Official Report 153KB pdf
Item 3 is the continuation of the inquiry into the Scottish Higher Education Funding Council teaching and research funding. I welcome our panel of witnesses: Brendan Hyland is the former chief executive of Kymata; Professor Steve Beaumont is director of the Institute for System Level Integration at the Alba Centre in Livingston; and Professor Sir David Lane is chief scientific officer of Cyclacel Ltd.
Do you need some background on us?
Yes. Your papers have been circulated to the committee and I have no doubt that members will want to ask many questions on your written evidence, but it would be useful to have a short introduction from each witness.
I am a former head of the department of electronics and electrical engineering at the University of Glasgow. I now run a research and education institute that involves four universities and is part of the Alba Centre, but I have also been involved in the establishment of companies to commercialise university research. I am a member of the board of Electronics Scotland and of the research and enterprise committee of the University of Glasgow.
My background is as an academic scientist. I trained in cancer research and worked in the academic sector until I moved to Dundee in 1990. Since then, I have started to undertake research projects in collaboration with pharmaceutical companies and to consult for biotechnology and venture capital groups.
My perspective is not that of an academic, but of an individual who has been closely involved in the past few years in commercialising technology from the University of Glasgow and the University of Southampton and from some commercial organisations—British Telecom, IBM and Polaroid in the US.
I thank all three witnesses for their written evidence. I shall kick off by pursuing some of the points that you made. There are some threads that run through all three papers. One of those is the view that the existing mechanisms for encouraging research and commercialisation are wholly inadequate for the job. Two of the papers cite the research assessment exercise as it is currently constituted. I know that there is also frustration with some of the SHEFC funding and with Scottish Enterprise technology venture schemes.
The electronics industry—and possibly others—needs an intermediary body between the universities and the industry, to support the technology transfer process from the universities to industry and to help industry to upskill. There has been a great deal of talk about the closure of the Motorola plant in Bathgate and about the industry's need to upskill. We need to consider the mechanisms that will allow us to do that. There is a huge difference between the sort of research that is going on in universities and the sort of research that would really make an impact on industry in Scotland. There are problems relating to funding and access to the right sort of personnel. A different type of body is needed to deal with those.
Are you talking about a US-style electronics research institute?
Yes. There are a number of examples of such a strategy working successfully on the continent and in Canada, to which I alluded in my submission. Coupled with mechanisms for levering in industrial funding and public-sector research funding, that strategy seems to have brought about a dramatic change in the attitude of the academic sector towards commercial or applied research.
I support many of the points that Professor Beaumont has made. The biotech industry is in the process of being created. Its products could be designed and produced here. They might be manufactured in bulk elsewhere, but the real value is created in the generation of products—something that small companies can do.
I agree with the points that have been made. I bring three areas of focus to this. The first is my concern that the metrics that are used to measure academic research are probably fundamentally wrong for our society. What you measure is what you get. We measure the number of papers that people publish so we get lots of papers. I do not believe that the number of papers that is published contributes materially to the value of this society. I would like a significant shift in the focus of RAE funding from pure and basic research to applied research, with a clear definition and—if possible—an imperative that that is a precursor to the commercialisation of the research, whether that occurs in Scotland, the UK or elsewhere. As a rule of thumb, I envisage a 70:30 split: 70 per cent of Government-based funds focusing on applied research and 30 per cent on pure or basic research.
You made points in your paper about the need for greater volume of research and the scale of research in this country. The committee heard evidence from the director of research councils at the Office of Science and Technology a couple of weeks ago, who agreed that the amount of money that we need to put into commercialisation should be multiplied by a factor of 10 or 12. I presume that you are making the same point in your paper.
No, quite the contrary. I have sought to argue that one of SHEFC's objectives appears to have been to increase the sheer volume of research activity, and that such an objective is fundamentally wrong. I would rather see an increase in the quality of research, particularly the sort of research that results in businesses that generate wealth in the local society and thus give something back to taxpayers.
Part of that is to skew the balance more towards applied research.
Absolutely. As for funds that are invested in the commercialisation process, I should point out that my experience has been markedly different and I make no pretence that my experiences of commercialisation are representative of all universities. However, I know of one case in which an inappropriate level of expenditure in the commercialisation process increased the transaction cost, which more or less killed the deal. I am not sure that such an approach adds any material value. I would rather see a model that was more akin to the University of Cambridge's model from many years ago, which was far more laissez-faire and brought people to the table.
Your expansion of the previous point has gone some way towards answering my question. Your paper lays great emphasis on a potential return to taxpayers, which is a concept to which I am not at all hostile. However, surely a balance must be struck to ensure that pure research that might be absolutely essential is not prejudiced. In the early stages, it might be impossible to prove that a pure research project has any commercial outturn in the immediate future. Do you accept that such a balance must be struck?
Yes, but I should perhaps flag up something at this point. I am not sure of the exact numbers, but I think that the UK gross domestic product is about 5 or 6 per cent of global GDP. If we have a proportionate research and development base, that means a base that is 5 or 6 per cent of global research and development. As Scotland probably represents less than 20 per cent of UK GDP, our research base probably represents 1 per cent or less of global R and D. As a result, we should look outside Scotland to find the best pure research and then bring it into the country and apply it. Money is made and society is driven forward by applying, not by creating, research.
How can we break down the peer respectability culture that exists in our higher education institutions—the barometer of which appears to be publications—and make the academic attitude towards research much more attuned to what is needed outside in the enterprise world?
The metrics need to be fundamentally changed. As Miss Goldie rightly pointed out, we currently have a peer review environment. Unlike my colleagues, I have not been exposed at any level of detail to a peer review process. However, my first-cut view of the issue is that the Scottish Government should take a much more dirigiste approach at a Parliament level, through close co-operation with Scottish Enterprise or SHEFC or whatever. It should focus its limited resources on certain key strategic technologies from which society will benefit and use that approach to set many of the metrics for key research areas in the community.
The universities can be encouraged to take a more uniform approach to the way in which they reward and promote academic staff. As I said, I have come across a number of cases in which academics have felt that they are held back in the system as a result of carrying out commercial work and applied research, rather than fundamental research that can be published. I believe that that can be addressed within the existing promotion systems if the universities are encouraged to adopt a uniform approach.
I support that. In principle, the RAE can recognise commercialisation of research. There are aspects of the exercise that are designed specifically to do that. The culture is that the exercise is assessing pure academic output, so people are looking in their submissions for that. They feel that, when the submissions are judged in peer review, they will be peer-reviewed by an academic group that has not received clear guidance about the role and importance of commercialisation.
Can I pursue the issue of the costs of technology transfer? What are the main cost barriers?
In my experience, I have come across two severe barriers, one of which is time. That is an enormous barrier.
Whose time?
I draw attention to the time that it takes the university to reach a decision about the nature of the technology transfer process. I should like the decision to be made within a week. I am not casting aspersions on a particular institution, but it usually takes about a year to make such a decision and an opportunity is lost as a result.
So basically, the universities are being slow and greedy.
Yes.
We heard evidence from a witness from the Royal Society of Edinburgh who wanted the research budgets devolved entirely to the universities so that they can decide what to spend the money on. You are saying that that would be a disaster.
I can talk only from my experience, but the level of funding necessary to commercialise research in the biotechnology industry rises so high so quickly that it is not possible for university funding to reach the important value step. In my game, getting something into a clinical trial is a big value step for the people who might purchase it from my company. That costs about £500,000 per product. If it can be put into a more advanced clinical trial, it might cost £3 million per product. To imagine that universities can advance that technology to that value step is hard. They cannot. It is hard to think why they would choose to invest in that essential development process. If those processes are to be developed, they must engage global capital—venture capital and, ultimately, the stock market. We must consider where the value steps are in the process.
If research budgets are given to the universities, the money will be spread thinly. If you want to use research in a strategic way for the development of industry, there will be a problem. As I said in my submission, although Scotland and SHEFC can invest money largely in infrastructure, when it comes to research the distribution and prioritisation of the money is controlled elsewhere by the research councils and so on.
Are there any specific measures that you recommend SHEFC should take to speed up the decision making of the universities and make them less greedy? The picture that you paint is the other extreme from the University of Cambridge or the United States experience. From what you are saying, the slow decision-making process is a key part of the reason for the failure of commercialisation in this country. How can we encourage the universities to speed up their decision making?
We have to incentivise the process and make it clear what is expected from the universities. If they fail to perform, that should show as another measure of their performance.
We must also consider the reasons why the universities are being greedy. One is because they regard commercialisation of research as a way in which to solve their funding problems. If there were a way of coupling incentives back into the universities for commercialisation, that could help in several ways. It might speed up the process and help the universities to protect themselves against the effects of commercialisation, which, as I mentioned in my paper, can be an attrition of skills. If there are fellowships or other streams of funding that are connected with the commercialisation process, they could be seen as an incentive by the universities to speed up the whole process.
Convener, your last couple of questions covered some of the areas that I wanted to talk about. Professor Lane, I wish to be absolutely clear about what you said about the model for universities taking more of a risk on the return. As for the University of Cambridge model, you asked for flexibility, for a longer payback period and for the university to take that risk. Presumably, that would depend on the type of industry and the financial position of the university. I am sure that you can understand why, when many institutions are cash-strapped, they would be loth to take that jump. I do not understand what you are suggesting in terms of an incentive scheme that would allow the universities to take such a risk.
If a university is dependent on funding from SHEFC, one can imagine a system in which SHEFC rewards those universities that encourage successful businesses. For example, if an academic starts a company, that person's salary is replaced by an academic appointment. That means that the university does not risk losing that position to the commercialisation process.
Would SHEFC take the risk?
We are trying to promote Scotland's economy. After a careful assessment of a business start-up, one can usually see who is likely to be successful and can make a choice. There could be a competition. We could say, "We will replace 50 positions and universities can compete for them."
On the one hand, I completely understand and accept what you say about venture capitalists who perhaps do not have the expertise or knowledge of a particular area. On the other hand, by pushing the risk back up the chain towards SHEFC, you are asking it to take that risk on businesses that may or may not be successful. What is the assumption behind that suggestion other than that it has the expertise to make such a decision? I am not sure that it does.
I am not too clear why SHEFC would be taking a risk. We are suggesting not that it should fund the companies, but that it could couple some of its funding to the process of commercialisation. All it would do is make further investments in the research base, in areas that are commercially active. That can only help to develop further that research base and focus on economic priorities.
I understand that, but the replacement money would be, in a sense, sharing the risk on behalf of SHEFC. It would be making up for the gap that would be created by the institution taking the risk. I am slightly confused why SHEFC would be in a position to back those departments on the basis of an incentive that may or may not be successful.
This particular issue is an acute problem and we must come up with a solution. In their current financial condition, the universities find it hard to reach a solution. If necessary, funds can be redirected rather than new money being provided, but funds must be targeted towards encouraging such a process.
You referred to the differential in staff salaries. What differences were you talking about?
Let us consider starting salaries for academics. For a lecturer with a PhD, the salary is between £18,000 and £19,000. An electronics engineer graduate can earn £25,000 plus. There is a considerable difference in salaries.
There is also the problem of people moving to the United States.
Indeed.
The differential between Scotland and the United States is enormous.
Absolutely.
You suggested supporting a joint academic industry post. Do you consider that that is a realistic measure? Will it make up the huge gap between here and the United States?
Joint appointments can be successful. I have experience of them, partly encouraged through the Alba Centre, which seems to be keeping the former academic involved in the academic institution and enabling research to continue that otherwise would have been completely lost to the university. Such a suggestion is not fanciful.
Thank you for your written and oral evidence. You have put forward some radical ideas and I am sure that we shall seriously consider them.
Mention has been made of universities seeking too high a stake in companies. We experienced quite a different process. I accept that everyone will have a slightly different experience. The universities that we dealt with were not greedy on the equity front. The problems that we faced were due to the transparency of the process that was being followed. I strongly encourage a set of common guidelines to be prepared for universities so that universities can improve the transparency from both the internal academic and commercialisation standpoints.
I strongly endorse that point.
That goes back to my point about needing to engage the universities from top to bottom. The decision chain in universities in not simple. It is not a matter of the university agreeing to commercialised research, but heads of departments, deans, academics and Uncle Tom Cobleigh and all are involved in the decision. If the process can be speeded up by a streamlined arrangement that is fully understood, articulated and communicated throughout the academic sector, that would be a useful development.
That is a useful recommendation. We now move back into private session.
Meeting continued in private until 16:33.
Previous
Subordinate Legislation