Agenda item 2 is the first oral evidence session for our cross-cutting review of economic development. I welcome various officials from the Scottish Executive.
Thank you for giving us the opportunity to come and talk about the economic framework. I have two opening comments. One is about the consultation process, which I gather the committee is interested in hearing about, and the other is an overall comment about FEDS.
On the priority areas, page 7 of the Executive's written evidence states:
Jane Morgan might say something about Scottish Enterprise in that context, but I endorse your point. The data indicate that spending on business R and D in Scotland is well down on the level in the rest of the United Kingdom—it is about half the UK level and about a quarter of the level of the leading quartile of Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development countries, with which we are often compared.
I will add a little detail. Along with Scottish Enterprise and Andrew Goudie's department, we recently considered R and D support. The main finding was that we need a range of measures, rather than a focus on a particular measure such as tax credits. That finding has informed the attempt to create a pipeline of support that takes people through different stages. As Andrew Goudie said, the R and D tax credits operate at Great Britain level. There is also a range of support for small companies in the early stages of research and development. Some of that support is directly administered by the Executive, so its budget falls into the "other" category rather than the enterprise networks budget. The enterprise networks use a number of measures, some of which are directly oriented to companies, such as the proof-of-concept scheme. Also relevant is the funding for the intermediary technology institutes to carry out more commercially oriented research. Such research might be undertaken by universities, but the intention is to identify intellectual property that can be developed by companies.
Paragraph 1.3 of the FEDS document, under the heading "The Scale of the Challenge", includes a table of gross domestic product per hour worked—I do not know whether that is the right measurement to indicate how the economy is doing, but I will assume that it is, given that FEDS allocates almost a page to it. If we leave aside Germany, Scotland is performing poorly even in comparison with the rest of the UK and it is clear that since 1996 there has been about a 5 per cent fall in GDP per hour worked. Do you expect your strategies to change the situation? If so, how soon will the figures improve? What is the lag?
You are correct to say that the table shows a lag over the past few years. That is very much a function of the cycle that we have been through and the structural change that we have experienced during part of that cycle. It is undoubtedly true that areas of the economy that would typically have higher productivity, such as electronics, have taken a bit of a hit. It is equally true that parts of the service sector, which tend to have lower levels of productivity, have been a smaller part of that.
I am trying to get you to set yourself a target. The budget is full of targets for other departments, but the Finance Committee—before I became a member—complained that the budget sets no target for economic growth. Are you setting yourselves a target for the next five to 10 years? If so, what indicators would you like to see at the end of that period?
Ministers have taken the view for quite a while that setting an aggregate target for growth is not necessarily the direction in which they want to go. FEDS is pretty explicit in setting a target, in that it talks about the wish for
My question was phrased in quantitative terms because the Executive included the figures to which I referred in the FEDS document. If such a document is produced in five years' time, do you expect the figures for Scotland in relation to other countries to be significantly better?
Yes. I mentioned cycles and we must always be careful about cyclical effects, because they can disrupt the figures, as they have done this time. However, I hope that over the course of eight or nine years the cyclical effects will be evened out and shorter-term policy instruments such as R and D will be having an impact. That is certainly the intention and I am sure that ministers take that view.
The target issue is important. When Professors Bell and Lapsley gave evidence to the Finance Committee, I asked them whether it would be
I have mentioned what I believe is ministers' attitude to what drives policy and the seriousness with which policy is taken. Ministers regard the qualitative commitment that is made in FEDS as being strong enough. In addition, some in the academic community have shared with us the view that, because the mechanisms that are at play are, as you know, incredibly complicated, it is difficult to create a model that can capture the way in which policy and spend link to an outcome. Some groups in our universities attempt to do that, but most agree that it is extremely difficult to capture such relationships. The question has always been partly how much effort and resources we should put into trying to do such modelling work, given that it is not clear how much it would affect the direction of policy, but also whether we have the knowledge to capture the detail of the mechanisms that are at play within the economic system.
I understand the potential to penetrate the complexity and enter the morass of cause and effect, but I do not see that happening in other countries, such as Ireland, New Zealand or the Czech Republic. Would they succeed as well as they have done with an absence of targets and a similarly relaxed long-term approach to remedial outcomes?
Ministers would not regard their approach to the outcomes as relaxed.
We are talking about very long-term drivers.
The long-term nature is not related to any degree of relaxation. There is a view that the economic mechanisms that are at play are long term; the education example is perhaps the best one to give us a feel for that, but there are others in the system. For example, on physical infrastructure, there are significant lags between the moment of decision and the moment when infrastructure is in place. There is realism that some such measures will necessarily take longer, unlike shorter-term solutions such as appearing to subsidise companies for the immediate future.
Perhaps I can draw you on some short-term issues. In July or August next year, the International Institute for Management Development, which is based in Switzerland, will bring out a report that will examine Scottish competitiveness. In its previous report, Scotland was ranked 36th out of 60 and the UK was 22nd, which suggests a gap in competitiveness, which might be wider between London and the south-east of England on one hand and the Highlands and Islands on the other. However, what was depressing about that report was that Government macroeconomic policy was placed 39th—which is what dragged us down to 36th place—and Government microeconomic policy was placed 38th. Do you have plans in place to get a better outcome when that assessment is redone in 2005?
I will make a couple of points about that. First, in my mind, there are questions about the robustness of the exercise to which you refer. Some of the indicators that are used have difficulties. For example, it appears from what the researchers write up about their methodology that the total size of employment in an economy has a bearing on the ranking of the country, which I find difficult to understand.
It did not work that way for Estonia, which was ranked 28th.
Let the witness respond.
Leaving aside the questions about the methodology and taking the point about macro policy, I think that ministers' judgment is that, over the past five or 10 years, the conduct of macro policy at the UK level has been beneficial to the Scottish economy. The Scottish business community has been receptive to the view that stability in macroeconomic policy is extremely important and that stability in the outcomes to do with inflation and growth has been important in providing the context for the investment decisions. My understanding from talking to the business community is that it is supportive of the stability that we have had during the past five or 10 years.
I suspect that you are talking more to organisational leaders than to individual business people, because that is not the feedback that I get, and the recent Ernst & Young survey that showed that 46 per cent of Scottish businesses wanted more power for the Parliament and 26 per cent were neutral on the issue suggests that there is a different undercurrent in the business community. I will home on one thing—
Just one thing, Jim.
With the multiplicity of different initiatives that are on the go, how will the formula that you are working on now close the economic gap and reverse our current population decline and when will that happen?
It is difficult to resolve what the formula's impact will be on the demographic trends. I am sure that we can find examples in which economic development and buoyancy lead to stronger migratory trends that are favourable, but there are other examples in which the migratory trends have themselves stimulated economic development, so the causality can run in both directions. As you know, the First Minister is pursuing the latter of those directions through the fresh talent initiative, which focuses on trying to bolster the skills and entrepreneurial spirit in the country to try to contribute to the overall picture. The population question is complicated, but it has obviously been addressed through some of the Executive's initiatives.
I understand that point.
I will pursue you slightly on that, Dr Goudie. There is a Treasury view on the long-term sustainable growth of the UK economy, which is embodied in, for example, budget forecasts. Does the Executive consider that the sustainable growth rate for the Scottish economy is above, below or at the same level as the UK rate?
At the moment, the long-term growth rate for Scotland is about 1.6 per cent and the latest for the UK is, I think, 2.1 per cent. The Executive's view is that the sustainable rate is higher than the 1.6 per cent growth rate that we have at the moment, but I do not think that ministers have taken a clear view on what that long-term rate might be. There is a qualitative view about the fact that it can sustainably be accelerated, but there has been no discussion of any particular figure.
You said that you had an aspirational target of getting into the OECD's top quartile.
The aspirational target for the contributory drivers of productivity and growth is certainly to get in towards the top quartile and you will know the structure for that from the analysis that we have done in "A Smart, Successful Scotland".
Dr Goudie, excuse my ignorance, but you said that the growth rate in Scotland is 1.6 per cent, and the Scottish ministers believe that it is higher. Will you clarify that?
I am sorry; I will clarify that. Our estimate of the long-term trend in the rate of growth, based on the period 1974 to 2003, is 1.6 per cent. The figure for the UK is 2.1 per cent. The intention is to abstract from the cycles over the period 1974 to 2003 and get a feel for the long-term structure. The point that I was making was that, as is set out in FEDS, ministers are sure that we can accelerate that long-term rate of growth to something that is sustainable but higher than 1.6 per cent and towards the UK figure.
In your written submission to the committee, you say that one of the principal outcome objectives is economic growth and talk about it being
Typically, it might be expected that productivity levels in manufacturing would be higher than in service areas of the economy, although that is, of course, a generalisation. However, the point about FEDS is that, whether we are talking about manufacturing or services, raising productivity in those sectors to the extent that we can do so will make them more competitive within their own market. We have taken an uncontentious view throughout FEDS that the market that we must talk about is the global economy, as that is the market in which internationally traded services and manufacturing compete. Even if we are talking about an area of the economy in which there is no international trading—obviously, we can think of quite a few such areas; construction is usually cited as an obvious example—the competitiveness and productivity of that area are important, as they bear on the costs of sectors that trade. Therefore, putting productivity at the centre of things is crucial, whether we are talking about the traded, non-traded, manufacturing or service parts of the economy.
As you know, the review is a cross-cutting review. How much work is being done across all the Executive departments to look in more detail at productivity problems? I have asked the minister parliamentary questions about productivity, and I want to give an example. If my recollection is correct, more than 8 million days are lost to the Scottish economy through absenteeism for one reason or another, which is a considerably higher figure than that for economies of an equivalent size.
I agree very much with the general thrust of what you say, and will pick up a couple of threads.
One piece of work that is signalled in "A Smart, Successful Scotland: Ambitions for the Enterprise Networks" is the building up of an employability framework. The document recognises the issue of economic inactivity, so as to identify roles of a whole range of organisations in helping inactive people who may be able to get back into work. For example, there already are, and there will continue to be, close discussions between the Health Department, which may be concerned about people with mental health problems getting back into work, and the Development Department, which has a particular interest in other groups. Many client groups need to be addressed in an integral fashion, and cross-working is happening in working towards the employability framework.
We must move on. I want to ensure that Jim Mackinnon is not forgotten, so I remind members that they can talk about "A Smart, Successful Scotland" or the national planning framework.
I want to deal with FEDS, although I do not want to pass up the opportunity to discuss the national planning framework.
I will not challenge your quotations, which I am sure are correct. However, I will describe what I think the current picture is, as I do not think that it has changed from what it was. In our work on efficient government, we have put together an implementation plan that will be launched either at the end of this month or early in December, which will set out much more detail on what is going on.
I have a follow-up question. We received a helpful departmental letter last week that confirmed that it had been agreed with the Treasury that we were pursuing comparable efficiency savings programmes in the spending review. In addition, Tom McCabe said in response to a parliamentary question that the Executive
I am not sure that I can give you a precise answer.
An order of magnitude will be sufficient.
The important point in this discussion is the comparison of like with like. Ministers have been keen to focus on the deliverability of what they have called the cash-releasing savings. Obviously there are two sides to productivity: cash releasing and time releasing. The focus has been on cash releasing and ensuring the robustness of that. The £650 million that you quote relates entirely to cash-releasing savings, as does the £1 billion.
Including the local government element?
Yes.
We might want to write to you about that, but I am happy to leave that question for another day.
The plan will be published in a matter of days. You might want to have a look at that and then come back to us on that point.
I have a final question. I concur about the need for like-for-like comparisons, so when a parliamentary question gets an answer that refers to securing
I am not familiar with that exact parliamentary question.
Many parliamentary questions have received answers that the Scottish Executive is undertaking an efficiency initiative that is as ambitious as the Gershon review in its scope, and it has said that it and will seek
It will be over the same time horizon in the sense that Gershon goes up only to 2007-08 at the moment. It will not be comparable in the sense that the Scottish ministers are already looking at taking the efficiency work up to 2010 and have already set out their targets for that period. Comparisons have to be made over the same time period.
I want to talk about the refreshed version of "A Smart, Successful Scotland" and contemplate the four years that have gone before. There has been much criticism that the strategy has been neither smart nor successful and that it has choked, rather than helped, our economy. Are you able to point to a single measurable achievement of the smart, successful Scotland strategy during those four years?
First of all, we have to decide whether we are talking about outputs or outcomes. We could list many outputs and I will give you one or two. There are also some issues about the time period during which those outputs will impact on the economy. There are many outputs, such as the businesses that have been supported or have undertaken research and development, or the young people who have undertaken modern apprenticeships. All those outputs are designed to improve the productivity of the skills base and the technology that contributes to the improvement in productivity.
One of the indicators that you outlined that you are determined to resolve is the one on entrepreneurialism. Even using such a basic measurement, we seem to be going backwards. The number of new companies in Scotland fell in the year to the end of June.
It might have done; I do not have the exact figure. However, it is not helpful to consider one short time period. The SSS report shows that between 1999 and 2002 there was some positive progress.
We need to be careful about the years that we look at. I strongly emphasise that the nature of this strategic approach is to take a longer-term, non-cyclical look at the way in which the economy is running. Ministers' intention not to respond immediately to the economic cycle is an important difference, and an important characteristic of FEDS is to take a longer-term, strategic view. So if, in the course of a difficult period of global or Scottish growth, fewer companies are being formed, that has to be accepted as part of the strategy. I do not think that there is any sense in which the strategy is aiming to counter that cycle; it is focused on trying to counter the long-term structural position of the past 20 to 30 years.
Would you not accept that even a simple measure such as lowering business rates might have had a tremendous effect? It seems that we are now going in that direction.
Ministers have taken the view that business rates have an effect on corporate behaviour. They are a relatively small part of total corporate costs but the revenues that are raised from business rates have a role to play in supporting other forms of public expenditure. The priorities that are set out in FEDS entail public expenditure and ministers have taken the view that some of the drivers of economic development set out in that framework need to be well funded, and they are content with the balance between business rates and the funding of those important programmes.
In view of the long-term view that you are taking—which is quite right in many ways—why was it necessary to refresh and reissue the document if, by its very nature, we were not going to have the results of the first version, or be able to tell whether the strategy was working, for a much longer period than has elapsed since it was first published?
That is a fair question. The reason why we refreshed the document and why ministers requested that we undertake the consultation was to confirm that other people shared our view. Ministers were of the view that there had been some fairly dramatic changes in the global economy during that period of time, as you will recollect, and that there was an important question about whether those major global developments could have had an impact on the type of strategy that we were pursuing. It is only fair to say that ministers' starting point was that they felt that such an impact was unlikely, but that it was only correct that after those four years of quite serious global upheaval, we should revisit the question. That was why we did so.
I will be a little more direct than Alasdair Morgan. In a sense, it is always important to do a little bit more horizon scanning but, instead of a refresh of FEDS, would ministers not have preferred an integrated action or implementation plan that says what ministers are now going to do?
The approach that was adopted with the first version of FEDS is still the current approach. FEDS is a strategic framework for the direction of activities, but not the action plan itself. The action plan should come from different portfolios in the Executive in relation to how they interpret and implement FEDS. For example, an obvious example is the way in which the action plans for the enterprise network implement FEDS. Similarly, we expect other departments, such as the Education Department, to capture the key principles or drivers in FEDS in the work that they do. It has never really been the intention that FEDS, or a second supporting document for FEDS, should try to provide that action programme for the Executive as whole. The intention was always that that should be embedded in departments or portfolios and in the way in which they define their strategic approach, with FEDS as a clear objective—alongside others, no doubt. Jane Morgan might want to say some more about the enterprise action programmes.
Obviously, the smart, successful Scotland strategy develops some of the strands of FEDS in greater detail. It is for the enterprise networks to produce corporate plans that are, in a sense, the action plan that takes that forward. The enterprise networks are best placed to do that, but they do so in dialogue with the Executive. The process involves FEDS, then the smart, successful Scotland strategy and then the corporate plans, which set out the action plan in detail.
The question that I want to ask on the back of that might be best put to Jim Mackinnon. In west-central Scotland, since the second world war, we have had a series of planning frameworks that have had an effect on, for example, the regional council's structural plan, and which sought to tie together issues of economic development, transport, water and sewerage investment and regeneration plans. For some reason, housing was excluded, but it should not have been. The frameworks for implementation were partly to do with scanning the circumstances but they were also designed to present strategic choices. How the national planning framework, FEDS and the smart, successful Scotland strategy contribute to an integrated programme of decision making is not clear to me. In what way do they allow us to determine what is needed and how we can prioritise the spending across the various portfolios? If we view such decisions as being a matter for the portfolios, there is no drive from the strategy framework towards a strategy.
Jim Mackinnon might want to comment on the planning framework.
The national planning framework was a first attempt to examine Scotland as a place, how it was changing, what the drivers of change were and what the implications of that were for the various parts of Scotland. We were clear about the fact that the policy had geographic implications and that some areas were growing rapidly while others were in need of regeneration.
Other members will want to pursue this issue but I am interested in how we get from the creation of the planning framework—which is a consensual piece of work—to making decisions and saying, "We could do a variety of things but we are going to do this for these reasons." I am not sure how we get to that point or what mechanisms exist between ministers to ensure that we can get to that point.
Jim Mackinnon's answer to the convener's question captured precisely the contradiction that he is outlining. In Mr Mackinnon's paper, there is a legitimate claim that support for cities is needed as they are the main drivers of the economy and, in Dr Goudie's paper, there is an identification of the intractable problems of persistent high levels of unemployment in areas such as my constituency. How can the latter issue come to be reflected in the expenditure plan?
I have seen the review papers that you received as background information and I have some difficulties with some parts of them in relation to the urban-rural issue that you mention.
Irrespective of how you arrive at that number, how the adviser arrives at it or how 20 other economists arrive at it, is the balance right at the moment?
The balance that the Executive is worried about is not so much to do with the urban-rural thing, although that is important, but to do with economic development. Discussions have been much more focused on whether the balance between the key components of skills and education, infrastructure and direct enterprise is right. That is where the main emphasis has come. Cutting across that, however, has been the important question whether the rural interest and the support that comes from the European Union side and through the Scottish Executive Environment and Rural Affairs Department is adequate for the sort of development that is sought.
I want to come back to Jim Mackinnon on planning.
We published the west Edinburgh planning framework last March, with the agreement of all the stakeholders. The framework has been well received and that has been helpful in the debate on heavy rail and tram systems for the city. To reinforce the point that Andrew Goudie made, within two hours you can get from west Edinburgh to very many parts of Scotland.
You have just confirmed that it took two years from when the Executive announced its intention to have an NPPG for west Edinburgh for all the stakeholders to agree, and you reached an NPPG in March 2004—
No. It actually took a year.
So it took a year from the announcement of the intention for the Executive—
That involved working with the stakeholders, with a three or four-month consultation period, and getting the document finalised. Given that most local plans in Scotland take the best part of five years to produce, and given that 40 per cent of local plans are more than 10 years out of date, I think that doing such a strategic document with considerable stakeholder support in a year is quite an achievement.
Sure. Is there an intention for the Clyde corridor yet? How long do you expect that to take? Given that the intention to pursue such a plan in both areas was announced two years ago, what is your timescale?
Jane Morgan might be able to say more about the Clyde corridor, as she has been closer to Clyde regeneration than I have been.
Do we have a policy intention for an NPPG or not? I am just trying to establish the position.
There is no intention and no commitment to do a Clyde corridor planning framework at the moment.
The Executive's target for the processing of major applications, both industrial and residential, is that 80 per cent of major applications should be determined in four months. It is clear that delays in the system are a problem. It would not be possible for any member of the public to determine, from looking at the current planning audit that the Executive publishes, where our performance is against that target over any recent time horizon, because major applications have two composite elements. Could the Executive publish data on its own performance in relation to major applications against its own target, to elucidate the debate in the run-up to the discussions on planning that lie ahead of us? It is unfortunate that the published planning audit of performance does not let us look at trend performance against the Executive's target. That may be an oversight, but I think that it would help the current debate.
We publish figures, and not just for local performance, but I am not sure whether we do so on a trend basis. We also publish figures on our own performance, which are quite commendable in relation to the processing of major applications. That includes notified applications, which we have the option to clear back to the councils—for example, the application for the world headquarters of the Royal Bank of Scotland was cleared back to City of Edinburgh Council within three weeks—and appeals that are recalled for decision by ministers. Our performance targets for those things are in the public domain, and I think that they are quite commendable.
I do not want to pursue the matter now, but it would be helpful if Jim Mackinnon could write to the committee to clarify where we can find performance data on the target of 80 per cent of major applications being dealt with over four months, that being a composite of both industrial and residential applications. It would interest the committee to see those data, but I am happy to receive the information in writing.
I am happy to write with more data on that if it would be helpful. The other thing that I should say is that the Glasgow and Clyde valley structure plan team is taking an active interest in providing and articulating a framework for the regeneration of that area.
With regard to the spatial work that is being done, I am slightly alarmed by some parts of the paper that you have presented to us. I understand the Commission wanting more spatial work to be done, which will shape decisions on distributing expenditure, and you also have a strategy that is predominantly based on the cities. What mechanism will there be in the spatial work for deciding on the distribution of expenditure? What will be the process and the decisions on that? Your planning policy is stated in black and white, but there is uncertainty with regard to how the spatial work will be put together.
I shall deal first with the first point, about the European Commission. Strong signs are emanating from the Commission that suggest that it wants to see spatial frameworks being prepared so that it can see how resource allocation fits, not just in Scotland but in other parts of Europe. That was one of the drivers for the work that has been undertaken.
I am like Jeremy Purvis in some respects, because my area of Dumfries and Galloway does not identify with any Scottish cities. The identification at the Dumfries end is with Carlisle, not Glasgow or Edinburgh.
Your point about the position of Dumfries and Galloway is absolutely right, and it is reflected in the national planning framework, which recognises that Ayrshire and the south-west form an important gateway to Scotland. We have become terribly interested in connections to continental Europe, which are important for Scotland, but connections to Ireland are critical and it is important that we do not lose sight of that. Ayrshire and the south-west are critical. We also recognise the important economic generator in the south-west that is Crichton campus. In terms of devolved education and being a generator of economic development, the campus has been hugely impressive. We recognise other opportunities, which often are small scale, such as Wigtown as the national book town.
We all agree that small businesses are an important part of economic growth and development in Scotland. Great emphasis is placed on that in various ways. What analysis has been made of the failure of small businesses, to prevent such businesses from failing in the future? Every business is a potential failure. Unless the matter is properly analysed, how can we stop the domino effect?
I am not sure whether Scottish Enterprise has done any work on that. About two years ago, the University of Strathclyde reviewed the Scottish Executive's business birth rate strategy, which focused on why we had not succeeded in increasing the business birth rate at the rate that we had hoped. I am not sure whether that went into detail on what you ask; Jane Morgan may remember.
I do not, but I know that the problems that companies face in the early stages and later have been addressed over the past few years. One such issue is access to finance. Over the past five years, there has been a considerable increase, for example, in helping companies to access equity investors such as business angels. That is a particular problem area, which is increasingly being addressed, for example through the co-investment fund.
Surely a good way of helping to grow the economy would be to examine the obvious pitfalls that many small companies face and to highlight them for the future benefit of new start-ups.
Yes. We might have to look back over that and give you an answer in writing on what has been done, because many issues contribute to business failure. However, one would always expect to see a degree of churn. One will never get to the stage at which there are no business failures. The important point is to increase the volume and accept that there will be a degree of churn.
Margaret Curran's introduction to the planning framework states:
At the end of the national planning framework we talk about making it happen. The framework covers a wide range of subjects. Many of the issues are decisions not for the Executive, but for agencies, local authorities and the private sector. We have posed some of the choices for Scotland in terms of regeneration and development. Andrew Goudie might be able to say more about how that has begun to feed through into the framework for economic development. We have already seen it have an impact on, for example, the work of Scottish Water, in terms of the priority that has been afforded to servicing development, which is a key concern of the development industry.
Scottish Enterprise, for example, fed views to Jim Mackinnon for the national planning framework. Those views are reflected in two main ways—first, in the provision of bespoke business infrastructure, such as science parks, and secondly in more integrated, wide-ranging regeneration projects, in which the networks require to work with other partners. Analysis will feed through to expenditure on property and, to an extent, to the allocations to local enterprise companies, in recognition of the opportunities and challenges that they face in their areas.
I presume that that applies to transport issues and across the broad expenditure framework.
That is broadly right. I return to the point that FEDS is designed to set a relatively high-level framework for activity, and to raise the priorities for consideration within portfolios and departments. It is important that the interaction between the planning framework and FEDS has had an iteration over the past four or five years. It feeds through to transport in the same way. That is a good example.
I thank the witnesses for coming along. I remind members that our next three evidence sessions will be next week, 7 December and 14 December.
Meeting suspended.
On resuming—