Official Report 529KB pdf
Item 2 is evidence from our witnesses on the Regulatory Reform (Scotland) Bill. I invite the witnesses to introduce themselves and to make brief opening statements, if they wish to do so.
Thank you for the opportunity to give evidence to the committee. Social enterprise is a business model that is already heavily regulated, whether in relation to the discipline in which organisations participate or in the construct of the organisations. I suggest that there is already heavy regulation in the context of housing, financial services, social care, health, criminal justice, employability, tourism, retail and hospitality. On the construct of organisations, a whole range of regulation already affects the way that community interest companies, Scottish charitable incorporated organisations or companies limited by guarantee that have charitable status do business.
I am an assistant secretary with the Scottish Trades Union Congress. Given the focus of the discussion, it is probably also relevant to say that I am a long-standing member of the Scottish Government’s regulatory review group.
I am the director for Scotland for Consumer Futures, which is the new name for Consumer Focus Scotland. In light of the United Kingdom Government’s reforms of the consumer landscape, we now work only on energy, post and water, but we have a remit to apply our insight to regulatory markets in general.
I am the head of bargaining and campaigns at Unison Scotland. We represent the staff who administer most regulation. We made the case in our submission for the value of regulation to be recognised. Like others, we are concerned about the confusion that the economic growth proposal creates. We are also concerned about the centralisation proposed in the bill, particularly through national directions and planning fees.
If witnesses and members wish to make a point, they should catch Diane Barr’s attention. She will pass the information on to me and we will move on from there.
In simple terms, the answer is no—needless to say, I will expand on that. Regulation is different in different fields and in different parts of the country. Most of our members are involved in local regulation and have to reflect the needs of not just businesses but the community. If you read the planning sections of the bill, you would think that the only customers of a planning department are developers, when, in fact, the customers are us—the community. Planners have to take into account a wide variety of interests. That is difficult when community interests come up against commercial interests; nonetheless, it is the job of planners to look after us, not simply to look after businesses’ interests.
We agree with the proposal to place a duty on local authorities, but we feel strongly that there needs to be provision for an evidence-based case for exceptions. We think that national standards will bring consistency, fairness and transparency, which we think will benefit consumers and business and should result in clear national priorities and better co-ordination and dialogue between agencies. We think that that will offer benefits to consumers and maximise efficiency and effectiveness.
You do not believe that centralisation of the standards would be objective.
We are not saying that centralisation would not be objective. The standards themselves are set in the context of their being centralised. That is fine. However, we are not entirely convinced that having the same framework that set the standards then being responsible for agreeing the derogations requires legislation.
I certainly endorse Dave Watson’s comments. In the past, trade unions have often been lone voices in making the positive case for regulation, which I do not think we hear often enough, but we have always acknowledged that to keep pace with a dynamic economy, regulation has to be proportionate and dynamic, and it has to be applied flexibly. I do not believe that the provisions in the bill are in keeping with that approach to better regulation.
I echo Stephen Boyd’s comments. Our members’ view is that it is probably ill considered to leap to legislate further before the existing legislative and regulatory framework is reviewed. As David Watson said, the argument is around whether individual communities and structures are involved in the design stages, the review stages or in trying to achieve simplification, clarity and flexibility around existing regulation. Rather than leap to legislate, we have a desire to review what we have already.
Thank you. I think that you have all set out your position quite clearly. I will ask members to tease out certain areas. We will start with Rhoda Grant.
The argument about the difference between better regulation and less regulation comes across in some of the submissions. There seems to be a concern that the bill will lead to less regulation, which might impact on people carrying out those duties but might also impact on the public. I suppose that the Government would argue that the bill is about better regulation, not less regulation. Are there things in the bill that lead you to be concerned that it will lead to less regulation?
It is important to make the case for proper regulation. We should remember that the purpose of regulation is to protect the public and legitimate businesses. Good businesses have nothing to fear from regulation. In fact, they suffer from the cowboys. In our submission, we use the example of fly tipping, which does not help legitimate businesses. Regulation is valuable for business, and it is certainly valuable for the rest of us.
We welcome the Scottish Government’s overall approach to regulation. It is trying to achieve better regulation. It gets it that regulation is a means to an end and not an end in itself, and it has a clear policy objective and a vision of what it is trying to achieve. However, we are disappointed by the limitation of its vision of regulation as a means of supporting business and economic growth. The suggestion that the objective of better regulation is only to deliver that and to provide a favourable business environment in which companies can grow and flourish, which is clear in the policy memorandum, ignores the fact that better regulation is as much about consumers as it is about businesses, and that it benefits both.
To add to what Dave Watson said, I think that it is important to draw a distinction between what the UK Government is doing—it is pursuing a nakedly deregulatory process through its risible red tape challenge and associated activities—and the Scottish Government’s agenda, which I am certainly not trying to suggest is about anything other than better regulation. The problem is that, as well as the economic duty, the bill covers issues around primary authorities and transferable certificates, and it opens up opportunities for regulatory arbitrage between different parts of Scotland. I do not believe that that is the intention, but when we look at regulation we always have to be careful about unintended consequences, as we have seen from numerous examples over the years. Those aspects of the bill certainly open up opportunities for that even if it is not the stated intention—and I do not believe that it is.
I do not think that there is an argument that people are championing less regulation; it is about better regulation and the issues that I mentioned earlier—consistency of approach, simplification and clarity. An organisation that operates in the housing sector will be regulated by the housing regulator, and if it establishes economic activity through a subsidiary that operates in social care, it will have regulatory requirements in relation to social care as well. If it is established as a charitable organisation, it will also have to operate within the Office of the Scottish Charity Regulator guidelines. It is the merging of those requirements and the need for a consistent approach among each of those regulatory frameworks that are vexing our members.
Are there things that can be done through the memorandum of understanding between the Government and COSLA? Indeed, certain regulation opt-outs will be available. Would that alleviate fears, or do we need to go further to make the bill work?
Working with COSLA to bring national standards together is the way ahead. I would distinguish that from the bill, which seeks to give ministers the power to direct from Edinburgh—that is the difference. There is a clear approach. We have a regulatory reform group, on-going work with COSLA, guidance that has been issued and all the professional bodies that have been set up in the different areas. All of that can be pulled together with best practice and so on. That is the way to drive improvement; it is not for a minister in Edinburgh to sit there and say, “You will do X and Y.” The consequences of that would be as I described before.
The economic duty was mentioned in some of the opening remarks. Alison Johnstone will ask about that.
We have heard evidence about the economic duty from previous witnesses. Scottish Natural Heritage felt that the promotion of an economic duty would have no impact at all on what it is already doing. There is a feeling among many that non-legislative approaches are working and that legislation simply is not necessary. However, concern has also been expressed that there is a conflict between the economic duty and other duties that regulators have.
Let us be clear. Most regulators take economic factors into account. Sadly, as a result of the cuts in staffing, they are increasingly having to act in a policing role rather than in their main role of educating and supporting. That has come out clearly in recent surveys. Our members would prefer to spend time with businesses and others, helping them through regulation rather than policing them. However, that is largely where we are, as we have shown with environmental health and planning in particular.
I support what Dave Watson has just said. We think that there is a lack of clarity about how the duty might work, and we are concerned that introducing the new statutory duty might override regulators’ core functions. It is not well defined.
I tend to agree with the view that was espoused by the SNH representative to whom the committee spoke recently. As we say in our written submission, there is no evidence that Scotland’s regulators are acting in a way that is preventing sustainable economic growth. No one has provided evidence in that regard. Our concern is that the introduction of the duty tips the balance further the other way. We need to learn the lessons of recent economic history of one regulatory failure after another. In our written submission, we talk about what happened when the Financial Services Authority, at a UK level, was given a specific duty almost to promote the financial services sector. That made it difficult for it to discharge its core remit, as there was a fundamental conflict between promoting the sector and regulating it.
The initial proposal that was consulted on was changed to make the duty for sustainable economic growth apply only to the extent that it is compatible with the exercise of a body’s functions. Do you think that that represents a material change in how the duty will impact on regulators?
In fairness, I think that we would all agree that the present wording is better. The responses to the original consultation were very strong on that point. However, the new wording still has the risks that I have indicated. The issue is not so much that there will be legal challenges; it is that there might be, and that will have an impact on regulators. Although the wording is a bit softer and gives regulators a little less concern in those areas, the unintended consequence will still be that regulators will be concerned about how companies—particularly big companies with deep legal pockets—will make use of this provision to the detriment of the public.
Is it clear to the panel that there is an agreed definition of sustainable economic growth? Does it mean the same to everyone? Would it make sense to have clarity on that term and ensure that it is fully understood before we impose a duty on regulators to promote it?
I saw that there were some questions about definitions of sustainable economic growth, so I dug one out, which I will read to you:
Where did that definition come from, Mr Boyd?
Wikipedia, I am afraid. [Laughter.]
Did you write it?
I just thought that we should be clear where the definition came from.
From memory, I think that it is very close to the definition that has been in various Scottish Government documents.
I think so, too.
The definition that Mr Boyd gave appeared to be a definition of sustainable economic development. It might be that “sustainable economic growth” should be replaced by “sustainable economic development”. I am sure that the committee will explore the issue at some length.
You have made a valuable point. Trisha McAuley commented on the issue, too. It is about who understands the phrase. What do the people who use services—our customers—understand by “sustainable economic growth”? When we design the delivery of services within a regulatory framework, it is important that people can understand why services are designed and delivered in the way that they are.
For clarity, does “sustainable economic growth” need to be defined in statute for the approach to work?
The difficulty with that is that if we are struggling—even with the benefit of Wikipedia—we should put ourselves in the shoes of an environmental health officer, a planner or a Scottish Environment Protection Agency inspector on the ground. How will a new professional in such an area make such judgments on the ground? It is difficult.
That is slightly aside from my point, which I suppose is about whether the power, if it is introduced, needs to carry a definition with it. Is that immaterial, because the legal challenges will happen anyway?
I think that they will happen anyway. If you put a phrase in legislation, it is helpful to include a definition, because legislation has its own lexicon in the laws of statutory interpretation. However, the difficulty is that any definition that you come up with will be very general and fairly woolly and will be open to challenges as to, first, what it means, and, secondly, how it is applied in particular circumstances. Those are the two legal challenges on something as nebulous as sustainable economic growth.
Did Trisha McAuley want to come in?
Yes, but the conversation has moved on, so I will just say that I support what Dave Watson just said. Any definition that would clarify things would help, but we question whether the duty is required at all. That is our key point. If the duty remains in the bill, it should be better defined than it is at present.
Mr Watson, why do trade unions have rule books?
We have rule books because they regulate the rights and responsibilities of members, as does regulation in other areas that our members regulate.
You agree that there is a need for regulation.
Absolutely. We make the case for regulation.
To promote the union and ensure that it works effectively.
No, no. The rule book is there to regulate the rights and responsibilities of members and the organisation. It regulates behaviour, as it were, on that basis, as does regulation in the community.
I have difficulty with where you are coming from. You have talked about policing as opposed to regulation. Your submission talks about deregulation favouring cowboys. We sit here six years after a debacle in the banking industry because of light-touch regulation and deregulation. What is your position? Are you in favour of regulatory reform or not?
We are in favour of good regulation. That is pretty clear in our submission. The banking industry is a good example of the risks of light-touch regulation. Good regulation is to the benefit of good businesses and the community. That is what we say in our submission, so we are all in favour of regulation. We are not in favour of oppressive or unnecessary regulation. Scotland has a lightly regulated economy, as Stephen Boyd rightly pointed out, but the regulation that we have exists for a good reason. Our members who administer it understand that and that they are there to do that on behalf of the wider community.
Are things working well? Why do you think that the proposed regulatory reform undermines local democracy?
It undermines local democracy because ministers in Edinburgh would set out their version of national standards, not the local authority that is elected to do that in its communities. Secondly, particularly under the planning proposals, ministers will set out their view of performance in each and every local authority. Again, that is the role of the democratically elected local councillors.
I do not wish to draw any parallels with how London operates. I am confident that we could do a lot better.
Mr Watson, I am not sure whether you are absolutely up to speed with the planning regime. Are you aware of the Heads of Planning Scotland planning performance framework?
Yes, and it is a good example of getting together best-practice standards from people who deliver the service at the sharp end. That is not the same as a minister and senior civil servants in Edinburgh setting the standards. There is nothing wrong with having national guidance and practice or with people getting together and working out the best way of dealing with things. There are structures and frameworks to do that. However, that is not the same as top-down performance targets that are decided by a minister and civil servants in Edinburgh. They are two different things. The HOPS approach is the right one; the top-down one is the wrong approach.
You must, then, be unaware that the HOPS approach is very much the one that the Government is encouraging.
I am sorry, but that is not the approach that is in the bill. I agree that, to date, that is exactly what Governments of all colours have done since 1999—they have worked to improve performance—but the bill has a specific proposal in it, and people right across the board, including planners, have pointed out the consequences of taking that top-down approach, which is set in the centre.
What, then, do you think of the first annual planning performance report? I urge you to consider the fact that it is the first one, so it has been encouraged by the current Government, not by all Governments since 1999.
I have no problems with that report. The general approach of improving standards, improving delivery and co-ordinating is fine, but that is not what is in the bill. I do not know whether it was intended to be in the bill, which gives ministers clear powers to set their own performance framework from Edinburgh. That is not the same as the approach that has been taken to date, which has been to improve performance across the board.
In talking about a particular issue, your submission states:
When we say that the bill is chasing the wrong target, we mean that the surveys that we have done, particularly in the past couple of months—on environmental health and on planning—demonstrate significant cuts in staff. Both the numbers and types of inspections have had to be cut and we have seen consequences of that in environmental health and in food inspection, with E coli and legionnaire’s disease, for example. We are also seeing a big cut in the education and support role that regulators have in relation to businesses and the community. That is the target that we think should be chased; it is about that sort of service. We do not believe that the way ahead lies with ministers deciding the performance of each and every local authority in Scotland.
The bill does not say that.
I am sorry, but the bill does say that; that is exactly the power that it gives to ministers. In our view, that performance approach from the centre is wrong. We can see from guidance on approaches and best practice that we can develop a narrative around economic growth and how regulation fits into that. I have no problem with the broad Scottish Government strategy on that basis. The problem is that if we put that in a piece of legislation that can be legally challenged—in fact, every single regulatory decision could be legally challenged on that basis—that is an entirely different ball game from the sort of approach that has been supported by the Scottish Government to date.
I will go back to performance, if I may.
It is difficult for me to answer that question at the moment, because we no longer work in that area and I have no remit. Therefore I have not looked at the bill with that in mind, nor made any preparation to talk on that subject. I can certainly go back to it.
The STUC, too, commented about the constraints on planning departments. Stephen Boyd, do you have any comments on performance and how we monitor that?
I have very little to add to what Dave Watson has said, apart from saying that, as I go about my business, speak to developers and observe long-established businesses around the country, I see that the planning issues that constrain development concern skills, resources and the capacity of planning departments, as Dave Watson has said.
I am not sure where that places planners. On your example of the coal mine, the current situation is that we have a problem with the restoration of redundant open cast coal sites.
Absolutely.
If there were better and clearer regulation, we would not be in the position that we are in now.
I am not entirely sure that that was a regulatory issue. The regulation was in place, and both local authorities and developers knew what they should have been doing, but they chose not to do it. They chose not to keep the bonds as resourced as they should, and that has come back to bite them. Could tighter regulation have ensured that the bond was kept up to date? Perhaps, but it would not surprise me to learn that they would have found a way around that as they have done in the past.
So the regulation was ignored in that case.
I am not entirely sure. The regulation was in place, but both partners in the process chose not to keep the bond up to date. I am not that up to date with the detail of the case. Could the regulatory system have been changed in such as way as to make sure that the bond retained its full value? If so, that should have happened, and this is another example of slack regulation that blights our economy and communities.
It blights our growth.
It does blight our growth, and that point is often overlooked. We tend to assume that less regulation means more sustainable economic growth but, sadly, it does not.
On that basis, then, better enforced regulation would not have blighted our economic growth.
Absolutely.
Can I have one last question, convener? It is for Fraser Kelly.
Yes.
Good morning, Fraser. Your sector has grown hugely in the past two years. A couple of weeks ago, the committee heard from the representative of OSCR, the charity regulator, who was here explaining its role. When did you last meet him?
Within the past two months.
Do you know how often he or his function engages with your members and new members to help them to understand the regulations surrounding charity operations?
Infrequently. The guidance that comes from the charity regulator is sometimes poorly understood by social enterprises.
No no. We can agree to disagree about whether social enterprise is a sector, but the important thing to note is that social enterprises and the third sector are adding value to the economic growth of this nation, and that might increase. You are saying that there are difficulties because the “regulator”—I put that in inverted commas—is meeting you infrequently and not giving enough guidance.
I go back to Rhoda Grant’s question about less versus better. For us, the issue is about better legislation and regulation. Those regulatory bodies need to speak to one another more frequently and to speak to the organisations to which they have a responsibility more regularly. Everyone has rehearsed the issues of time and resources, and every organisation and every person in this room and beyond has those problems. That is why the simplification process and getting better regulation and legislation are far more important than getting less, or indeed more, regulation.
Section 41 deals with planning charges and fees in connection with performance. What are the witnesses’ views on the proposal to link planning charges and fees to performance? How would it affect planning authorities?
I covered that to some extent in an earlier answer. We really do not see how that proposal will help matters. Evidence from a number of organisations has asked how removing cash because of poor performance will improve performance in a particular area. It is important to understand that planning fees are only part of the subject. The role of planners is not simply to respond to developers but to take an interest in the whole community. Sometimes, the actions that are required to get a planning application through require engagement with a wide variety of other agencies, not always the local planning authority that will deal with the application.
Do you acknowledge, however, that there is a need to measure performance?
We can say that it would be a broad gain if applications were dealt with promptly—within six or eight weeks. That is absolutely fine, but if we have strict targets, people game the targets and other services lose out as a consequence. The issue is the framework and how we measure performance. We know from experience that having penalties in the way that is proposed in the bill does not work.
Could I hear from other witnesses on that?
I have nothing to add to what Dave Watson said. I reiterate the point that we know from the experience of the past 15 years that targets change behaviours but do not improve systems. The evidence is unchallengeable.
As I said when Chic Brodie asked a question about that, we have no further remit in that area, so I cannot talk about planning. What we said in our response to the consultation still stands, so the best thing to do is to refer back to that for information.
What alternative changes could be implemented to improve planning performance?
Many of the things that the Scottish Government has done over the past few years to encourage better liaison, more sharing of best practice and peer review, which was suggested in one of the submissions, can all improve practice. However, the biggest requirement is to resource planning departments properly.
Is the decision about how they fund the service not one for local authorities?
I am sure that if a COSLA representative were among the witnesses, they would give you a quick lecture about local authority cuts and the scale of the problem. We might have some sympathy with that view.
Is there an adequate mechanism to allow for engagement with consumers on planning decisions?
I refer back to our consultation response. We said, as Consumer Focus Scotland, that there was not adequate engagement. I cannot expand any further on that.
Should planners and local authorities have the right to appeal ministers’ decisions?
We do not have a policy view on that issue, as we have not considered it.
Does no one else have a view? If not, I thank witnesses for their previous responses.
On a slightly different theme, I am sure that we all support the principle of local democracy and support decisions being taken locally. Can the witnesses help me by providing examples of when a local community has campaigned against national regulations and the local authority has said, “Yes, you have made a very good case. We will exercise our power to vary the way in which the regulations are applied”?
Off the top of my head, I cannot picture a particular example but, when we talk to our planning officers group, the officers talk about how they apply regulation. Not every regulation is black and white, so there is scope for discretion in a number of areas. A planning officer who works in Shetland will understand the local circumstances. They obviously cannot break a particular regulation but, when they have flexibility to meet local circumstances, they will use it. That is what planners do.
I take that answer to mean no, given that you cannot think of any examples. Can any other witnesses think of concrete examples of what I have described?
I am sorry, convener, but I do not think that that is at all pertinent to our discussion. I answered the point in general terms. I am not sure what point Mike MacKenzie is trying to make. The fact that we cannot produce a specific example from a specific local authority is not material. I am sure that every planner in every local authority in Scotland could give you an example—
I would like to thank you and move on to other questions, if you do not mind.
I endorse Mr Watson’s point.
Can you think of a situation in which members of the public might be distressed by being faced with a postcode lottery, because onerous regulations apply in one area but a few miles across the border, as it were, the regulatory regime is different? Would people be distressed or unhappy about that situation?
I can see that people might feel that, but the point is that there are national laws for a lot of these issues, although there might be discretion in areas. The problem with the concept of a postcode lottery, which is used in a number of areas, is that one person’s postcode lottery is another’s local discretion. To be honest, I always cringe when politicians of all colours—it is not just Mike MacKenzie—use the phrase “postcode lottery”, and I have given others a hard time for it as well, for that very reason. I understand the issue about regulation being applied differently but, in the main, most regulation is dealt with locally and people exercise sensible discretion when they can do that under national laws, which are consistent throughout Scotland.
Mike MacKenzie raises an interesting point. Our understanding of the Scottish economy is that the issues that affect communities are broadly similar. They are housing, health, economic sustainability—do people have jobs?—and environmental sustainability. The issues are similar, but communities need different solutions in many cases. The issues in Helmsdale or Elgin are not the same as the issues in Greenock or Port Glasgow.
You will be seeking outcomes with reference to your measurements.
Yes.
Mr Kelly, I thank you for making an important contribution to the debate. In your earlier comments, you seemed to point out that the regulations that impinge on a business or organisation often differ from or contradict each other. Can you or the other panel members think of any examples of that?
Mr Boyd wants to come in first.
I would like to make a general point about complaints. We often hear about inconsistent application of regulation. I have been a member of the RRG and its forebears since the inception in—
Can I stop you? It would be much more helpful if, rather than making the point that you were going to make, you answered the question that I asked. That is usually how this operates.
You are making points of an extremely general nature, so I am responding in kind. I think that it would be polite, having invited—
I am asking for specific examples that you are aware of.
I am going to come to that.
Mr Watson, given your concerns about planning, I expect that you can give me numerous examples.
If you are looking for examples, we have set them out in our evidence and have provided other information on that basis. I have not come armed with 20 examples in 20 authorities. Our evidence is based on the views of those on the ground who do the work every day—they are not sitting in Edinburgh watching this meeting—and they say that deciding the regulation in Edinburgh then imposing it on everyone in the country is not the right approach. All that they would say is that they seek to apply regulation flexibly to meet local circumstances.
But you cannot give any examples.
I was not in Waterwatch.
I am sorry—I must have misunderstood.
I am happy to answer your question, though.
In general terms—I think that Mr Watson has touched on this—do you think that big business and big organisations have been tying regulators in legal knots and that, as a result, regulations have disproportionately affected small businesses and small organisations, which do not have the legal resources to fight them? Does the bill’s thrust give the regulators more teeth to deal with bigger businesses and organisations and, if so, is that a worthwhile direction of travel?
I am not sure that the bill gives regulators more teeth, but I am certainly concerned that the overriding duty—if it is overriding—would make regulators focus on big business at the expense not so much of regulating small businesses as of going out to help them. The committee will need to speak to the small business sector, but we represent such businesses in the regulated markets that we work in and we know that they are under severe pressure.
I will comment on the important point that Trisha McAuley made about the patchwork consequence of some developments and on Stephen Boyd’s point about interpretation. Mike MacKenzie asked for an example, so I will give one, which concerns a potential wind farm development in South Ayrshire. A community there interpreted what one regulation, PAN 47, said about the role that it could play before the application, but the local authority took a different view. Another planning regulation, PAN 3/2010, detailed what could be done post-application. The community council took one view; the local authority took another. There is a lack of clarity in the documents; that has taken up loads of planners’ time, has created angst in the community, and it certainly has not been productive. The consequence might well be that that does not add value to economic growth.
I am not sure what the question is—
It was not a question; it was a statement.
My point is that, yes, regulation will always be applied differently. There are mechanisms and frameworks and there are various ways of addressing different interpretations of arrangements. The conflict involves the development of national standards and the minister sitting in Edinburgh deciding what he or she thinks should be the approach on that basis. We need local authorities and others to work and engage with the communities that are affected in order to reach understandings on common practice, rather than the top-down approach that is promoted in the bill.
I think that Dave Watson needs to look at sections 43 to 45, which relate to the minister’s role in developing a code of practice when changes apply.
I welcome the convener, Murdo Fraser, who will take over the chair.
My apologies for not being here earlier; I am grateful to Dennis Robertson for stalwartly holding the fort in my absence.
We are still discussing the key tension involving local democracy and community capacity. That is critical, but there is inconsistency. I will not rehearse some of that, as it sits in what we mean by sustainable economic growth. If we are looking at putting a duty on regulators, taking the wider view is definitely the way to go.
I agree.
Trisha McAuley mentioned the code of practice, which I do not think has come up before. Does anybody else have concerns about the code of practice, or are the witnesses content that it is provided for in the bill?
We are content that it is provided for in the bill, but ministers are not required to consult bodies that represent end users of the code of practice. Section 1 requires end users and the recipients of regulation, including businesses, to be consulted on regulations, but there is no requirement to consult those people on the code of practice. Such a requirement could be included.
I should probably point out that unions will be involved in the development and implementation of the code of practice; there have been discussions to that effect.
Should the memorandum of understanding be underpinned by legislation? Should it be in the bill?
I do not have a view on that, to be perfectly frank.
Does anybody else want to comment? The witnesses are all shaking their heads, Dennis.
That is fine. We will just take it that that could be the case.
The STUC’s submission states:
It is absolutely our position. I stress again that we have had extensive discussions with ministers, Russel Griggs as chair of the RRG and senior officials over a considerable time and we have never heard a rationale for the bill that is remotely compelling and would force us to change our mind in any way whatsoever. I stress that strongly.
Our position is the same. The bill has been used to tidy other bits and pieces, which is fair enough. Such a bill is an opportunity to tidy other things that were waiting for a suitable opportunity to come along. However, we see no need for the main thrust of the bill on national standards, the direction power, planning fees and so on.
I should have said that our concern is not only because we cannot see a rationale for the bill but because, in Scotland, we have pursued a distinct approach to better regulation for a number of years that has considerable buy-in from a range of stakeholders who have put a lot of time and effort into developing our different approach. Our concern is that the bill might drive a coach and horses through that. The consensus has been difficult to establish and maintain—it has required a lot of sensitive discussions across a range of areas—and the bill, particularly the economic duty, could upset that, which would be a real shame.
For the reasons that I outlined about protecting vital services, I support what Stephen Boyd said, with the exception of the section on national standards. I support what he said in that the key thrust of section 1 and the bill’s general principles being concerned with the economic duty skews regulation towards one aspect of the work of regulators, possibly at the expense of protecting some of their core functions.
I come back to my original comments. The issue is the balance between an enforcement bill and an enabling bill.
I will take the witnesses back to planning. We have heard a lot about how underresourced planning departments are and about their capacity. Setting aside the underfunding of local authorities, should the fees for planning applications for wind farms, for example, be increased?
I would not want to state a particular level. It is argued that planning fees seem to be in excess of the cost of administering a particular aspect of an application. However, those who pay planning fees need to recognise that the fees are not just for the administration of their planning applications. The planners’ role is to take account of the wider community’s interests. Therefore, planning fees are an important source of income to fund planning departments to have the necessary range of skills.
Fergus Ewing has indicated to us that the Scottish Government is minded to lodge a stage 2 amendment to adopt primary authority partnerships, which are a concept that exists in England and Wales. Does anybody have a view on whether that measure should be in the bill or have concerns about it?
I said at the start that my concern is that the proposal opens up another opportunity for regulatory arbitrage. Over time, companies might gravitate towards local authority areas where regulation is regarded as being less stringent. I am not saying that that is the bill’s intention, but we have learned from regulation over the past couple of decades that there are often unintended consequences of such proposals, so I would be very concerned.
We were told about the proposal a couple of days ago, so we have been able only to discuss with colleagues down south their response to primary authority partnerships. The general view is that nobody has seen any great benefit from the system.
If nobody wants to add anything, we will call a halt. I thank the witnesses very much for coming and giving their evidence, which was helpful to the committee.
I welcome our second panel of witnesses on the Regulatory Reform (Scotland) Bill.
My question is for Nancy Jamieson. Should fees be ring fenced to planning departments so that any fees that are charged go straight into resourcing that service?
That is a point of view. The Audit Commission’s report in 2010 said that it was very keen that the planning service be fully funded by planning fees. The planning service has different aspects: there is development management, which deals with planning applications, and development planning, which deals with development plans, and there is no fee income from the latter. To make the whole service self-sustaining, which is what the Audit Commission says we should be working towards, we would need some sort of ring fencing. Whether that would be acceptable in the real world, where councils’ budgets are diminishing, is another matter. Chief executives would have to take a view on that.
What proportion of the cost of planning departments is currently paid for by fees? Where does the balance lie?
I am acting development management manager in the City of Edinburgh Council. We have an overall budget of about £7 million; about £4 million of that comes from planning fees, so the council has to make up the remainder. Some smaller councils perhaps are able to make up 100 per cent; that might just be the development management side. In Edinburgh, however, just over half the budget is provided by planning fees.
If that is the case, would the solution to the problem be to have the cost of the fee reflected in the cost of processing the applications, or to have either a general increase in fees or a level which you then top up, depending on the cost of the application?
The HOPS view is that the fees system in Scotland needs to be restructured. We had a 20 per cent increase in fees in April, which helped; but it does not get over the problem that we have, in that the maximum fee is about £19,000 for any application, unless it is for a mixed development. In England the fee can progress up to £250,000, as a maximum.
Mike MacKenzie is muttering.
Thank you. I mutter a lot, as you may have noticed. However, I am happy to ask some questions. I recently read the first annual planning performance report, which makes pretty grim reading as it shows that significant numbers of applications were still in the system after 99 weeks and that less than a third of planning authorities used the planning system to negotiate better design standards. How can we improve planning in Scotland?
Who is that question for?
It is for anybody—it is for all the panel. It is a pretty open question.
Right. If it is going to the whole panel, can we please have fairly short answers? Who would like to start?
Mr MacKenzie has asked a very big question. I suggest that the answer is not to try to force the issue and tell planning authorities how to do planning. I think that bureaucracy reacts poorly to that and, even, to the carrot-and-stick approach. I should say that I am very pleased to have been asked here to represent the applicant at the coalface, so to speak. Those of us at the coalface applaud the intentions of the carrot-and-stick approach, but bureaucracy finds its own way and there are all sorts of ways around that. We have a situation in which there are fewer planning applications and in which planners are even worried about their jobs. Applications have a tendency to take longer, just to ensure that planning is seen as important. I am not being particularly online with my colleagues’ message here, but that is the way of the world and it is how things happen.
Does Nancy Jamieson want to defend the planners?
I definitely do. One of the problems that we have just now is that the current system of performance recording is very crude. Basically, we have to give Victoria Quay all our figures. We have this rather odd instruction that if we think that the applicant has been sitting on the application and not doing anything, we have to tell the people in Victoria Quay how many weeks we think should be excluded from the performance time.
On that point, do you think that too much use is made of section 75 agreements? We have certainly taken evidence from witnesses to that effect.
In Edinburgh, we have an economic resilience plan so that, if there is a proposed section 75 agreement and the developer feels that it would make their development unviable, we discuss that with them, and we ask for the development viability appraisal. There have been a number of cases recently when we have taken applications back to committee and said, “No, you don’t have to pay the contribution.” There is a very detailed circular on planning obligations and the specific circumstances in which a planning obligation—that is the correct term for a legal agreement—can be asked for. It must be related to a development and must be necessary for that development. Planning authorities in general must scrutinise that circular and ensure that they are requiring developer contributions in accordance with that circular. We must be clear about that.
I am conscious of the fact that, as I understand it, the planning performance report was based on the planning performance framework that was drawn up by Heads of Planning. Despite the fact that it looks at quite a broad range of things other than efficiency and speed of determination, some of the results are very bad.
The planning performance framework was a joint framework between Heads of Planning Scotland and the Scottish Government. In 2012, for the first time, all the planning authorities submitted their planning performance frameworks. Just last week, we got a review of ours from the Scottish Government. We had not previously had any feedback on it. The picture that was given was that performance is about not just speed but a range of things that a planning authority must deliver. Is it open for business? How is it delivering sustainable economic growth? What initiatives does it have in place? I have not read all the other planning authorities’ planning performance frameworks. The City of Edinburgh Council got a very good rating, but we need to work to improve.
Surely local planning authorities would not massage statistics in the way that you suggest.
That would not be massaging the statistics; because we have to deal with an application within two months, it would be meeting the performance target that was set by the Scottish Government.
I am led to believe, however, that despite that statutory obligation to determine within two months, well over 50 per cent of applications are not determined within two months. That is not a new thing. There seems to have been a two-month determination period since I was a wee boy, yet we achieve less than 50 per cent of that. How do we improve it?
Where does that statistic come from?
It came from the first annual performance report, based on the HOPS planning performance framework.
The HOPS planning performance framework is a framework for every planning authority. Each planning authority has its own planning performance framework.
Yes, but you will be aware that the first national planning performance report has been published, and the statistic came from that.
What development type is the 50 per cent? I do not recognise the figure.
It is actually a 5 per cent increase on what it was. Just over 50 per cent of all applications are now determined within the statutory two-month period. There has been a 5 per cent increase, so there is a bit of a pat on the back there, but it is still only 50 per cent.
Perhaps I can hand over to Alistair MacDonald to say something.
I was chair of Heads of Planning Scotland in 2011-12, so the first planning performance framework came through when I was chair. I was also head of planning for Glasgow City Council and I retired earlier this year.
Is it not the case, though, that a lot of planning authorities are still kind of in denial about the credit crunch and the different economic circumstances that we are now in? They are imposing section 75 agreements that may have been appropriate prior to the credit crunch but which are, post-credit crunch, not workable.
Again, I have to disagree with you. In 2008—
I am only asking the question.
In 2008, in Glasgow, we put reports up to committee to change how we deal with financial contributions. That happened throughout the country. We would not expect payment up front, because no profit had been made, so we would stagger payment, perhaps even right to the end of the project, before it came back into, say, community benefits. That was how we tried to assist developers. Like Nancy Jamieson, we queried whether we needed to go down the road of section 75 agreements. Is there another way that would lessen bureaucracy? We knew that the industry was going through a very hard time. My experience with Heads of Planning Scotland was that throughout the country we were looking at how we could assist people, particularly house builders, to get through the very difficult situation in which they found themselves.
Let me make two points. The issue that Alistair MacDonald and Nancy Jamieson brought up is a real one. It would be good if the committee challenged HOPS or Scottish Government planners to find a way of removing from the statistics applications in which the applicant is holding things up.
My question was really about how we can improve the planning system. It is obvious from the planning performance annual report that some planning authorities are pretty good and others are not as good. I have heard all kinds of reasons why the system is not as good as we want it to be. How can we improve it?
I appreciate that that is your main question, but I want to make my second point, because section 75 agreements have been floating about in the discussion.
Planning Aid’s view is that improvement happens in the system when people understand how it works. To some extent, to talk about how the figures appear to show that decisions take much longer when a section 75 agreement is involved is to misunderstand how the system works to deliver what everyone wants, at the end of the day.
You have made your point. It is all the developers’ fault.
No, it is not necessarily—
Is that not your point? Are you not saying that developers are exploiting that?
It is about understanding the system. Everyone is getting something out of the so-called delay, because it suits them.
I am a wee bit disappointed because I am not hearing much about how we can make improvements. I will rephrase the question and talk about judging the system by its outcomes.
That is a broad question. We are focusing on the provisions of the bill, so I ask the witnesses to try to focus in their responses on the issue in the bill, which is to do with planning fees. This is not a discussion about how to improve the planning system in general, because that is beyond the remit of the bill.
I will try to identify some positive measures for improvement.
Good morning. Malcolm Fraser’s initial comment was like a breath of fresh air. We were told earlier that planning authorities were constrained, and he said that some planners are worried about their jobs. The disconnect in the information that we are getting confirms that we need some sort of disciplined regulation in the system.
On wind farms, it is certainly a no-brainer. The Government should set a context and not allow applications to be argued through the planning system, in which lawyers and everyone else go through enormous hoops only for different and bizarre decisions to be made. The context should be set nationally.
I would not disagree with Malcolm Fraser’s last point. Unfortunately, not all the plans that come across the table from applicants are as good as Malcolm’s architecture, so they need to be worked on.
Can I stop you? Do we have too many local authorities?
That is a little bit wide of the mark.
No, it is not.
It is wide of the mark for the bill. By all means answer the question, Mr MacDonald, but it is not relevant to the bill.
I am sorry but, in my position at the moment, I am reluctant to answer that question.
That is fine.
There is then a democratic process with local consultation and the planning committee approves the local plan. A different emphasis in how a rural authority, an urban authority or a mid-range authority approaches a particular type of application might account for some of the apparent disparity that you have experienced in the south of the country. I cannot say that for sure, but I hope that all planning authorities aim to have up-to-date development plans. That is important, as it guides development and it guides people such as Malcolm Fraser and RICS members when they invest in an area.
It is difficult to provide a picture of what it is like to work in a planning service that delivers development. For example, for the Craighouse development that has been in the news recently, we spent a year giving pre-application advice, but the application that was submitted just was not acceptable. I hear what Malcolm Fraser says—I have worked with him on many schemes in Edinburgh, and he is great to work with—but there are an awful lot of architects out there who are difficult to deal with because their clients want a level of development on the site that is not acceptable.
I agree that there is a broader resourcing issue. As Nancy Jamieson said, planners must not only co-operate with the developers on the ground but take on board the community’s interest in the application. Planning reform was predicated on that—there is no third-party right of appeal—so we need to take the community with us. Both the developer and the planning authority need to explain what their roles are and what is happening. That takes investment, as it involves an additional burden on the decision maker and on the applicant. If we get that wrong, that will make the application process last longer because people will always look for what challenges they can bring. The game plan is to make the process as open as possible and allow people to have their say at the start, so that the application can be refined at that point, rather than people discovering only halfway through and then lobbing in any challenge that they can to hold up the application.
I will come back to the issue of investment versus efficiency in a minute.
Having made my pawky comments, let me now make some positive ones. My wife has an architectural practice, too, and she does a lot of work in Scotland and some work in England. I work with large developers that are based in England but work in both England and Scotland.
I agree with Alison Polson that there is a resourcing issue. If we are to have a system that focuses resources on major applications, which of course have the biggest economic, social and design impact, I think that there is a reasonable case for having differential fees to reflect the resources that planning authorities require to put into that work.
I hear what you have all said about resourcing, but I robustly question the efficiencies that can be made in that respect. I do not want to discuss the number of single turbines in the south of Scotland and how much time they have taken up vis-à-vis what we should have been doing, but I note that in its submission the RTPI calls itself
I am not sure that planning education is terribly relevant to the bill, even though it is mentioned in the RTPI’s submission, so I ask Mr MacDonald to address the issue quickly.
We accredit the courses across the UK that provide training for planners, whether at postgraduate or undergraduate level. In my experience, the young planners who are coming through—as RTPI Scotland, we work with an association of young planners—are impressive: they are highly enthusiastic and highly skilled. I have strong hopes that the graduates and the young planners who are coming through at the moment will serve the country well.
When the bill is implemented, I presume that it will be part of the formal education process.
It will be part and parcel of their education in planning and other Government matters.
You have hit on the question that I was going to ask about penalising underperforming authorities. Do the other members of the panel agree with Mr MacDonald that it would be wrong to penalise authorities that underperform? How do you think that underperforming authorities should be dealt with? What would be best practice when it comes to encouraging them to perform better? In addition, how should performance be measured?
The planning performance framework that was brought out last year represented a first step in the process of establishing a broad range of qualities for planning authorities to be measured against. I think that that is the test bed that we need to start working from. Although problems will be thrown up with the stats, that will gradually work its way through the system. Heads of Planning has responsibility for the framework, as it brought it forward; Nancy Jamieson can speak about that. I think that Heads of Planning can act as a mentor and assist by passing on good practice by the exemplar authorities to smaller authorities, which will benefit from that experience.
Does anyone else want to comment on the reduction in fees?
The reduction in fees would have a major impact on some authorities. Planning is not all about electronic working—you cannot get round the need to have people on the ground to assess the application. The case officer must visit the site, look at all the policies and make an assessment. A machine cannot do that.
Planning Aid is concerned about those very things, particularly if they squeeze community engagement right from the start. It is vital that the community is involved and gets a chance in the pre-app stage to understand what the applications are about. If people do not get that chance, the risk is that there will be more challenges that have to go through the system.
We will come back to you if you remember.
The RICS supports the connection between planning fees and performance. It is far better to reward good performance, best practice and delivery, and there are a lot of good examples of that in our experience and from elsewhere.
The question is of incentivisation and clarity of statistics. It would be positive if councils were allowed not to record applications that applicants are sitting on.
Would it not be better to have a consistent approach across all the planning authorities? That would aid the measurement of performance. If there was a consistent approach to planning, the measurement would give the like for like. At the moment, the situation is a mess.
That is because each planning authority has its own development plan. That is what planning reform is about: local decision making. That is why there is a local review body. It is not pan-Scotland.
In a sense, with the bill we are looking for consistency of approach.
Planning Aid would like consistency, but the system is set up as it is.
We do have consistency: how we deal with planning applications is set out in regulations, which say what a valid application is, how long there is to deal with it and what form the decision letter should take. It is the assessment of the application that will be different in each planning authority, because as Alison Polson says—
Is it that the application is not happening consistently?
Do you mean processing of applications?
Yes.
It is pretty straightforward, really. Once we receive the application, we make sure that it is a valid application. One of our big problems is that about 30 per cent of applications are not valid when they are submitted to the planning authority—we then have to chase up all the things that are needed to make it a valid application. After that, we assign the application to a case officer, and we have to do neighbour notification and arrange advertising. The case officer visits the site and we have to look at and deal with all the representations that come in. The application has to be assessed against the development plan.
Do you think that monitoring and scrutinising performance should be the role of local authorities and councillors, or should it be done by the Scottish Government?
It is probably best if Malcolm Fraser answers that.
It should be done by the Scottish Government. It is interesting to think about what things should be devolved downwards, with more local representation, and what things should be dealt with at a higher level. National indicators and guidance are the sort of things that are best done by central Government, which can spank bottoms and skelp heids when necessary, and perhaps shame organisations in certain situations.
Like most councils, we put our planning performance framework to our planning committee. If our performance was not good, it would have something to say about it. There is scrutiny at council level, and we also have to provide the statistics to the Scottish Government.
There is no doubt that we need national scrutiny of how well legislation is working, as that represents Scotland to the wider world and is important for inward investment.
Okay. We will move on to questions from Alison Johnstone.
It is unclear at the moment whether section 4 of the bill, on the regulator’s duty in respect of sustainable economic growth, will apply to planning authorities. Do panel members have a view on whether the sustainable economic growth duty should apply to planning authorities? If you think that it should, what issues might that raise? I ask Nancy Jamieson to answer first, and then Alistair MacDonald and Colin Smith.
I guess that my answer comes back to what we said earlier, in that planning is regulated by strata of different regulations and acts. The Scottish planning policy—especially the new draft policy that is going through its consultation process just now—is very much focused on sustainable economic growth. That is something that we will have to take on board as we progress. I think that planners often forget about sustainable economic growth when trying to balance all the different policies that they deal with.
I would say that our job is to come forward with sustainable development for the benefit of the country. That cannot be left out of planning: it must be part and parcel of the core response for any planning application. I think that you will see more and more councils looking at a sustainable economic model. They will have to consider that as part of their overall response to a particular application. There are checks and balances in the system, and one will be consideration of sustainable economic growth.
The delivery of sustainable economic growth is critical because Scotland competes with other countries and Edinburgh and Glasgow, for example, compete with Bristol and Manchester. If we do not compete and attract business investment in a sustainable way, it will go elsewhere. There needs to be a real focus on the delivery of sustainable economic growth. In all the regulatory functions—again, there is a link to planning fees—we need to focus on competing in a sustainable way.
Is the panel of the view that the duty should apply to planning authorities?
Yes.
Yes.
We have heard from witnesses previously that the duty may be a lawyers’ charter. I was on the planning committee in Edinburgh and can remember an example of planners recommending refusal for a supermarket development. In that case, the councillors gave it the go ahead and did not heed the planners’ recommendation. If such an application was refused in the future, would the developer be more likely to come back and say that the council had a duty to promote economic growth and that it was clearly not doing it in that case? How do you weigh up other considerations if you have conflicting duties?
One of the complex duties on the planner is to weigh up all the many different aspects, including the possible economic benefits. For instance, for a recent application for a hotel down at Crewe Toll in Edinburgh, concerns were raised about whether the amount of parking on site was sustainable, because it would encourage people to use their cars, and whether there would be issues about air quality.
You gave the example of an out-of-town superstore, which might contend that its application should be granted because it would provide economic development and bring jobs to the area. The downside to such a development might be that those jobs are taken from other businesses, which might then close because of that potentially unsustainable activity. That is part and parcel of looking at the best fit and the best location for such a facility.
If planners already take sustainable economic development into account anyway, is it necessary to legislate for the duty? I would like to understand how the bill will make planning better.
Including the duty in the bill will raise the profile of the issue.
I have a concern that the bill may lead to the economic duty overriding other concerns. Do you share that concern?
I do. The issue comes down to how you define the term “sustainable”, which is often defined in a way that is exactly the opposite of what it means—it is a classic example of a word that has been turned into its doublespeak opposite.
Malcolm Fraser’s point is right. If people want to invest in an area by, for example, opening a new centre that creates 500 jobs, they will look at the quality of life in the area, the transport connections, the provision of housing, the provision of shopping and the local environment. All those things become part of their decision, which is based not just on the sheer economics but on the place where their employees will be well looked after.
Having the duty up front might lead to an improved level of evidence. Rather than promoting developments purely on the basis of the level of investment involved or the fact that they will create X number of jobs, the duty will drive the provision of evidence that shows that a development will provide a net economic impact and not just a headline figure. There will be a better understanding of what the actual economic impact might be.
I have a final question for Nancy Jamieson, who deals with planning on a daily basis. How will the bill make life easier for you?
We already have discussions with our economic development colleagues about how they can assist us in the planning process. If we have a major development, we need to know what its economic impacts are. Perhaps the bill puts that into a more regulatory function and we will be able to incorporate it into the report.
My question follows on from Alison Johnstone’s question about what the sustainable economic growth duty does. It is often analysed in terms of a potential tension with the environment or in terms of the legitimacy of the economic dimension, and that is how you all looked at it. Is there any potential tension between the duty and the preservation of the built environment and heritage? Perhaps Malcolm Fraser would be a good person to answer that.
Yes, there is. You are quite right. There are all sorts of tensions. I continually make the point about VAT. Powers over that are unfortunately not available to us, but at present, if we repair and renew a building, we are charged 20 per cent VAT, but if we knock it down and stick up a new building, even on the green belt, it is 0 per cent. There is a massive economic lever that is used agin repairing and renewing buildings, which is a simple, obvious and not just sustainable but heritage-led approach.
There is a link between economic growth and heritage. One of the principles in the SHEP test for demolition of listed buildings speaks directly about viability. There is a real link there between economic testing and viability testing, so that raises a heritage issue.
I like Malcolm Fraser’s comments about the joyful reuse of listed buildings. The skill of the architect can bring some modernity to an old building such that it can still be recognised but we can play about with it. Buildings do not have to be regarded as sacrosanct. We have lots of building stock in the country that can successfully lend itself to that reuse. I whole-heartedly support Malcolm’s view that we should use our built environment in an inventive and joyful manner.
The bill gives with one hand and it also emphasises the element of balance, which is what planning is about. It states:
I give you the example of a lovely listed façade that remained propped up on a street. Various reports said that it could not be repaired and that, if anyone tried to repair it, it would fall down. There were engineers’ reports that stated that, and a public inquiry was going to be held on it. However, another engineer’s report blew that out of the water and there was no public inquiry. That façade has been retained and now has a completely new building behind it, with shops on the ground floor and flats above. The case gave rise to a whole debate about economic viability, but we were able to prove that things could be done in another way. Land values came into that as well—the owners’ expectation of what the piece of land or building is worth in the marketplace. Sometimes, owners have to reduce their expectation to allow a profit to come out of the end. It can work if you question in the right manner.
The economic viability test—the SHEP test—is deeply problematic because it assumes that we live in the world before 2008. We have a site in Edinburgh that looks like the surface of the moon, which has one listed building sitting on it and nothing else for some distance around it. The developer can say that the site cannot be developed because of the listed building, and the listed building therefore becomes a whipping boy for the way that the market is. An application is submitted to demolish the building and it can be demolished at any minute as a result of that, but that is clearly not its fault. The one piece of heritage—a substantial, strong-walled reusable thing—gets blamed for the market’s problems and gets demolished.
This has been an interesting discussion, although rather discursive and somewhat wide of the mark. Mike MacKenzie has a supplementary question, which I hope is relevant to the Regulatory Reform (Scotland) Bill.
I assure you, convener, that all my questions are relevant.
I also hope that it is very short.
It is relevant to the duty to promote sustainable economic growth that seems to be dominating discussion of the bill. I am glad to hear you say that that duty is not a problem and that you have been doing that for years anyway. I welcome that part of the bill, and I must question whether you have been doing that for years. If that were truly the case, why do we have so many out-of-town supermarkets—more than any other country except, perhaps, the United States? If sustainable—I emphasise that word—economic growth and development is how you have been operating, how do you account for that?
What difference will the bill make by introducing an obligation to promote sustainable economic growth? How does that compare to what has happened in the past? I ask for brief answers, please.
If we could define sustainability in a reasonable, correct way, taking in the greater good for a whole community, the on-costs for a local authority and Government in general and the potential for growth, money and wealth, that would be a positive thing. It would not allow out-of-town supermarkets to be built. At dinner, I sat next to the head planner of Highland Council and asked him why he had stuck an enormous supermarket outside Fort William, which is going to destroy the remaining parts of the town. He said that the planning lawyers had made a very good argument for it. We need planners to have the equipment and the definition of sustainability to kick such arguments into touch.
There is now a stronger recognition by Government, in advice that is given to local authorities, that the sustainable approach is the one that we should be taking. The application for the Braehead shopping centre was called in and refused but went to appeal and was granted by the reporter at the time, despite the fact that various councils in cities and towns were saying that it might have an impact. That application was granted on appeal.
Such a shopping centre would need a retail impact assessment, and I have never seen a developer submit a retail impact assessment that says that the development will impact on a local shopping centre. It is difficult, because the process is based on the evidence that they provide and our being able to say that, yes, the development will impact on the local shopping centre. In Edinburgh, however, the councillors often do not agree with our opinion on such things.
Thank you. Unless there is anything that you desperately want to add, we will call it a day. Thank you for your evidence, which is very helpful to the committee.