a lot, where there are different rates. In the Basque Country, for example, which is the one that I happen to know about for various reasons, the rates are lower for small businesses, which are defined at a certain level—you obviously need to worry about the definition of small businesses. The amount by which the corporation tax rate can differ from the Spanish average varies for small businesses, so small businesses have some advantages there.
We are now getting near the nitty-gritty of where it becomes useful to have this devolved power. I very much agree with the other two members of the panel. If you have a level of corporation tax that applies under the unitary system, the power of the devolved corporation tax rates could be applied to the smaller businesses. If we are looking for growth in SMEs, let us give them the incentives. As Jim McColl said, let us give businesses a five-year tax holiday until they reach a certain number of employees or a certain level of profitability. The power should be used to create growth among SMEs, because that is where growth will come from. By all means attract inward investment, but growth in Scotland will come from the smaller entrepreneur. Let us use the Scottish Government’s power to produce a nil rate, a low rate or an escalating rate—whatever method is best. That is how we could create some genuine growth.
Would you be happy for things to be slightly different in Scotland from the rest of the UK?
Yes. It is almost falling within my original argument to say that we should try to retain a unitary rate but should use the powers that we have to incentivise locally—if we can refer to Scotland as a local community—and to try to create growth ourselves and get a competitive advantage. That has to be done through the smaller businesses.
I am keen not to misunderstand. Are you saying that it would be good for Scotland to have the devolved power as long as it was used wisely? For you, using the power wisely would involve targeting SMEs.
Yes. Clearly, politicians have different views and it is their views that count. However, if I were a politician, I would say that we should keep the main level of corporation tax for the larger companies—they generate the bulk of the revenue in any event—but give incentives to SMEs. That is not a particularly expensive option, because they are not paying all that much in corporation tax anyway, in relation to the big guys. However, doing that will create a level of growth.
A total of 97 per cent of companies in Scotland are SMEs, and there are three key ways of stimulating growth in them. One is to halve the corporation tax rate. That would allow SMEs to accommodate the additional costs of being located in Scotland. For a small company, it is relatively very expensive to consider international markets, which is where the room for growth is. By definition, an SME has a small percentage of the available market. The economic climate does not matter. It does not matter if the economy halves; SMEs will still have fantastic opportunities to grow, because they start with such a small share of the market. They have to get out there and engage in markets outwith their home market, but they often cannot afford to. Secondly, therefore, we need to find a way of supporting them, and a third angle of approach is from the banking side. Debt finance is tough for SMEs, so some sort of industry bank would be helpful.
Before Mr Rennie asks a question, I ask everyone to wish him a happy birthday. [Laughter.]
How old is he?
I have even brought some fudge.
I am not that soft—we will have to wait for that until we finish the meeting.
Professor Hughes Hallett, you have kindly provided us with a formula that I have not seen since I was studying—which was a few years ago. You call it “simple”, although it is not very simple to me. Maybe I am just a simple politician. How many other academics or tax accountants would share your view that the process is simple and easy to calculate?
You have switched questions: you started on the formula and you are now on the process. They are two different things.
Yes, that is what we are talking about.
All it does is work out the proportion of profits that you allocate to the Scottish tax as opposed to the rest of the UK tax. It is no more complicated than proportions. There are two elements: employment in Scotland versus employment in the rest of the UK. I think that it is reasonably clear.
Is this widely shared?
What do you mean?
Do people agree with you that it should be the process?
Fifty US states agree with me, which is a good starting point. They actually have something more complicated, which the accountants—not the academics—dream up. From their point of view, the formula is simple because the alternatives are much more complicated.
The corporation tax rates have fluctuated quite substantially, even just in recent years. How do you estimate how the Scottish block, as derived from the Barnett formula, should change from year to year? How would you make the calculation?
If I had a free hand, I would not make it at all because I would not have the grant.
We do not have fiscal autonomy on the table; we are discussing corporation tax in isolation. What would you say the reduction in the Scottish block should be in order to accommodate fluctuations?
If I had to do it that way, I would have to use some form of forecasting because I would have to know, ex ante, how much I was taking off the grant before I gave you the grant. There is no getting away from forecasting. I would find out the best forecasting formula, which I promise you is more complicated. From the one thing I have read on the UK Government’s response, it seems that it has no idea on forecasting. I therefore do not know the UK Government’s view on forecasting, but that is my view.
So what is the number? You have given us a long explanation but, given the consequences, we could do with a number. We have heard criticism of the UK Government for what you have called its failure to provide forecasts or indicate what the impact might be. However, you are doing exactly the same now—you are not giving us the figures. If you are seriously putting forward the proposition, we need to know the figures.
If you have corporation tax, the conventional way of doing it is to take twice the standard error. In the written evidence, I have set out the standard error for corporation tax as £377 million. That means that you would need about £700 million.
So £700 million.
About £700 million.
The figures estimate the corporation tax take for Scotland at £2.6 billion. You are saying that there would be a £700 million reduction in the block.
That is the cushion that you would need. On the other hand, the standard error for an income tax would be around £4 billion, which means that you would need £8 billion. Which would you rather have?
For Scotland to get the corporation tax, surely the block will have to be reduced.
But you have switched again. You were talking about volatility a minute ago.
I have been consistent throughout. I want to know what the reduction in the block would be.
On average, it would be whatever the corporation tax is now.
Okay. Would you take into account any changes in the corporation tax in the UK, say, or companies shifting profits?
Why would I do that?
Because the UK gives a block grant to Scotland, so—
Compensating the UK for being disadvantaged is not part of the philosophy behind the Scotland Bill.
But obviously any profit shifting in the UK would impact on the UK’s finances.
Indeed.
Should that not be taken into account?
It is for the UK to take that into account, not the Scottish Parliament.
So Scotland gets all the take but none of the give.
Which is exactly what happens with the current income tax arrangements.
But there are compensatory elements in the income tax arrangements.
There are.
That is the whole point. That is what I am trying to work out.
Well, that is precisely the problem. In the last UK budget, the lower income tax threshold was raised. Had the Scottish income tax been in operation, such a move would have lowered the revenues coming into Scotland. In England—I am sorry; I should say the rest of the UK, although I pretty much mean England—compensation comes through the raising of national insurance contributions and capital gains tax. In Scotland, those two taxes cannot be raised to compensate in that way. The London Parliament has not thought for a moment that it might have to compensate; of course, it has now been told to work out some way of doing that but when you ask the secretary of state he says, “I don’t recognise that number” or “Calm down, dear. It’ll be all right. We’ll think of something”. We do not have a clue.
That is rather insulting to the secretary of state. He is actually working—[Interruption.]
Hold on. Mr Rennie, your job is not to put Professor Hughes Hallett on the spot over something that the UK Government is responsible for and about which it said it would provide a model and forecasting.
It was a rather silly criticism of the secretary of state—
No, it wasn’t.
I am sorry to disagree about this but—
I think that we will have to agree to differ but I will not have our witnesses harangued—even if it is your birthday. [Laughter.]
I am not haranguing anyone. Still, I will make one more attempt. Even though there could be profit shifting in the UK and even though the UK Government is considering similar measures for the other taxes that it is looking to devolve, you still do not think that there should be any compensatory arrangements.
That is correct. Indeed, the same holds true for all of these taxes. It is up to the responsible Parliament to put in place the responsible compensation arrangements. It is perfectly open to the UK Parliament to find another tax to substitute, to change the arrangements of a particular tax or, indeed, to do anything else. It could even ignore it. It is a free choice—and vice versa. Given that the spirit of the Scotland Bill is such that these arrangements are not built in for income tax, why build them into corporation tax once the initial calculation has been done?
Okay. I am finished.
Did you wish to come in, Mr McColl?
What we are trying to do with the measure is to compensate Scotland for its disadvantages. If you compensated the UK Government for the people that moved business to Scotland, all that you would be doing is re-establishing the disadvantage. What we want is for the people who locate in London or the south-east to move here. They go naturally to those areas because things are much easier: there is more of a critical mass, the cost of doing business is less, and it is easy to get to every country in the world. If I want to go anywhere from Scotland, I have to add in extra days, it takes longer, and it is more expensive. I need compensation for that. I cannot see how a reduction in corporation tax would provide that compensation if the UK Government simply said that we have to give money back to compensate it.
I think that we have to conclude this discussion because we are running out of time and Mr Ingram still has to ask his question. The no-detriment issue has been discussed at great length and can be raised later with the Treasury minister and again with the secretary of state when he returns.
I have a brief question for each of our panellists.
Was your first question for Mr Springford?
Yes.
If it was, I have probably forgotten it by now.
HMRC has one of the most complicated tax systems. Given the volumes of things that you have to go through, it is a nightmare. Giving Scotland all its own tax-raising powers would create a fabulous opportunity to do everything in a more cost-effective way; after all, you should see the number of people who are employed by HMRC to collect the money.
Are the Strathclyde results robust? Of course they are. Where else would you go?
I thank our three witnesses for their evidence and members for their questions. We have had a robust but, I think, respectful evidence session.
United Kingdom Minister
I am happy to chair this session taking evidence from a UK minister. I welcome David Gauke MP, Exchequer Secretary to the Treasury. With him is Paul Doyle, who is deputy director of the devolved countries unit. Thank you for coming—we are very pleased to have you here.
Thank you for the opportunity to contribute today to the debate on devolution in Scotland and the Scotland Bill in particular. I have worked closely with my colleagues in the Scotland Office on developing the financial proposals in the Scotland Bill, which I believe substantially increase the powers and accountability of the Scottish Parliament.
Thank you very much. I will open the question session. I noted that you said that the committee would be aware that you were meeting the Scottish Government today, but we became aware of that only because we saw it in a press release. It happens, but it would have been—
I am surprised that that information was not shared with the committee. The point is duly noted. I am sure that it has been duly noted by the Scottish Government as well.
To those who are muttering from the sidelines, I say that I make the same criticism of the Scottish Government.
I take your comments on board. It would be fair to say that the Scotland Bill Committee in the previous session of Parliament was supportive of the direction that the Scotland Bill was taking and thought that it was a substantial step in the right direction. We have certainly listened carefully to the comments that were made by that committee and have taken up a number of its recommendations. However, we are keen to make progress in a consensual way, and I look forward to this committee’s questions.
Good. I am glad to hear it.
I am sure that the Scottish Government will release its points. The discussion was confidential, but I can say that the key output of the meeting was that we made progress on the high-level principles for the adjustment to the block grant. I am pleased that we made progress on that. The co-operation between the UK Government and the Scottish Government on that specific point is important to ensuring that we get the block grant right as income tax powers are devolved.
On a point of information, do both Governments intend to share some of the findings of that meeting? If so, when will that be?
It would be discourteous for us not to be as open as possible with both Parliaments. I am sure that the Scottish Government will take the same approach. The intention is not to produce a formal communiqué from this morning’s meeting, but that will be the intention for future meetings of the joint exchequer committee. It was a useful forum for us to discuss the key issues, and I hope that it will be useful in future as we discuss the implementation matters that need to be addressed.
Good afternoon and welcome to the committee. What is the Treasury’s understanding of how the income tax proposals in the bill would impact on future Scottish budgets?
Our policy intention is that the income tax powers and the adjustments to the block grant will essentially be revenue neutral, and that has been agreed by the UK and Scottish Governments. The intention is not for there to be a systematic flow in one direction or the other. Clearly, there are matters that we need to address. We agreed the high-level block grant principles, but it is a process of the Office for Budget Responsibility making predictions, gaining an understanding of what effect devolution of income tax as proposed would have on the Scottish exchequer, and then ensuring that adjustments are made to prevent unnecessary flows. There is uncertainty and a degree of unpredictability, but we want to eliminate that as much as possible so that there is no impact on the Scottish Government.
You say that the system will be revenue neutral. How will the no-detriment principle work to achieve revenue neutrality?
Revenue neutrality is the objective. We have set out our assessment that, if we had applied the system historically, in some years there would have been a net benefit to Scotland and in other years a net cost. I know that the issue has been debated many times in this committee and outside it. Working with HMRC and the OBR, we will try to find the mechanism that gets us close to revenue neutrality as consistently as possible. That is part of the work that needs to be done in the months and years ahead.
In the early years of the process, in years in which there is no benefit, you would take steps to ensure that any shortfall is made up to achieve revenue neutrality.
We want to ensure that the system is not in any way systematically biased for or against one Government. We will have the transitional years, during which the methodology can be refined and improved so that we can be as accurate as possible. That is not a guarantee that, in any one year, there will not be a cost or a benefit, or that the next year will necessarily act to counterbalance that. The attempt is to find a system that, over time, will be neutral.
I took great interest in the statement in your opening comments that you and your officials spent an enormous amount of time and effort working through the financial proposals in the bill. What evidence did you consider for choosing the 10p tax rate?
The 10p tax rate was based on the Calman commission recommendations. We see that as a substantial increase in accountability for the Scottish Government. We have to choose a level somewhere. The 10p level is clear and simple and, as I say, was recommended by the Calman commission.
It is very trusting of you to accept the Calman commission recommendation on that point, although you did not on many others. I return to the original question: why 10p and why not 12p or 8p or any other figure? What work did the UK Government do that brought you to the conclusion that 10p is the correct rate?
As I say, the parties that were involved in the establishment of the Calman commission enabled it to produce recommendations. There is no particular reason or strong argument for moving from the Calman commission proposal. The 10p rate is simple and straightforward and one that people can understand. It would be more difficult to say why we should move from 10p to 8p, 12p or 13p. The Calman commission recommended 10p, which seems to strike the right balance. It is half the standard rate of income tax. For standard rate income taxpayers, something that is half of their marginal rate is significant and straightforward to understand.
I am sorry to stay on this point, but I am still trying to discover what work the Treasury did to convince itself that 10p was the correct rate to choose.
I am not persuaded by the argument that the fact that something is a reasonable amount should be discounted. It is a perfectly sensible point and I am not sure what body of work would result in the conclusion that there is something magical about another number—that it should be 8p or 12p. As I said, 10p is half the standard rate of income tax. It is a clear, straightforward number and I am not sure what economic argument you think exists that would take us to another number.
Let us be straight: I do not propose that the 10p rate is a good idea. It came not from us but from the Calman commission, and Sir Kenneth Calman said that there was no evidence for choosing that rate. I would have thought that the Treasury might look into it to determine whether it was the right rate, but you seem to confirm that neither the Treasury nor the Calman commission had any particular reason for choosing 10p over any other figure.
We considered the implications of the 10p rate for budgeting, for example. There was no particular reason why it should not be 10p. A huge amount of work has been done on a range of issues, but 10p is a clear point. Remember that the context for this is trying to increase the level of accountability for the Scottish Government, so a straightforward number clearly has advantages over a complicated one. Can you come up with something that is more straightforward than 10p?
What do you mean by a complicated number? Is 9p any more complicated than 10p?
The 10p rate is more understandable for the Scottish public because half of their basic rate will go to the Scottish Government and half will go to the UK Government.
If, as you said, it is about giving responsibility to the Scottish Government and the Scottish Parliament, why not 20p rather than 10p? We would be twice as responsible if it was 20p.
It is a question of striking the right balance. The 10p rate is a significant step in providing greater accountability to the Scottish Government and devolving tax powers. It is a major constitutional and fiscal change. I am not surprised that some people want all of it and will come back for more, but it is a substantial change and I hope that the committee welcomes it.
On income tax, I am still none the wiser on the compensatory measure that you described other than that you are saying, “Trust us, we will work it out.” We need a bit more reassurance than that, if I can be so bold.
Derek, can you ask one question at a time, please?
Let me deal with the point about volatility. It really is the other way round. Corporation tax, which I am sure we will talk about in greater depth later, is undeniably a volatile tax. Much of the difficulty that we see in public finances in the UK is because of the volatility of corporation tax in addition to the high level of borrowing before the recession. There is no denying that corporation tax is much more volatile than income tax. Of course, income tax drops in bad years but nowhere near as much as corporation tax. Therefore, one argument for devolving income tax rather than corporation tax is its lack of volatility.
I want to ask specifically about the revenue compensation, picking up your point about the patterns of income tax. Overall, the share of public spend from income tax has changed, and we would be at an immediate and annual disadvantage if the Parliament relied only on income tax as opposed to having a basket of taxes and a range of economic tools that we could use. We would be too heavily reliant on income tax, which, as a share of public sector spend, has been going down.
If more taxes are devolved and a greater share of the Scottish Government’s revenue comes from taxation as opposed to the block grant, the volatility risks will increase. Having a spread of taxes does not compensate for the fact that the more reliant the Scottish Government is on tax as opposed to block grant, the greater the volatility will be. The decision for the Scottish Government and the Scottish Parliament is whether that is welcome. I stress the point that income tax is not particularly volatile and is less volatile than other taxes.
Can I ask about the stratification within the 10p rate?
Yes, but make it your final question, please.
Okay. It is quite important. Bearing in mind that the 10p figure is just something that somebody liked, can you explain the rationale for a figure that is 50 per cent of the basic rate, 25 per cent of the higher rate and 20 per cent of the top rate? Where has that logic come from?
It is 10p across the piece. As I say, it has the advantage of simplicity—it is clear and easily understood—so it will contribute to increasing the accountability of the Scottish Government for the decisions that it makes as far as tax and spend are concerned. I hope that that is welcomed.
That does not explain the variation in rates.
Well, it is 10p in the pound. That is a fairly simple way of doing it. The fact that it is a flat rate across the income distribution does not take anything away from the fact that it is a simple, straightforward measure that will, I hope, be readily understood.
Can I pick up on that point?
Very quickly, please, because I think that Mr Rennie wants to come in.
The argument is that, as the economy grows—as we hope it will do over coming years—the UK will benefit. You say that the 10p rate amounts to half the standard rate, but economic growth will mean that more people are pushed on to the upper rates, and the Westminster Treasury’s share of the revenue from those upper rates will be substantially more than the Scottish Government’s. Where is the rationale there? If, as you said, we are sharing the tax rate between us, why should the UK Treasury benefit more than the Scottish Government?
We anticipate that the higher rate threshold will continue to rise, as it has done. There are provisions under the Rooker-Wise amendment whereby it does so automatically—it rises in line with the consumer prices index. It is the case that, in Scotland, a higher percentage of taxpayers pay the standard rate as opposed to the higher rates than is the case elsewhere in the UK but, for everyone, the proposed rate will be half their standard rate. The intention behind what we are doing is to ensure that Scotland does not lose out.
Some might say that it might contribute to the deflationary bias that is inherent—
I think that the agreement was that you would get to ask one little question.
Okay. Perhaps someone could pick up on that.
I will exercise the convener’s privilege. When Sir Kenneth Calman gave evidence in the session that Mr Maxwell referred to, he said—I am paraphrasing, as I do not have his words in front of me—that he regarded the work of his commission as a starting point. When he was asked about the 10p rate, he said that he envisaged that such things would be looked at much more closely before it came to legislation. It seems to me that your Government attaches great weight to the Calman commission report—you admitted that to Mr Maxwell—but given that the lead author of that report said that the members of the commission viewed its proposal as a starting point for discussion rather than something to be included in legislation, would you take that on board, even at this stage?
I am not sure that we have seen persuasive arguments to move away from the Calman commission recommendations. I do not want to repeat myself, but I think that what is proposed in the Scotland Bill represents a highly significant change. It represents a big increase in responsibility for the Scottish Government, which will increase the Scottish Government’s accountability to the Scottish people. The simplicity and straightforwardness of the commission’s proposals are commendable, given that taxes can be far more complicated than people would like.
We had some very interesting discussions this morning about the potential for simplifying the tax system.
You made the observation that the block grant is based on a spread of taxes.
The block grant is calculated based on spending, but clearly the Exchequer—
Is not it the case that the revenue comes from all UK taxes?
Yes.
You mentioned that the spread of taxes is more volatile.
My point was that the greater the share of the Scottish Government’s income that comes from taxation as opposed to the block grant, the more volatile its income will be.
As I understand it, the proposal will involve you taking away some of the block grant, which is based on a basket of taxes, and replacing it with revenue from one tax—income tax. All the calculations show that the revenue from income tax grows more slowly than the revenue from other taxes. For example, the International Monetary Fund showed that since 1965 in the UK, the revenue from income tax has grown at 0.9 per cent, whereas the revenue from all taxes has grown at 6.5 per cent. The reason is that some volatile taxes are volatile up the way. For example, oil revenues are very volatile up the way and have risen by eight times since 1965, which makes up 43 per cent. You are taking away those very buoyant taxes from our share of the block grant and replacing them with income tax, which grows very slowly. I am not sure why that is fair or why it gives the Scottish Parliament more power or responsibility over the money that is raised.
With respect, I must come back to the point about the block grant. It is calculated for Scotland on the basis of the Barnett formula, which is a spending formula and not—
It is based on tax, including Scotland’s taxes from oil, whisky and so on.
I do not think that it is based on tax. It is based on spending.
It is based on UK revenue. We get a share of UK revenue through the block grant.
Yes—and you will do in the future. I wish it were the case that there was a strong link in the UK public finances between revenue and expenditure, but in recent years that has not really been the case—that is the problem that we face. The block grant is based on a spending formula.
There is, however, a mechanism for the block grant. You said that there is a lot of uncertainty about your proposal. Given that—
I am sorry. Can I just make one point? Three years ago, we saw tax receipts fall very dramatically. That did not automatically feed through to a reduction in the Scottish block grant.
The Scottish block grant has been cut by £1.3 billion this year.
Yes, but it did not automatically feed through.
If you ask anyone in Scotland about it, they will tell you that the money has been cut this year. Anyway, if I can just move it along—
That is a slightly different thing.
Can we move on?
The Scottish Government calculated, using 1999 as the starting point, that if we had used the proposed mechanism for the block grant we would have lost £8 billion because income tax grows more slowly than other income that makes up the block grant. That is the deflationary effect of the proposed scheme. I know that the UK Government disputes that.
I clarify for the record that the letter was from the Secretary of State for Scotland.
I apologise.
I presume that you got a copy of the letter, Mr Gauke.
Yes—I have a copy in front of me. We work very closely together, so that is fine.
You will be able easily to explain the methodology, then.
The difficulty with the Scottish Government’s methodology is exactly as you describe: it takes one year. You can take individual years and they will point in one direction or the other.
The period was 10 years.
Yes—but that is another hypothetical example.
It is not hypothetical because the Scottish Government starts with 1999.
We are going to have to stop this because it is becoming—
It is really important, convener. I am sorry, I will behave myself and be more polite, but if I could—
We do not accept the Scottish Government’s methodology. The UK Government has set out our methodology. What is very clear is that the answer to the question whether Scotland wins or loses depends on which years you take. I can quote you a set of years where, for example, over the spending review period, Scotland would do very well under the proposed system. You can cite other years when that would not be the case. It partly depends on the relationship between tax receipts and the increase or decrease in those, and what public spending is doing. However, overall, I am afraid that the evidence does not support the view that the proposed system would cost billions and that it has a deflationary bias. We do not think that the Scottish Government’s work in this area is very impressive.
Can you explain your methodology, please? The Scottish Government’s work was based on the 10 years after 1999, which was the year when the Parliament was set up. That seems to be quite reasonable, because those years include a period of boom and a period of recession, which seems to be a fairly good stretch of time to examine. However, you dispute that by citing a hypothetical situation, and say that your methodology is more accurate. I do not understand that, which is why I am asking for an explanation.
We have published a technical note—
Can you explain it to me, please?
I am not sure how long we have got. The technical note clearly sets out that in different years, there are different effects. One can cherry pick a group of years, which is the point about the Scottish Government’s work and some of the other assessments in that area that you have quoted. In a period in which there is a severe recession, there is one impact, while in a period in which there is fiscal consolidation—which we are doing at present—and tax receipts increase more quickly than spending, there is a substantial gain for the Scottish Government.
There is one more—very quick—question from Joan McAlpine.
With regard to that methodology, the Secretary of State for Scotland claims in his letter—exactly as you do—that the “hypothetical” system will result in a gain for us. However, he goes on to say:
I am just re-reading the letter, and I am struck by its similarity with what I said. We have done the work, and the model illustrates what would have happened if the rate had applied in the past. However, it is the case—as I said a moment ago—that, as Michael Moore’s letter states:
John Mason will come in next. Is your question on income tax, Mr Mason? I know that Richard Baker is keen to get on to borrowing powers, and there are other things to discuss.
Yes, but I would like to discuss borrowing powers too.
Perhaps you can discuss those issues together.
Yes. We said 5 o’clock, but we can go a bit beyond that.
That is even better than I imagined—how wonderful.
I do not want to bring this to an end.
We will see where we get to. John Mason can round up on income tax.
I will not touch on borrowing powers until later.
It would be a very important change to bring in the 10p rate, which is the Scottish amount. We must remember that income tax is the biggest tax—the biggest revenue raiser—in the UK, and the most important. If we had gone down the route of saying that we should devolve income tax altogether, that would be a significant shift. We must remember that a lot of expenditure is still done on a UK basis.
Is there a risk that the public will not understand, and that each side will blame the other?
I am sure that political arguments will be presented in that way. However, the Scottish people are more than capable of understanding how the 10p system will work, and of holding both the UK Government and the Scottish Government to account.
We have discussed HMRC with witnesses, and have heard about various experiences. We have heard that the country’s tax rules are complex, and that there are lots of books on that. We have also heard that HMRC is “a guddle”. I do not know whether you are familiar with that word.
I fear that you may have to help me.
I think “mess” could be used instead. The committee has wondered how much we can depend on HMRC.
As I mentioned earlier, we established a high-level implementation group, and HMRC has been engaged in the process. I meet senior members of HMRC regularly, and they are conscious of the challenges that devolution will bring and of the need to adjust the system. I am confident that they will deliver, so I am not overly concerned.
In that relationship, will Scottish ministers be able to question the OBR and HMRC directly, or will they have to go through the UK Government?
For HMRC, an accounting officer will have specific responsibility for Scottish matters. We have also made it clear that senior officials at HMRC are available to give evidence to the Scottish Parliament and its committees; they will be held accountable by entities such as this one, and by other organisations.
So, the Scottish Parliament can hold HMRC to account.
There will be the mechanism whereby HMRC can give evidence. I envisage the Scottish Parliament’s being able to question HMRC and to issue reports on its performance in the matter, in a way that is similar to what is done at present by the Treasury Select Committee—or, more precisely, by a sub-committee of the Treasury Select Committee.
Forecasting would mainly be done by the Office for Budget Responsibility. Will forecasting separately for Scotland and the UK involve a lot of extra work?
A lot of the data is held by HMRC, which has a well-respected unit—the knowledge, analysis and intelligence unit—that will gather data and provide it to the OBR, which will then be able to assess the situation and make forecasts. That is how things will work at a practical level.
Before we move on to Richard Baker, who wants to introduce a new subject, I mention that we have had informal round-table discussions with many practitioners. There is real concern that HMRC will not be able to come up with the necessary implementation methods within the timescale that is proposed in the bill. There is real concern that an awful lot of work has still to be done. How do you respond to that?
HMRC tells me that it is on track, but you are right to say that a lot of work has to be done on the implementation side. Our focus has been on income tax, but one can also discuss other taxes. A lot of implementation work needs to be done on stamp duty land tax and landfill tax. We hope that the Scottish Government, which will have responsibility for those taxes, will also do a lot of the necessary work.
That was rather neat, minister.
I will ask a couple of questions on some of the other issues in the bill.
You are absolutely right that the cap is a floor rather than a ceiling and that it may subsequently be increased.
We would hope that the discussions on the cap can continue, because it sounds like there may be some disagreement about what the cap should be in order to allow a credible fiscal policy here in terms of stimulating economic growth.
I agree with your point. We await details on excise duties. We have not, as yet, received anything and we look forward to doing so.
Mr Maxwell wants to ask about corporation tax, but before that can I go back a wee bit and ask for some good analysis of the 10p rate of income tax from the UK Government?
We have done a great deal of analysis of what the impact of the 10p rate would be. We continue to work very closely on that.
I meant the thinking behind 10p being reached as an optimum figure.
I do not think that one would sit down with a lot of data, come up with a magical number and say that the optimum level would be 9.123 or something. The important thing is to identify a straightforward number that the Scottish people will understand and 10p does that.
If we were not in a decimal system, would the figure be 12p?
Since the convener has raised the issue, I will follow it up. Mr Gauke said that a whole lot of analysis had been done on the income tax rate—not on the 10p level, but in general.
A whole lot of analysis has been done on the impacts and there is continued analysis to work out what the block grant changes would be and so on. That is what I am talking about.
That is what I thought you said. Perhaps I have missed that analysis: where is it?
It is continuing analysis, which is continuing to be worked through, on what the block grant would be. We talked earlier about the methodology that the UK Government produced on the impact of income tax devolution.
Have you submitted that to the committee?
We produced a technical note, which you have seen.
But the analysis that you are talking about—
The technical note is an analysis of the impact of this devolution of income tax on the Scottish budget. The committee has that technical note.
The clerk has informed me that the technical note was provided to the previous committee.
Can I come in? I have the technical note.
No. Perhaps you can come in after John Mason has asked a question on the same point, and then it will be back to Stewart Maxwell on corporation tax.
My question is about how much work has still to be done on both income tax and corporation tax. The Institute of Chartered Accountants of Scotland told us that it reckons that there is a huge amount of work to do on the question of residency and whether people are resident in Scotland, England or wherever. I assume that the UK Treasury would lead on that.
We have refined the definition of residency in the Scotland Bill, so there has been improvement there.
I now have a copy of the technical note, for which I thank Ms McAlpine. It says:
Yes, it does—I want to be clear about that. Work has to be done with the Scottish Government, and I think that we have made progress today on the exact mechanism required.
May I make a brief point?
If it is brief and on this issue, because time is running out.
The point is pertinent. It is not just the Scottish Government that has to be convinced, but every member of the Parliament. We have to be armed with the facts on how Scotland will be affected. Has consideration been given, for example, to a joint commencement order? Time is marching on with the Scotland Bill.
We can come back to that, but Mr Maxwell has been very patient.
In your response to Richard Baker, I think that I heard you say that the Scottish Government had failed to accept that the block grant would be adjusted if corporation tax were devolved. Is that right?
It had failed to accept that there would be an adjustment to take into account tax-motivated incorporation and profit shifting.
The Scottish Government paper on this issue talks about an immediate adjustment to the Scottish block grant by the equivalent amount.
But it clearly does not take into account tax-motivated incorporation and profit shifting.
The committee that considered devolving the power to Northern Ireland made exactly the same proposal as is in the Scottish Government paper.
The calculation that would have to be made is that the change in the block grant would need to take into account the cost to the UK Exchequer of tax-motivated incorporation and profit shifting. I think that the point is accepted in principle by the main political parties in Northern Ireland, but it does not appear to be acknowledged, let alone accepted, by the Scottish Government. There is a need for much greater clarity from the Scottish Government about how those issues would work, because if corporation tax were to be devolved and Scotland were to cut corporation tax, the issues would be relevant to what the adjustment to the block grant would be, which is clearly of relevance to the Scottish people in deciding whether they support the policy.
I refer you to the paper that HMRC produced in July, “Explanatory Note on estimating the cost of a reduction in the Corporation Tax rate in Scotland”, which assumed a cut to 12.5 per cent—the Scottish Government had not suggested such a cut but you produced the paper anyway. Where in table 1, on page 2, or anywhere else in the paper, are estimates provided of changes in other revenue, such as a rise in the amount of income tax as a result of increased economic activity, a reduction in unemployment and benefits being claimed and so on?
The paper did not do that. Its purpose was to assess the costs of the policy. We produced it as an illustrative example. You said that the Scottish Government did not ask for such an assessment, but given that the Scottish Government had not addressed cost, we thought that it would be helpful to produce the paper, to inform the debate. The paper considered the costs.
When most people—if not all people—estimate the cost of a policy or anything else, they take away the expense, add the gains and regard the difference between the two as the cost. What you did was to say, “It is all negative” and ignore the positives. How can your assessment be the cost?
It is clear what the paper does; it sets out the costs. The Scottish Government’s paper sets out the advantages. The methodology that was used in the paper is exactly the same as the methodology that the Treasury and HMRC use to cost policy measures on a regular basis, including for every budget. The methodology is not unusual. The paper very much filled a vacuum that the Scottish Government left when it failed to address the whole point of costs.
I see no vacuum, because as far as I am aware the Scottish Government has not suggested that it would cut corporation tax to 12.5 per cent. Even if we accept your figures, we must surely not accept your assessment of the cost, because you have ignored all the positives.
The point is that under the Azores judgment, which means that there cannot be state aid—there cannot be a subsidy from the UK as a whole, as the member state, to part of the member state—the cost to the UK would have to be picked up by Scotland in the adjustment to the block grant. That is how it would work. I take one example in relation to the cost to the UK Exchequer of tax-motivated incorporation, which would result in an increase in corporation tax receipts but an even greater decrease in income tax receipts and NICs receipts. The difference would have to be picked up by Scotland in the calculation for the block grant. That is the point that I am not sure that the Scottish Government has brought to the fore. It was important that we made the point.
Table 1 does not show a cost to Scotland, though, does it? It is a cost to the UK.
It is a cost to Scotland, because to comply with the Azores judgment we understand that the cost, which is a cost to the UK Exchequer, would have to be picked up by Scotland. If it was not picked up by Scotland, in essence there would be an element of state aid or subsidy for the corporation tax cut, which would not be compliant with the Azores judgment.
As I said, the Scottish Government has not suggested a tax cut to 12.5 per cent, so it seems odd that you produced your paper on that basis. You also failed to provide any figures for revenue growth from income tax, corporation tax or anything else.
On your point about the Scottish Government never saying that it would reduce corporation tax to 12.5 per cent, the Scottish Government and certainly members of the SNP in Westminster, in making the case for devolution of corporation tax, have been making the case for Scotland being in the position of the Republic of Ireland, for example. At that point the Scottish Government had not set out a specific number on how it would like to reduce corporation tax, but it had certainly been making the case that it was looking to the Republic of Ireland as an example of where it could go. Therefore it was perfectly reasonable to inform the debate and bring the numbers out into the open by using 12.5 per cent as an illustration. If you want us to produce the numbers for corporation tax at 15 or 20 per cent, I am sure that we can do that.
You make a valid point about Ireland. It is often cited by the Scottish Government, which then distances itself from the impact of the reduction in the tax take. Perhaps the minister can explain the additional cost to business of compliance and the additional cost to the Scottish and UK Governments of devolving corporation tax to Scotland. Has any analysis of that been undertaken?
That is an important point. We would need to take steps to counter profit shifting as much as we could. The complexity would be increased for cross-border businesses, which would need to be able to attribute profits either to Scotland or to elsewhere in the UK. There would also have to be a methodology to ensure that profit was not attributed falsely one way or the other—that there was not an issue with people putting up a brass plaque in one place but not conducting operations there. All of that anti-avoidance activity would impose a cost on both HMRC and businesses, which we would need to quantify.
I am aware that time is getting on. I will pick up on a couple of points, the first of which was raised by Richard Baker in his questions on borrowing. It relates to the general theme of shortfalls in income and how people would manage; it also relates back to much of the evidence that we have heard suggesting that a basket of taxes is required if the Scottish Government is to be properly able to boost the economy.
There has been some movement on, for example, the policy that the Scottish Government would have to deal with the first 0.5 per cent of any forecasting errors. As far as revenue borrowing is concerned, we have made the case that that is sufficient given the size of forecasting errors in recent years. We will continue to engage in that area.
It has been quite a while since the previous committee’s report was published. We subsequently received a white paper from the previous UK Government and we were then told about the respect agenda, but this committee is again considering the matter. It seems that little movement has been made by the Government on the recommendations that the previous Scotland Bill Committee came up with, considering that they had cross-party agreement and that a lot of them were agreed by everyone in the Parliament.
On borrowing, we have gone further than the Calman commission recommended—a point that Sir Kenneth Calman has welcomed.
Excuse my interruption, but I do not believe that you have gone further than the previous Scotland Bill Committee recommended.
That may be the case, but, as I say, we are constrained on the issue by the current public finances and the need to stick to our overall proposals. We look constructively at the arguments that are made by parliamentary committees and, where possible, we take those comments into account.
My second point returns to what I mentioned at the outset of this discussion. The most recent legislative consent motion to go through the Parliament was heavily caveated because of real concerns and it has to come back again. Today, we have heard concerns—across the piece in the committee, some of which have been relayed to you—about implementation and the effects on the block grant, discussions on which are still on-going. We are told that the respect agenda is still in place. Do you agree with the Prime Minister that the respect agenda is still in place, and will there be joint commencement of the bill?
I always agree with the Prime Minister, as you would expect.
There is a precedent in the Welsh Assembly having joint commencement of its bill. Can we expect Scotland to be accorded the same respect? You have not answered my question.
I am quite happy to look at that precedent. I want us to reach a consensus on the point and hope that the issue will not cause a divide among us. We believe that we have in place a mechanism that is appropriate and reasonable, but we hear the points that you are making.
We have time for two quick points, although I am aware of the time.
I do not understand how any instability or uncertainty would be created. This is exactly what happens in Wales, and there are a number of examples of the same sort of thing. The UK Parliament and the National Assembly for Wales must agree on matters before they make progress.
I am sure that we can reach consensus.
May I—
Very quickly.
It is very important.
It is all important.
Are you saying, Mr Gauke, that if the Scottish Parliament—after listening to the arguments and analysis of the UK Government and the Scotland Bill Committee, and after listening to all the evidence from outside stakeholders and other interested parties—decided on a vote of its democratically elected members that it did not wish to implement the income tax powers because it believed them to be damaging to Scotland’s interests, the UK Government would then go ahead and force those powers on us?
That is a very hypothetical question.
It is not the least bit hypothetical.
It is a very hypothetical question. The UK Government does not intend to find itself in that position. We will work hard to develop proposals, and we will work closely with the Scottish Government.
Will you accept a vote of the Scottish Parliament?
I have nothing more to add to my answer. The question was very hypothetical. We will work hard to ensure that we are not in the position that you suggest.
Thank you, Mr Maxwell. I hope that Mr Mackay’s question will not be hypothetical.
It is not hypothetical. Mr Gauke, your colleague from the coalition brought along some fudge today, but you have produced some of your own on the issue of commencement powers. The matter is straightforward: if we reach consensus, there is not an issue; if we do not reach consensus, and if you still want us to support the Scotland Bill, we will need clarity on the financial implications for the country, the Parliament and the Government. Will you be a little more constructive on commencement powers? You have been vague on the principle.
We believe that what we have set out is perfectly reasonable. We want to proceed with the Calman agenda, because we believe that it is right for Scotland. We will act in good faith in ensuring that the block grant adjustment mechanism is fair to all sides, and we expect to proceed in 2016. I do not think that we will need additional legislative hurdles, but we hear the points that are being made by this committee and the Scottish Government and we will reflect on them. However, as I say, I think that what we have set out is perfectly reasonable.
I will allow another five minutes, if that is all right with you, minister.
That will probably be it—then, I will have to go.
On commencement, I understand that the go-ahead for the tax powers rests solely with the Treasury in London. We are asking why it cannot be based on an agreement between London and Edinburgh.
It is a question of the UK Government devolving powers that are currently its sole responsibility. We hear the arguments that are being made and want to work in a consensual way. You and a number of your colleagues have made the point that you want the commencement power. We hear that, but it is devolution of a power that is currently held by the UK. We want to work as constructively as possible with the Scottish Government and the Scottish Parliament.
You said—
No more than a few seconds, please, because it is not fair.
No, it is okay. I have made my point already.
Stewart Maxwell will ask the final question. I must insist on quickness—we cannot have the minister miss his flight.
Of course not. Minister, let me sum up the evidence that we have heard today. You have no evidence for the 10p tax rate, no explanation for the revenue compensation process, no rationale for having a flat-rate tax only and no mechanism for making the adjustment to the block grant, and you refuse to accept a democratic vote of the Scottish Parliament as being a part of the process of implementing the income tax proposal. Why would we accept any of that?
Thank you for your characterisation of the afternoon. I have rather enjoyed it.
Thank you, minister. In closing, I make a final point on commencement. I do not think that anyone on the committee—or, indeed, in the Parliament—would like to be in the position of signing a blank cheque by approving the bill without knowing all the implications. We will be talking about joint commencement quite a lot.
Please do.
Thank you for your time, minister. Thank you, Mr Doyle, for your forbearance and patience.
Previous
Attendance