Official Report 185KB pdf
We now return to our local government finance inquiry. Again, we welcome to the meeting our adviser Rita Hale. Today we will hear from a variety of witnesses, covering a range of issues. Professor Arthur Midwinter is unable to appear before the committee; unfortunately, he has flu. I have slotted him in for next week. Members should be warned that next week's meeting will again be a long one.
Good afternoon. I have appeared before the committee before, but never in quite this format or on my own. It feels a bit like being in the dock.
Thank you. Your written submission is mostly concerned with non-domestic rates. You say that the non-domestic rate
I cannot answer that question offhand, although I can certainly provide details in writing to the committee. However, I have some figures on local business property taxes as a proportion of GDP, which show how much of the wealth that business creates is taken in business taxes by local government in different countries. The latest figure for the UK—it is a couple of years old now—is 1.8 per cent of GDP, which is higher than the proportion in most European countries. For example, in France, the figure is 0.5 per cent; in the Netherlands, 0.4 per cent; in Germany, 0.3 per cent; and in Ireland, 0.4 per cent. Overall, we think that the issue is significant.
That would be helpful. I will now open the floor to questions from members.
Your submission mentions that the CBI strongly supports the uniform business rate. Is the size of the non-domestic rate bill one of the most important factors for the location of businesses or are other factors taken into consideration?
It is one of the factors. Different businesses consider different issues to be key. Transport links are often considered important. Skills and local skills shortages are also a factor. Non-domestic rates are not necessarily the most important issue for all businesses, but they can be for some.
You say that the UBR is not the most important factor in deciding where to locate a business. The labour force, transport and the working environment would probably be higher up the scale than the UBR.
It is hard to generalise. For some businesses, the UBR may be the most important factor. That depends on a business's cost structure, its margins and other factors. For other businesses, access to local labour markets or transport is more important.
Do you have statistics on your members citing the UBR, local transport links or labour force accessibility as factors?
We might have. In a survey that we published about two weeks ago, we asked questions about competitiveness. I do not remember offhand whether a question was asked on business rates, but transport and transport links were high on many companies' agendas. I will check the detail and send copies of the survey to the committee.
That would be lovely. Thank you.
Do you have experience of the business rate causing a business to relocate? If so, will you give details?
I do not have personal experience, but I can check with my colleagues and find out whether examples of difficulties exist. When companies make such decisions, a complex range of factors including future markets, investment plans, transport, skills, rates and other costs is often considered. Companies are not always willing to share that information with outside parties—even a body such as the CBI, to which they may belong—because they feel that the precise mix of reasons for making those decisions is subject to commercial confidentiality. I will find out whether we have examples but, because commercial factors are involved, it is difficult to find instances of companies saying, "This was a reason; this was a factor; this cost was so much."
Nevertheless, you are sure that changing to a non-uniform business rate would have a bad effect on businesses.
We take that view because our members tell us that. There is a long history to the issue. In the early 1990s, the view of Scottish businesses was that business rates in Scotland were much higher than those in the south. I worked for the CBI in London in the early 1990s. Whenever we had meetings with a range of members—particularly those that were smaller companies—from throughout the UK, a smaller company from Scotland would always ask why business rates were so high.
You said that the business rate in Scotland was higher than that in England. Do you know of companies that have chosen not to locate here or that have relocated to England because of that?
I can find out whether we have examples. The phenomenon is fairly new, because, as I said, the link was broken only last year or the year before that. The issue has caused much concern among companies in Scotland and location decisions are not all that is involved.
All the information that we have received is backed up by statistics or by studies to show this or that, and everyone can defend their corner. However, some studies have shown that the market determines the price of a property and that, if rates are depressed, rents rise, and vice versa. Do you accept that?
I would like to wade through whatever piece of evidence suggests that. Property prices can fluctuate for a range of reasons, but our concern about business rates is that local flexibility should not be used simply to offset other factors. Rates will be seen as a source of additional revenue; that will happen independently of what the property market is doing.
If you accept that there is an argument for that, would you also accept that the return of non-domestic rates to local control would have no real effect on the total price of property?
No. I would like to see the evidence for what you suggest. Our perception is that, to the extent that those market movements happen, they are not perfect. You do not find that rates change a bit and that there is then an automatic offset and vice versa. There may be something of that going on in the mix, but property prices move for a range of reasons. If business rates are steadily increased, it does not necessarily follow that all properties affected will decrease in rental value.
Your submission says that the CBI is opposed to the granting of rates relief for small businesses. In fact, you say that the likely beneficiaries of rates relief are "lifestyle firms". What is a lifestyle firm? What is the CBI's view on the granting of relief to small firms that provide essential services, for example in remote areas?
I am happy to tell you that. I have a sense of déjà vu. I think that we spent some time at a previous session talking about the rural scheme, so I did not come with all the facts at my fingertips on this occasion.
You are saying that you are in favour of the uniform business rate being applied at a national level, but that you are prepared to make exceptions for certain companies and firms in rural areas depending on the circumstances. Is that not just bureaucracy?
That is the danger and that is why we are cautious about going down that route. We take into account the fact that there seems to be a particular issue about small firms in rural locations. There are proposals for an Executive scheme to address that issue. After talking to our members in rural and urban areas, we felt that, on balance, it was worth making an exception for those small firms.
I understand that you are saying that lifestyle firms are generally small businesses because people choose to set them up as such. Is there any evidence that the majority of those very small businesses remain very small businesses, or is it not a fact that those firms, which you dismiss so readily, will grow in the future?
You say that I dismiss the firms readily. My point was that, if our interest is in the economy of Scotland and meeting our collective needs for employment and wealth creation, we should not be focusing on those firms.
I would like clarification of a small point about lifestyle firms. You mention in your submission that you are against rates relief for lifestyle firms. I took out of your submission the fact that lifestyle firms might also service big businesses not just with materials, but with staff, such as in the case of small shops. I just wanted clarification about what you mean. If lifestyle firms disappear, it is not just the businesses that will suffer, but the communities within the areas in which those small firms operate.
It is hard to be precise about definitions. There are a quarter of a million small firms in Scotland, which are all unique; we are trying to get to grips with them in different ways. The key factor—this is not purely a CBI interpretation; it is a research-based one—is the motivation of the owner-manager. Are they seeking to set up a small shop with the aim of expanding the business and setting up another small shop? Take the example of Pret A Manger, which started with one shop in St Martin's Lane in London. It is now a global business employing a lot of people in Scotland. That expansion was always the intention of the two guys who set it up.
You will be aware from the evidence that we have taken, which is quite substantial, that a case is building that small businesses carry a greater burden than larger businesses as far as rates are concerned. Would the CBI still be opposed to small business rates relief if the costs were to be met by the Exchequer from national taxation rather than by a supplement on the national non-domestic rate?
We would not be opposed in the same way. For the reasons that I have mentioned, the view that we have taken—I can understand the confusion that arises—is that we do not see the approach that you mention as an effective measure to boost the economy, jobs and output. We would be particularly unhappy if the costs of all other business—not just big businesses, but small and medium ones—were hiked up to pay for a measure that we think will not boost the economy.
We are getting into the realms of taxation, which is a reserved responsibility. Hypothetically, would you support a system based on the ability to pay?
In what sense?
In the sense that businesses base their rates on what they can afford to pay. You implied as much by saying that you would support costs being met through national taxation.
There are a couple of issues. If the Exchequer were to pay for small business rates relief, that would not have the negative impact on other businesses.
Is it more important to the CBI that the business rate is uniform or that the increases in the rate are predictable?
That is a good politician's question. Both those factors are important. Ultimately, the level of the business rate is more important, but we are concerned about predictability, because we have noticed a pretty wide, cross-sector trend. Many of our surveys ask businesses about their expectations for output, orders and employment for the following four months or year, but businesses find it harder and harder to answer. Two or three years ago, they had a fairly clear idea of orders and output for the following six months, but because the markets are now more competitive, businesses are uncertain, which means that they cannot be sure three weeks in advance.
I probe the matter because I am interested. If the link to the RPI was broken and the Government could increase the UBR depending on the increase in local government expenditure that it wanted—which is less predictable—would the UBR still be acceptable?
There is a distinction between the system and how people pull the levers. We value the UBR because the level is set nationally. If the level were pushed above what we think is reasonable, we would criticise the decision rather than the UBR. We would agree with legislation to the effect that the UBR could never be increased by more than the RPI.
Has the CBI considered business taxation in other countries? If so, are there lessons to be learned from how other countries tax businesses for local purposes?
We have not considered local taxation in particular. The main lesson I have learned is that we must be wary of what politicians in the UK tell us about the UK tax system. We are often told that we have a low business tax environment, but in other European countries, although the headline rates of business taxation may be higher, there are many more different types of allowances, such as allowances for capital spending. The actual amount that is taken from business is much the same as here. I have some figures, which I can circulate to the committee. They break down the taxes in different ways. In the UK, we take 14.1 per cent of GDP in business taxation. In Germany, the figure is 12.3 per cent. The figure is lower, but that is not the message you get from just the headline rate.
I know that we have spoken about small businesses before. You say at the second bullet point on page 2 of your submission:
Those are good questions. We have tried to be honest and as clear as possible in our evidence. I wanted to make it clear that we are conscious of the pressures on medium firms. We feel a particular obligation to represent those firms. We all know about the big businesses; many are CBI members and are able to lobby. There is also a lot of political interest, for understandable reasons, in the role of very small businesses in the economy. We are concerned that a lot of Government policy has been made on the basis that, if a business is not small, it is big. The Government has helped very small businesses with employment legislation, but has implied that, if a company has more than 10 employees, it can cope with any difficulties. Many companies in our membership are in the medium bracket and they have been very hard hit. They do not get exemptions. Although no big business likes the sort of regulations that have been proposed, medium businesses are even more exposed. We feel a particular obligation towards those businesses. A body such as the Federation of Small Businesses does not have such a broad membership of medium businesses. No one else seems to represent those businesses well. That is why we have been especially keen to get their concerns across to the committee.
Do you agree that the small businesses that are in the CBI have a point when they say that they are just outside the threshold of the relief scheme and so will not get relief?
Part of our concern with the scheme is that, however it is arranged, there will have to be a threshold, which, inevitably, will be pretty low—it will be £10,000 or £15,000 or something—because the money is not there to have a scheme for everyone.
I thank you for that. We are grateful for your offer to give us more information on a couple of points. Thank you for your time.
Thank you for giving us the opportunity to appear before the committee to contribute to the debate on what we consider to be an important issue.
Thank you. Before I take questions from members, I would like to ask a question myself.
I am not convinced that we can answer those questions positively for the period that I was chairman of the Scottish Chambers of Commerce. Happily, I was chairman not for 14 years, but for four. If it were 14, I do not think that I would be with you any longer.
From my questioning of the previous witness, you will gather that I have a favourite expression. In your written evidence you say that whatever system is used, whether it be the council tax or another system, it should be based on ability to pay. How would you go about ensuring that?
In my time, we have fought for the tax system to be acceptable. No tax system is popular—by definition—but for a system to be acceptable it must have two elements. First, it must be seen to be fair in its treatment of individual ratepayers. Secondly, it should be simple to administer. There is concern about the inequity that the Executive's proposals on rates relief would introduce, particularly if one ratepayer ended up funding his brother next door. There is also concern about the complications that arise from the proposals. Those would be considerably greater if ability to pay were the primary consideration.
In your evidence, you say that the system should be based on the ability to pay. Now you are saying that that is impractical.
The issue is indirectly about ability to pay. The proposals that are set out in the consultation paper are, in a sense, ability-to-pay measures, but they are still based on the property value. As property value is primary in the proposals and a business must demonstrate ability to pay to the assessor or to the local authority finance department, ability to pay is a secondary matter.
In your written evidence, you state that new capital works should be carried out as public-private partnership schemes. Many of the witnesses who have given evidence to the committee have criticised PPP schemes. They have said that the set-up costs are too high, the lead times are too long and the schemes are expensive, because private firms cannot borrow as cheaply as public bodies and must put a price on the risks associated with the schemes. Have you heard those criticisms and, if so, how do you respond to them?
No matter what we do, there will always be criticism. We must attempt to obtain best value whenever we can and we must have a transparent way of doing that. One of the dangers is that that has not always been the case with PPP schemes, which has probably put those schemes under more duress.
You said that you try to get best value whenever you can.
I will rephrase that—we always try.
The next question is obvious. Have you considered any other ways of securing investment in infrastructure?
We considered the American concept of a local economic area—which our friends in the CBI will probably know of—whereby a local authority and its ratepayers agree to raise a certain sum for specific expenditure on improving infrastructure and the like in the area. We expressed neither opposition to nor support for that concept, but felt that it was at least worth considering. We recognised the problems that local government has had in providing infrastructure projects over the past few years, when funding has been so tight.
On the UBR, your submission is similar to the CBI's. I do not wish to question you any further on that—we have gone through that quite carefully. I am more inclined to question you on what your submission says about the balance of funding between central Government and local government. The question that I will ask you might seem unfair, but I will ask it anyway.
Those are some of the views that our members thought were worth considering. A root-and-branch review of local government finance was a common theme. Our submission states that we feel that balance is needed to return to local accountability. The members believe that too big a proportion of the money provided to local authorities is not raised locally and so they have little influence.
You are talking about a form of local income tax.
Something along those lines.
I see that a tax based on the ability to pay is mentioned in your submission.
Yes. Whatever scheme is introduced, we recommend that it be based on the ability to pay.
So one of your answers would be a local income tax.
Something like a local income tax.
You have mentioned local income tax, but you also go on to say that you are not in favour of allowing local authorities to increase the amount raised locally. A local income tax would increase the amount raised locally.
We mean that the gross take should not be greater. If businesses were paying a local tax, they would not pay so much centrally, so the overall take would not be greater.
That would shift the balance.
You are suggesting a local income tax without increasing the overall take. Would not that reduce the overall take because of the administrative costs of collecting a local income tax?
It might do that marginally, but I am sure that there would be a way of dividing up the money without increasing the administrative burden.
I wish that I had your confidence.
Do you have any experience or knowledge of other countries that use such a system without the administration becoming burdensome?
I do not but some of my colleagues might have.
I do not.
It might be interesting to find that out.
Is the Scottish Chambers of Commerce happy with a property tax for businesses as the means of contributing to local government, albeit that there is a uniform national rate? Have you considered any alternative forms of taxation for the funding of local government?
At the moment, we think that a property tax is the most simple and straightforward way. We cannot think of any other way that would be as accessible.
Your submission seems to say that your main concern is competitiveness and so the key issue is uniformity rather than the predictability of the UBR. Is that a fair assumption?
The simple answer to that is yes. I would like Geoffrey Johnston to say a few words about his personal experience of that. We are seeking to have a system that will support small businesses. We believe that there should be such a system.
I agree with the last point because of the issue of equity between one ratepayer and another.
I have a point about predictability. We agree with the CBI that it is vital that businesses know what their business rates are going to be. The ultimate predictability would be knowing that business rates would not increase at all. It is helpful for businesses to know about increases in the RPI.
Thank you. Your final remarks were very interesting. Do you have a note of what the finance department of the Scottish Executive is hiding from us that you could pass to us after the meeting?
With pleasure, convener.
There do not seem to be any more questions. I thank the witnesses very much for coming along and giving us your time. We shall be in touch with you again if we need to be.
Meeting adjourned.
On resuming—
I introduce Andrew Clearie, who is project adviser in the private finance unit of the Scottish Executive's finance and central services department, and Mary Munro, who is head of the capital finance branch of the Scottish Executive's local government finance and performance division. Please start with a few comments on your paper. We will then ask questions.
I will not go into detail on my paper, because the committee will have read it by now. By way of opening remarks, I will make only a couple of points. First, I will explain a bit about the unit in which I work and its role. Secondly, I will draw the distinction between public-private partnerships and private finance initiatives, because the terms are often spoken of in the same breath and are often confused.
The unit is understandably pleased that so many school PFI projects are in the pipeline. What, if any, checks does the unit make to ensure that the population projections for the area that is likely to be served by each proposed school indicate that the school is likely to have a life that at least matches the length of the PFI contract?
We require local authorities that seek support for any school PFI or PPP project that they are developing to present us with an outline business case, in which we expect to see that sort of detail and some logical connection between demographic projections and the scope of the project.
So there are checks. However, education authorities can elect to close and sell any school that has a declining school roll. What would happen to a schools PFI project in which the school roll suddenly declined?
As demand risk lies with the public sector, the PFI contract would contain provisions to change its scope to take account of the fact that the school was perhaps no longer needed. Because of their long-term nature, contracts must necessarily include change mechanisms.
Who is taking the risk?
In a PFI deal, the public sector usually takes the risk for demand, which in this case means the risk that a school's roll might exceed provision or fall below a viable level.
Your written evidence stresses the importance of securing value for money from PFI schemes and it cites the results of the Arthur Andersen study as proof that PFI schemes produce savings. Are you aware of the comments that were made by the House of Commons Treasury Select Committee about the validity of the results of that study?
No, I am not.
Okay. According to the Treasury Select Committee, the Arthur Andersen report said that it considered savings in a sample of 29 PFI projects for which a public sector comparator was available. In 12 projects, insufficient information was available to allow a risk assessment. Furthermore, the Treasury Select Committee report states:
It is true that the position of such deals is often dependent on the valuation of risk. We would want to check that the risk had been evaluated in a rigorous way that was shown to be robust, and that some kind of sensitivity analysis had been done on the key assumptions that were made about risk. I do not want to say anything beyond that.
Some members are concerned about PFI-PPP projects. Little information is available about such projects because the information is tied up with commercial confidentiality. However, a study has been done by the Treasury Select Committee. I find it surprising—nay, astonishing—that the Scottish Executive's private finance unit should have no knowledge about that or the Arthur Andersen report.
You misunderstood me. I have full knowledge of the Arthur Andersen report. You asked me about the select committee's comments and I replied that I was not aware of them. I was not sure how members would approach that question, but I am fully aware of the arguments behind the valuation of risk in projects.
Surely it is incumbent on you at least to be aware of what the House of Commons Treasury Select Committee said about the Arthur Andersen report before you cite it. The select committee seems not to give the value and credibility to the Arthur Andersen report that your submission gives it.
The Arthur Andersen report was very open about the assumptions that were made on the projects that it sampled. The report made the same point that you made; the value for money of a large number of the projects was dependent on the values that were given to risk within the value-for-money assessment. All that I am saying is that I am fully aware of the potential pitfalls of assessing risk within projects. In more recent projects, it has been my experience that any analysis that is undertaken goes some way towards addressing those potential pitfalls.
Your submission cites the results of the Arthur Andersen study as evidence that PFI schemes produce savings.
The Arthur Andersen study was clear that, in the projects that it sampled, the average savings were 17 per cent.
That same Arthur Andersen study was criticised by the Treasury Select Committee. The select committee found that PFI did not produce the savings that the Arthur Andersen study and your submission suggest.
In my submission, I cited a statement of fact from the Arthur Andersen report. I do not know what I can say beyond that.
In addition to risk, elements such as the profit element of PPP schemes have caused concerns. Your submission refers to the work that Partnerships UK has done on a not-for-profit model for delivering new schools, which you call the non-profit distributing bodies model. Will you explain further what that model entails.
There are a number of different approaches to not-for-profit models. Fundamentally, as the name suggests, the non-profit distributing bodies model means that there is no distribution of profits to shareholders; the profits are reinvested in the company.
Is it as simple as that?
Yes.
How much development of that model has taken place?
Argyll and Bute Council is looking at that type of model for its schools PPP, which it is currently scoping. Partnerships UK is working with that council on the project. We are awaiting a report from it on the viability of that model.
Is there a time scale for when that could be brought into use?
The time scale for that project depends on how the project is developed by the council.
So must you work closely with the local authority on all aspects of it?
Yes.
One of the concerns that is regularly expressed to me by people in the local government community is about the complexity, time scale and cost of introducing PPP schemes, even before they get to the development stage. The amount of work that is involved and the cost and the time scale are sometimes quite horrendous. Has your unit examined those aspects—the preparation costs—to see whether they can be improved and made simpler and cheaper?
One of the roles of the unit is to provide technical support to project teams. There are now many PFI projects, which are at various stages of procurement. We have learned lessons from the early projects. We are trying to put in place a number of measures to reduce procurement time for projects, because procurement is a lengthy and expensive process. For example, we are trying to increase the amount of standardisation of contract documentation. The Office of Government Commerce has produced a revised Treasury task force standard document, which will be issued soon. The Executive is developing a standard Scottish schools contract for PFI schools.
A second issue that is raised is that the more rural authorities have more difficulty introducing PPP schemes because the size of projects that are available to them is not sufficient to make them viable. Are you considering ways in which that can be addressed?
It is generally accepted—certainly for PFI deals—that the threshold in the schools market, for example, is about £10 million. Below that, the viability of the project and its attractiveness to the market are questionable. One way round that is to encourage authorities to bundle schools together into larger packages. That might mean bundling within one authority, as Falkirk did with its schools project, or it might mean neighbouring authorities working together on joint procurement.
Looking ahead, the costs of servicing PPP projects will have first call on local authority resources, particularly capital resources, in future years. Is the unit keeping an eye on the implications of that for local authority budgets? I envisage a time—five, 10 or 15 years down the line—when there might be a major problem for local authorities because so much of the money is tied into servicing of existing schemes.
We do not track the implications in respect of individual authorities' budgets, but we keep an eye on the overall picture, which is the revenue commitment that arises from PFI projects. I think I am right in saying that the Scottish budget documents now carry figures for revenue and capital commitments under PFI.
On level-playing-field support, your submission says:
Exceptions have arisen because some projects have not moved forward as quickly as we had hoped and the original deadline was going to cause problems for them. For example, because of the protracted procurement timetable that is associated with roads projects—due to public inquiries and so on—the A92 project will not meet that deadline.
Did you mention 1992?
The project is the A92 road project.
I was wondering about that. It is way past 1992.
The level-playing-field support was allocated in 1998, so we had to estimate when we thought the latest of the projects would be completed. At that time, four years seemed quite reasonable. Indeed, most projects have successfully met that deadline.
How much money has the Executive committed over the next 25 years to make PFI attractive to local authorities? Has the Executive looked that far forward?
We do forward projections in relation to level-playing-field support. I do not know the exact figure for the 25-year period, but it seems that the Executive commits between £55 million and £60 million a year to level-playing-field support.
Would you be able to get that information for the committee?
We could make that available.
We have heard how PFI schemes will be monitored and evaluated in terms of best value. How will that process take place?
We are putting in place arrangements to monitor PFI projects in operation. That has to be done against the backdrop of best value. We are lagging slightly behind England in the implementation of best value.
I would like to ask a supplementary question on that point before you answer my second question. Could we have information on paper that shows how a PFI that is up and running—so that confidentiality is not an issue—is of best value and how it is being monitored? That would allow us to see how the process operates.
To be honest, I have not thought about that.
Will you find out whether that is possible?
Yes.
I will return to Iain Smith's point about the revenue costs of PFIs over the next 25 years. Correct me if I am wrong, but I think you said that you monitored the situation for Scotland but that your figures have not been disaggregated.
We monitor the situation on a sectoral basis for Scotland. Those figures are sent to the Treasury biannually and we use them in our budget documents.
You say that you have figures for the cost over the next 25 years of present PFIs and for their cost year on year and that you give those figures to the Treasury.
Obviously, we also use them in our own Scottish budget documents.
Will you make those figures available to the committee?
We have made that information available in parliamentary written answers.
I do not think so. David Davidson requested the information as recently as 14 September. He was told:
I say with respect that the figures for the full period have been made available in parliamentary written answers. However, I am willing to make those figures available to the committee too.
Okay. Thank you.
Meeting continued in private until 16:03.
Previous
Items in Private