Official Report 509KB pdf
Good morning and welcome to the fourth meeting in 2014 of the European and External Relations Committee. I make the usual request that mobile phones be switched off.
I will say a few words on how small states can maximise their influence in the European Union. If we look at the traditional strategies of small states in international affairs, three have been significant. The first is hiding, which basically involves staying out of trouble by staying out of sight, usually through neutrality or non-alignment. Then there is binding, which involves preventing trouble from occurring by creating and strengthening the governance of international affairs through international rules and institutions. International organisations and institutions, including the European Union, are prominent there. The final strategy is to seek shelter and protection against financial turmoil and security threats, for example as part of NATO or the EU.
Thank you, and thank you for your written evidence, which is a helpful reference.
The comments in our written submission are consistent with what Anders Wivel said. Small states do not have the same economic or political weight as large states. When it comes to intergovernmental bargaining, large states have the advantage of economic power and more votes in the Council of Ministers. Small states rarely use the veto or threaten to do so, because there are huge costs in doing that. When it comes to big intergovernmental issues, the big states often sort things out—sometimes outside the formal institutions—and present a fait accompli.
Thank you, and thank you for your written evidence as well.
Yes, of course. Thank you for your welcome, convener and members of the committee. I am pleased to share my views with you today.
Thank you very much for those comprehensive opening statements, which have given us lots of avenues to go down. You all referred to the difference between small and large states and how they are considered to influence the EU. Is the term “small and large states” helpful, because one aspect of the term is based on population but another aspect might be based on economic growth and economic impact?
The term is useful because, if we look at the European Parliament or at how many votes states have in the Council, there are differences between smaller states and larger states. There is no clear-cut definition, and it would not make sense to have one, but we might say that the states that are not able to shake the EU need to act within it in another way than those that are able to shake it. If Britain, France or Germany has a certain agenda, that will have an impact on the whole of Europe.
Professor Keating, on the issue of the influence of small and large states, and with regard to what Anders Wivel has just said, do you think that Scotland’s climate change legislation, its fishing policies, its life sciences centres and its energy policy—particularly its renewable energy policy—will have an impact on whether we are described as a large state or a small state in those contexts?
The terms “large state” and “small state” are imprecise. They are not legal terms; they are just a general way of framing things. In the past, people used to talk about the European Community, as it then was, being based on the agenda of the Franco-German axis. Following that, other people have said that it is a directorate of the big states, with the British joining the French and the Germans, and maybe the Italians and the Spanish. Those are the large states with a large amount of influence that sometimes cut deals with one another. Everybody else, more or less, is a small state, and the recent accessions have brought in more small states. Small states are clearly in the majority—that is the normal thing to be. So the terms are just rough working definitions. What do you do if you are outside that directorate?
Professor Thorhallsson, Iceland is a small state and is not part of Europe, although obviously you hope that it will be. Do you see where small states could make an impact and how that relates to the power of the large states?
Yes. It is very important to distinguish between small and large states in the European Union, because small states need to use different methods in order to have a say in it. First, they must identify their main economic and political interests. It then all comes down to administrative competence and using the special characteristics of small public administrations that I mentioned in my statement, such as flexibility, informality and greater manoeuvrability.
Okay. We will now go to questions from colleagues, who should try to catch my eye if they have questions to ask.
Good morning and welcome to sunny Edinburgh.
A couple of months ago, we were in Sweden, where we started to talk about small states such as Sweden. The people there said, “No, we’re a big state because we’re bigger than Denmark and Norway.” The matter is therefore relative. Perhaps Poland and the Netherlands are big states. There is a continuum, not a clear distinction. We were interested in where Scotland, with 5 million people, would be, and there is no doubt that it would be at the small state end.
So what is the suggestion? Are you saying that, despite the fact that a country may have five MEPs more than another country, they are equal?
I am saying that the German MEPs, who are numerous, do not vote as a bloc, because the social democrats vote one way and the Christian democrats may vote another way. In fact, though, there are not many votes where the parties disagree, and the process works by consensus. It is a complication, though. However, your main point is right, because the big countries have a bigger presence in all the institutions. For example, they have more votes in the Council of Ministers, which can be critical, and they have more MEPs. As we have all said, the starting point is that the big countries have more width, so small states have to act differently. They cannot throw their weight around, because they do not have any to throw around.
Would it be fair to say that smaller states will need to be more co-operative and work in partnership with people rather than try to influence them?
Yes.
Professor Wivel, do you want in on that point?
Yes. I have two brief points on Mr Malik’s important question. To add to what Professor Keating said, there are two additional ways in which members of the European Parliament matter. One is that they provide links back to their national political systems; at least, that is the evidence in a number of small states, including Denmark. There is a kind of information link, in that the MEPs tell the politicians in the national political system what is on the agenda in Brussels, what people are talking about in the hallways and what are the upcoming issues.
Professor Thorhallsson, do you want to contribute?
Yes, thank you. An important point is that small states have less interest in many areas than the large states. That helps enormously when it comes to prioritisation and the focus on certain issues. When speaking about small and large states, we have to move away from their overall influence on the EU structure or framework. For states, but especially small states, it is all about being able to have a say on their key economic issues or interests. If small states can defend their direct economic and political interests, and even become active in those areas, one could say that they are successful within the EU. It is obvious that the larger states create the overall framework of the EU. However, I share the same view as that in studies by most if not all academics, who conclude that the small states are quite efficient in working within the framework that the larger states create.
That is helpful—thank you.
I want to examine some of the statements that have been made about how a small state positions itself within the EU. All the witnesses have talked about positioning, and we have heard the term “honest broker”. Professor Thorhallsson gave a great example of how domestic politics can influence the EU when he mentioned that the current Icelandic Government has suspended Iceland’s EU accession. There is quite a lot of difference between the timing of domestic elections. How much flux is there in the relationship? Is there constant negotiation with small states because domestic politics will all the time be influencing the state, as it is perceived in Europe?
Small states have tended to have the most influence on issues on which there is a wide political consensus in domestic politics, because in that case there are not fluctuations and they can work on an issue continuously. They need to build expertise and networks, so they cannot choose issues where there are a lot of fluctuations. Small states are most successful when there is continuation from Government to Government on an issue and, even though the Government shifts from conservative to labour or whatever, they continue to work on the same policies.
We need to make a distinction between the Nordic countries and the southern and eastern European countries. There is a lot of literature on the Nordic countries, which are seen as being exemplary in many ways, but there are also the eastern European countries. In the Nordic countries, entering the European Union was quite controversial to begin with. There were referendums in which the margin of victory was quite narrow, and Norway and Iceland decided to stay out. However, once countries were in, there was a consensus about how to act in Europe. That is not the case in central and eastern Europe, where there was enormous support for going in but not the same commitment or the same degree of organisation once the countries were in. Domestic politics therefore gets in the way all the time, which is one reason why those countries are less effective in Europe than the Nordic countries are.
It is important to bring in domestic politics. As you know, the small states are not the same. Some are very pro-European but others tend to be quite Eurosceptic. That said, we sometimes overlook the fact that different political parties work across borders. For example, the social democrats work quite closely across borders, and the social democrats in Denmark can be quite influential if they work with all the social democrats across Europe. The conservatives and liberals do the same, so there are many channels through which small states can have a say. It is not only about the state and the bureaucracy; there are other channels, including political parties, business and labour organisations.
Your opening statements implied that small states have less influence. Does that mean that an independent Scotland, if it were a member of the EU, would have less influence than it does now as part of the UK?
That depends on whether an independent Scotland would want to pursue different policies. That is a political question. If Scotland were to perceive that it has different interests, it would clearly be better off on its own. If it were to end up simply going along with the UK, independence would not have made much difference.
Thank you. That brings me to my second question. If Scotland were able to be independent and an independent member of the EU, and to keep the existing opt-outs and the UK currency, would that not lead to her simply being pulled along in the UK direction?
Yes. We make that point in our written submission. If Scotland had the same terms and the same opt-outs as the United Kingdom, and Europe were moving in a different direction, Scotland would be dragged along with the rest of the UK. That is why we want to see what the vision of an independent Scotland in Europe would be and how it might be different from what the UK does at present.
May I keep going, convener?
I think that Professor Thorhallsson would like to answer your first two questions.
As I have already stated, even though small states face structural problems within the EU, it is difficult to speak about states having less or more influence in the Union. Day-to-day decision making for any state is all about having a say in their direct economic interests. For example, in Luxembourg it is all about the financial sector. If Luxembourg is able to shape the EU financial legislation in its favour, that basically is it for Luxembourg. I am not sure that talking about more or less influence or overall influence helps in assessing the role of small states in the EU. We need to pinpoint the state’s main interests.
On small states, Professor Keating’s written submission states that
I would have to search my brain. Although I cannot remember a particular example, that has been demonstrated by statistical analyses. The analysis is statistical and does not tell us why it happens, but it seems to reflect the idea that small states will try to get what they can out of a package with the big states and then go along with that. Whatever their votes are worth, they will accept the majority in exchange for concessions, rather than trying to lead an opposition group and be on the losing side.
Professor Wivel, in your written submission you suggest that small states have a tendency to hide and keep out of trouble. When you made your opening statement, you said that that was a thing of the past. Does that mean that an independent Scotland would have to shy away from taking difficult decisions, out of a sense of not rocking the boat?
In the European Union, the small states that have been most successful in getting influence are those that tapped into the dominant political discourse and worked with the big member states. In that sense, we could say that they have not rocked the boat, or that they rocked only a small part of the boat, in which they have particular interests.
Thank you.
Good morning, gentlemen. I think that it is fair to say, if I summarise the opinions of the three panellists, that you believe that a small state needs to specialise, to build knowledge and leadership in that area, to network and build alliances and to prioritise the issues in which it wants to be involved. That sounds as if it would be quite resource intensive. What resources do some of the smaller states that are successful in working in that way devote to their presence and influence in the EU?
The other side to that is that you would focus on some narrow areas so, although the work is resource intensive, that intensity would not be across a broad spectrum but on selected issues. The issues that you select would be those that you typically have not only an interest but an expertise in. If you do not have that expertise, you will not be able to influence others. In that sense, the resources that are required by most small states are not insurmountable because they pick the issues on which to focus.
I do not have exact numbers, but the permanent representations of small states in Brussels tend to be much smaller than the permanent representations of the large states. I am often amazed by how much the small permanent representations achieve. How do they do that? In the larger public administrations, things tend to be much more formal—all decisions need to be taken in formal meetings. For example, France has a very strict bureaucracy; the same is basically true for the UK. However, when it comes to small states, the administrations must work informally and be flexible—and manoeuvre their officials, as I have mentioned. That is of fundamental importance in order for them to cope with the EU burden.
I understand perfectly the points that are being made. However, if we take Professor Thorhallsson’s example of Luxembourg concentrating on the financial sector and wanting to prioritise the benefit that it gets from any protection or measures that are put in place around that sector, does that imply that small states that have such specific interests must almost forgo having any impact on other areas that are dealt with in the EU?
Small states simply have to decide to set aside a number of issues. Some small states in the EU do not even send officials to some meetings in the Commission. They do not want to admit to that publicly, but the fact is that they simply do not have the manpower. That said, that might not hurt the small states’ interests, because they simply prioritise meetings of importance.
That is true, but it is also important for small countries to have their domestic administration Europeanised, because they cannot afford to have a separate group of people to look after Europe. That might even help them to learn a bit more about Europe. In addition, getting involved in European networks allows countries to learn a lot about policy issues. Because small countries need to do that, they are sometimes very good at it. That is not just because they are small, because some small countries do it badly. However, as well as contributing to Europe, well-organised small countries can use Europe as a policy resource back home.
I have a question on an issue that is related but at a slight tangent. On small states and the allocation of commissioners, I think that I am right in saying that small states and big states all get to have a commissioner. However, given the weight that the larger states have, it seems to me that they might pick the most interesting and important areas to have their commissioners in. Is that right, or does the system not operate like that? I do not know, so I am really interested to know what the story is on that.
If we look at the history of the Commission, we can see that small states have sometimes held some of the most important posts in the Commission. One of the important factors, of course, is how much clout a state has in the European Union, and the big member states have more than the small ones do. In that sense, we can say that a small state is disadvantaged from the start.
I think that that is right. There is an informal rule about balancing big and small states and the big states not taking all the big positions. At the moment, the President of the Commission and the President of the Council are from small states because the big states could not agree that another of them would get the position.
In other words, as with most situations in politics, connections are almost as important as expertise.
If a very small state sends a trusted, knowledgeable expert in the field of interest to Brussels, he or she stands a good chance of getting the post that their Government really wants. For example, when Norway made an accession treaty with the EU, it had been decided that Norway would get the fisheries commission. That was the field that Norway really wanted and it had been promised it.
That is interesting; thank you.
I want to pursue the discussion about the ways in which smaller states seek to gain influence within the European Union. Some time ago, I had the opportunity to ask Ireland’s current Minister of State for European Affairs, Paschal Donohoe, about Ireland’s relationship with the European Union and with the United Kingdom from the historical perspective. His statement to me was that, in his country’s view, Ireland had benefited greatly from its independence as a state. It had enhanced its relationship with the United Kingdom, and its participation as a small state in Europe gave it further advantages because of the necessity of engaging and interacting with other small states within the EU. In your view, is that more prevalent in Europe now because smaller states have to negotiate with one another and make connections? Do they do that much more systematically than the bigger states do?
Ireland does it pretty well. When it went in at the same time as the United Kingdom, it was tied in to British markets in all sorts of ways. Europe allowed Ireland to diversify its export markets. In that sense, membership enhanced Ireland’s independence. It had been formally independent since 1922 but still highly tied to the United Kingdom.
In the day-to-day decision making in the EU, alliance formation is based on economic interests. However, when it comes to treaty negotiations and intergovernmental conferences, in the past few years we have seen a split between the large states on the one hand and the small states on the other. It has been very important for small states to stand together to prevent what I would call attacks from the large states and enhance their status within the Union.
The experience is that coalition building is typically issue specific and based on economic and political interests. For example, Denmark will work with Germany on climate issues, but with Britain on labour market issues, because those are the most natural coalition partners in terms of their political consensus.
Okay. Many comments have been made about numbers being important or not important. It is my understanding that, when Scotland becomes an independent state, the number of our members of the European Parliament will almost double to be on a par, perhaps, with Denmark’s representation.
In the Council of Ministers?
Aye.
An independent Scotland would send a minister to the Council of Ministers, depending on the subject. As I note in my submission, the system of qualified majority voting is being changed: as of November 2014 it will be a qualified majority of countries with a qualifying majority of population; countries will no longer have a fixed number of votes. It remains the case, however, that bigger countries will continue to have more votes because they have bigger populations.
Over recent years, there have been some examples of our interests diverging on fishing, agriculture and the common agricultural policy. It is fair to say that, on those matters, some people in Scotland have the view that our interests were not served well by negotiations that the United Kingdom carried out on our behalf. An independent Scotland would surely have an influence and a voice whereas, previously, we had none.
Indeed. At present, when the Council of Ministers meets as the council of agriculture ministers, a Scottish minister is usually present but as part of a British delegation. After independence, the Scottish minister would represent Scotland and could present a distinctive Scottish case. The outcome would then depend on the balance of forces—the balance of power.
Absolutely. I presume that that is when the relationships that a small member state can develop and build when it is in the country’s interests to do so become very important.
That is what we have all been saying. It depends on the quality of the policy that you produce and whether that policy is not only lobbying for Scotland but offering something to Europe as a whole.
May I please have a view from the other two professors on what strengths Scotland could bring to the European Union as an independent member state?
Obviously, I do not know as much about Scotland as Professor Keating or members of the committee. In general, Scotland has not only expertise, knowledge and resources in state administration and politics, but the resources that the third sector or the private sector is willing to send to Brussels, which should also be considered. It matters that you have interest groups on the ground in Brussels and that they are willing and able to network. That is certainly something to consider as part of the package.
It would depend on who was in power—who governed—in Scotland. If Scotland were an independent state, the Scottish National Party might prioritise very differently from Labour or the Liberals in a coalition in the Scottish Parliament. It would depend on the governing coalition back home—it is important to keep that in mind.
Thank you for that illuminating point of view.
Ireland has been mentioned. We know that Ireland did very well when she joined the EU, albeit that she has suffered rather badly lately. If she was joining the EU today, would she benefit in the same way that she did then, or are the benefits now rather diluted?
In the 1990s, Ireland benefited from the agricultural spending and, to a lesser extent, from the structural funds. At one point, those accounted for 6 per cent of Ireland’s gross domestic product—I have that figure in my head because I looked it up yesterday for other reasons. That has tailed off because Ireland is prosperous now and is not eligible for that kind of spending.
That was not quite my question. I asked whether, if Ireland joined today, it would get the same benefits.
It would not be the same Ireland. If Ireland voted to join today, it would have stayed out for the past 40 years and it would be in a much worse state.
Hanzala Malik has a quick supplementary question on that point. We will then finish off with a question from Rod Campbell.
I have a few supplementary questions. The panel was asked whether joining the European Union would bring strength to Scotland. I will balance that by asking whether that would bring any weaknesses.
Are you asking about an independent Scotland in the European Union as opposed to Scotland as part of the UK?
Yes.
Yes, there would be weaknesses. We have talked about the disadvantages of being a small state—having less weight in some of the big negotiations and not having the capacity to operate right across the board. The question is whether it is worth losing that weight and capacity in favour of the advantages of independence, and that is a political judgment. Small states can succeed but they are constrained. If they are to succeed, they must know how to do that because they will not succeed automatically. How well or badly they do depends on how well organised they are.
It takes years for all new member states to adapt to the reality of the EU and to work within its decision-making process. That said, Scotland is a member of the European Union and several Scottish officials are working on EU matters right now. Scotland is in a very different position compared with the member states that have joined in the past. I would say that Scotland is much better prepared for membership than other countries were. We have, however, mentioned that there are certain weaknesses, and those need to be tackled. It then all comes down to administrative competence.
It is important to remember that how much an independent Scotland, rather than Scotland as part of the United Kingdom in the European Union, will benefit or cost depends on how your policies diverge from the future position of the United Kingdom. On one hand, as a small state, you have some structural disadvantages that you need to overcome; on the other hand, if you have some policy preferences that are very different from UK policies you might benefit because you could pursue those policy preferences more directly.
Because there has been lots of succession to the EU, a lot of the questions on the issue have been answered. A lot of the questions that I would have asked have also now been commented on by the panel. In particular, the comment was made that we would not be starting from point zero.
I need to get my mind round that. Let me think about that.
If we had the same interest as the rest of the UK, we would vote with the rest of the UK; if we did not, with all your caveats about our needing to network, prioritise and influence, we would be in a position to represent our interests in a different way—our interests would diverge.
In essence, that is true, but there is a complication in that, in the preparation for the Council of Ministers, there are all kinds of trade-offs. The Council of Ministers does not vote an awful lot because deals are done before the formal vote comes about: “I’ll give you something, you’ll give me something and you’ll give them something.” There are all kinds of negotiations. It is not simply a case of saying, “We differ from you on this issue, so we’ll vote in a different direction.” Ministers normally work out some compromise in advance.
I refer you to another academic, who is not here. The opinion of Professor Diana Panke from the University of Freiburg seems to be very much in line with the comments that have been made this morning. However, she emphasises that
That is very true. The experience of small states in the European Union shows that those that are well prepared, that have the expertise and that are flexible enough to act fast and tap into the policy process very early on will gain influence. That does not mean that the structural disadvantages that we have pointed to are without importance but it means that, on selected issues, those disadvantages can be overcome.
Part of the description is accurate. The UK, as one of the big players in the EU, is able to exercise some influence in, for example, the fields of security and defence and can inform the framework of the EU. However, Scotland, as an independent state within the EU, would have difficulties in informing the overall framework. That said, I do not see any reason why Scotland should not do as well as Denmark, Sweden or Finland.
That concludes the evidence from our first panel this morning. I thank the two witnesses who have come to the committee today, and I thank Professor Thorhallsson for joining us from Iceland. We really appreciate the effort that you have all made to attend the committee and to inform us as we continue our inquiry.
Welcome back to the continuation of our evidence on Scotland’s place in Europe under the proposals in the Scottish Government’s white paper. Our next witness is Brandon Malone, who is a solicitor advocate.
Thank you for the invitation to give evidence to the committee. I will set out my background and my interest in the subject to give context to my evidence. As you said, I am a lawyer. My background is in commercial dispute resolution. I am a partner in a commercial law firm with offices in Scotland and London; I am the chairman of the Scottish Arbitration Centre; I have a strong interest in constitutional law; and I am a member of the Law Society of Scotland’s constitutional law sub-committee.
You mentioned briefly articles 48 and 49, which have also come up in the other evidence that the committee has heard and in blogs that various people have written. The articles are pretty silent on the situation in which Scotland finds itself, which is unprecedented in Europe, whether in terms of successions or accessions or—as with Greenland—leaving the EU. Do you see any challenges stemming from the silence in the articles or do you see an opportunity to fill that silence?
The situation is without precedent—there is no direct precedent, regardless of what people are saying. As Graham Avery and Sir David Edward discussed in some detail, the EU is a flexible body, and I expect that it would find a solution.
You made the point that the UK Government taking a principled position would not be pre-negotiation. If the UK Government complies with the Edinburgh agreement—particularly the last paragraph—in good faith, would that principled position be a pragmatic way for the UK to set at rest some of the minds that are claiming uncertainty?
What I suggest goes beyond the Edinburgh agreement and the question whether it creates an obligation to act in good faith or however one wants to interpret it. The overriding principle is that, for the past 300 years, Scotland has been in a union in which a number of intangible assets have been built up over that period. I use the term “assets” in a broad sense; I am not referring to physical or cash assets.
We will move to questions from members.
Good morning, Mr Malone, and thank you for your comprehensive opening statement. I would like you to recap a little what you said about the matters that the UK Government could clarify that would not constitute pre-negotiation. First, however, do you agree that some of the comments from the UK Government—particularly in relation to the currency, for example—constitute an opening shot in negotiations?
The comments constitute a negotiating position. The UK Government’s current position serves two purposes—it preserves the negotiating position without giving anything away and it creates a great deal of uncertainty. Uncertainty is a benefit to the UK Government, as people want certainty and there is a great call for certainty from business, the Law Society of Scotland and various bodies, such as the Electoral Commission.
Will you recap—for my benefit, if for no one else’s—the matters on which you think that the UK Government should make a clear statement?
My point was that the UK Government should state prior to the referendum date whether in principle it wants Scotland to be an EU member at the point of independence; whether in principle it will make an application to the EU under article 48 with a view to achieving that; whether in principle it supports Scotland obtaining the same opt-outs as the UK and a rebate on the same basis as the UK; and—because the currency question is tied to the practicalities—whether in principle it is in favour of a sterling zone. I appreciate that that probably goes slightly beyond the remit of articles 48 and 49, but those things are tied pretty closely together.
In view of the time, I will let other members come in.
Good morning, Mr Malone. At a previous committee meeting, there was considerable discussion of articles 48 and 49 with some of your learned colleagues. I asked three of those colleagues who prefer the article 49 route to indicate clearly which article in the Treaty on European Union provides for Scotland to leave the EU, and I was not clear what article they were referring to. I would appreciate your view. My view is that no such article sees Scotland outside the EU. Will you comment on that?
The treaty does not provide for part of a member state to leave; that is not envisaged. The argument that is advanced by those who say that Scotland would be outwith the EU is, in a way, semantic. They say that an independent Scotland would not be part of the member state and would not then be part of the Union. That is the start and finish of their argument.
For a wee moment, I will use your expertise to pursue the notion that article 49 is the route, although I do not believe that it is. The assumption is implicit that Scotland could be put out of the EU very quickly—almost overnight—but that it could take years to come back in. I do not understand that. In effect, there are two processes—going out and coming back in—and there has been no discussion of what the terms of going out might be. I believe that there is no provision for that to happen.
That would be a horrendous mess, for the clear reason that Sir David Edward and Graham Avery set out—it would be a logistical nightmare. The preparation for going out and for reapplication and the covering of the interim procedures would involve much more work than simply obtaining a smooth transition and ensuring continuity of effect would.
Many thanks for that. I will let others come in, convener.
You have said that, in principle, the UK Government would need to do several things. However, the British Government seems to be taking the view that because there has not been a yes vote yet it does not need to do anything. The European Union, too, is refusing to speak to the Scottish Government on the issue, so nothing will happen until after the referendum takes place. Even then, if there was a gap of time in which things needed to be done, the British Government would not have to do anything, despite what you say about it in principle having to do something. The worrying point is that the British Government might even say, “We don’t want you to join the European Union.” If it does that, we will not get into the EU, whether we like it or not. Is that factual?
There are two questions there. You seem to be assuming that the UK will not take a position on any of the issues prior to the referendum. I think that that would be very unfortunate—
That is the line that it is pursuing.
That is the line. I simply make the point that I do not think that it is credible or can be continued. If the Government continues with that line and we get to the point at which you say it refuses to support Scotland’s application to become a member of the European Union—
I appreciate that that is hypothetical.
It is hypothetical and I find it very unlikely. It is possible, but I think that it would be entirely wrong. As I see it, the UK Government is looking at the issue through the wrong end of the telescope. We can see that from the Government’s papers. When the Government commissioned advice from Professors Crawford and Boyle, it asked them to advise on
Let us be realistic. At the end of the day, you are talking about nations looking at the best interests of their population. They do not need to do anything if they do not want to. You cannot force them to do anything. You can rely on people’s good will, but you are not in a position to force people to do anything. You cannot assume that people will play the nice guy. Let us get with the real world. The UK will not be the only state that has the opportunity to say whether it wants us to be a member; other European nations will have to decide that, too, and they might want to add caveats to the circumstances in which they would want us to be a member of the European Union. The situation is not as straightforward as you are suggesting that it could be. It could be straightforward, but it will not be. In the real world, it does not happen that way.
I do not have the gift of foresight that would enable me to tell you exactly what will happen; I am saying what ought to happen, having regard to—
It is a little naive to expect people to roll over and be good. It does not happen that way in the real world.
I disagree. I am not being naive. With respect, I think that you are being very cynical.
I am not; I am just being realistic.
There are, clearly, a range of possible outcomes, but I do not believe that the UK will try to drive Scotland into the ground. The UK Government is fond of describing the union as a marriage. If it is a marriage, it is one that was formed in the 18th century and does not seem to have moved on. Is the UK now saying to us, “We want you to stay but, if you’re going, we’re keeping the house, the pension and all our friends”? I do not think that that is what it is saying or what it will say. I do not think that that would be remotely equitable under international law.
I am testing your evidence. You are saying what ought to happen. I am saying that it is all very good wishing that something ought to happen but, in the real world, it does not happen that way. When you have a divorce, you do not say, “It was nice being with you for 20 years but cheerio.” It does not happen that way. It gets quite nasty.
There are principles. First, assets should be divided equitably. Obviously, there is room for argument on how that should go. Secondly, you have had evidence, from Mr Avery and others, that it is in the best interests of the UK and the rest of the EU to allow a smooth entry for Scotland into Europe on the terms that it already enjoys.
I agree with that. It is in their best interests. I am suggesting that what is hoped for in principle might not pan out in reality. I am disagreeing with what you are suggesting.
I agree that there is a wide range of possible outcomes. I have no issue with that suggestion. I am dealing in the realms of probability, likelihood and principle. That is where I and a number of other witnesses are coming from.
You referred to the testimony of Mr Avery and Sir David Edward. We have that on record, along with the testimony of many other witnesses.
I am sure that it has done so, although I cannot speak for the Scottish Government and I do not purport to do so. The argument, however, is the same as that which is being advanced now and, as Mr Avery said, it is not the complete picture. Sir David Edward, who was a European court judge, says he thinks that it is incorrect.
I am asking for your opinion.
I am giving it; as I say, it coincides.
Forget the Scottish Government—have you examined this?
Yes, of course.
Why do you come to that conclusion? We accept that we are in uncharted waters. How do we know that Spain, for example, would not say no to Scottish membership?
To date, no EU member has said that it would say no. They might do so; we do not know. I think that it is extremely unlikely. We can only go on the basis of probabilities.
Is it not likely that article 49 would have to be the route taken on this issue?
No, for the reasons that I gave earlier. That would involve Scotland applying from outwith Europe, which, as I say, is in no one’s interests. It would be an absurdity, as Mr Avery and Sir David Edward suggest. I keep going back to them because they are much more experienced than I am in these matters. They are also impartial, which I do not claim to be.
On another subject, if internal UK negotiations fail to reach a currency agreement, will Scotland be forced to apply to join the euro, and if it does not meet the euro criteria to join, where would it go?
We are now straying into economics and interesting areas like that. There is a lot of evidence to show that Scotland cannot be forced to join the euro: it would not have its own currency to join the European exchange rate mechanism and would not meet the criteria. As of day 1 of independence, that is not going to happen.
The uncertainty is being created by the fact that, to some extent, there is a difference of opinion within the SNP about what currency it would like to use. Would you agree with that?
I am aware of a difference of opinion within the yes campaign. I do not know about the SNP internally; I cannot speak for the party.
Dennis Canavan, for example, who was, I think, head of the yes—
He is part of the yes campaign. I am sorry; I am distinguishing between the SNP and the yes campaign. I know that Mr Canavan and, I think, the Green Party—
Okay. Dennis Canavan is not a member of the SNP, but there is a difference of opinion in the yes campaign on what currency it would use. That is why I am asking you what currency would be used if the pound was not used.
I do not think that that is a question that I can answer. That is ultimately a matter for the Scottish Government of the day, which will be voted in on the basis of policies that it has put forward. However, as I said, I find it extremely unlikely that it would reach that position because, as with Scotland’s European Union membership, the UK Government has not ruled out a UK currency. No one has ruled that out. The UK Government says, “Oh, it’ll be a difficult negotiation” and all the rest of it, but no one is ruling that out. It will not say yes or no, or whether it is in favour of it or against it in principle. It is simply maximising the uncertainty around the question.
I am sorry to begin with this question, Mr Malone, but I have to admit that I am slightly confused. Are you representing Business for Scotland this morning?
No. I have provided it with my opinion, but I am not representing it. I am here in a personal capacity.
Right. So you are here in a personal capacity and are a specialist in construction and dispute arbitration.
Yes. Those are my principal areas of interest.
Thank you. You mentioned that your view and that of the two experts whom you quoted is that article 48 is the preferred method of joining or maintaining membership of the EU and that that is the most valid method.
Yes.
Given that Scotland is not a signatory to any of the EU treaties and that article 49 is designed to accommodate a new state that wishes to become a member of the EU, why is article 49 dismissed so thoroughly, as you seem to think it is?
As I said, article 49 envisages a process in which an applicant state starts from ground zero and works up through candidate membership to become a full member of the European Union. I am not dismissing it in its entirety; I am saying that Scotland would have to be outside Europe to adopt that route, as a country has to be a state before it can apply under article 49. That is all fine, but it means that there would be an interim period of absurdity in which European citizens would lose their rights in relation to Scotland’s territory and institutions and Scottish citizens would potentially lose their rights—although potentially they would not, as they would still have UK passports and therefore may still enjoy UK citizenship. There would be what various people have described as an absurdity and a legal nightmare, which is not desirable.
That is where your argument falls down. Scotland cannot make an application under article 48, either.
I said that the UK Government would have to do that.
Yes. In either situation, Scotland would depend on the UK Government to make the application. I think that those who argue for article 48 are making a big error in many ways, because I think that, under article 49, it is entirely possible to make accommodations that would allow Scotland to become a member of the EU in its own right in a similar way to under article 48. Europe is particularly good at accommodations. I find it very difficult to understand why people get hung up on article 48.
No, for the reasons I set out earlier. I hear what you are saying about the Committee of the Regions and, with respect, I would say that that is not strictly relevant to what we are talking about here.
It is; it is actually very relevant.
That committee would not determine the issue; it would be the Council and, ultimately, the members who would do that and, as I say, none of them has said that they will veto. In his evidence to this committee, Sir David Edward said:
We have had the evidence of others, and we are considering that evidence, so it would be helpful to have your responses to the questions that are being posed. However, let me ask just one more question. Do you disagree with any of the points that are made in the chapters of the white paper on independence that talk about EU relations?
You would have to guide me to it; I do not have it before me.
Perhaps you might like to read it and give us your thoughts in written form.
I do not disagree with the points that are made within the white paper, but if you have a specific point in mind, perhaps I could answer that.
No. If you had a specific point of disagreement, that would be the one I would want to hear about.
Mr Malone, you mentioned that you were involved in the Law Society’s constitutional committee. Has that committee examined this issue?
It has. I am not here to speak for the Law Society or its committee. It is looking at the issue and I understand that a submission will be made.
Thank you. I go back to the points made by Hanzala Malik and his assertions and the discussion about how the negotiations might go. The assets of the UK were mentioned; are the liabilities not the other side of that coin?
Yes. Under strict international law, there are a variety of possible outcomes as regards division of assets and liabilities. However, as I said earlier, I think that we are approaching the problem from the wrong end if we say that the argument about that division will happen after independence.
To go back to what Mr Malik was saying, it would not be a case of the rest of the UK working against Scotland’s interests; rather, it would be in the interests of both the rest of the UK and Scotland to reach a consensual agreement in the negotiation process.
Yes.
In earlier evidence to the committee, Aidan O’Neill described the idea of a possible human rights hole being created with regard to existing EU citizens in Scotland if Scotland came out of the EU as being a “nightmare scenario”. If Scotland came out of the EU at any point, what impact would that hole have on other EU nationals and businesses and existing EU agreements, such as that on fisheries?
It would be very problematic. If nothing was in place and we got to the midnight hour on the day of independence and EU citizens in Scotland suddenly lost all their entitlement under the EU regime, it would be incredibly problematic.
In earlier evidence, Professor Cram stated in relation to whether the route would be through article 48 or 49:
Yes, I do. That is consistent with how the EU operates and with what the EU does. A number of examples have been talked about where rules that on the face of it are strict have become flexible to accommodate reality because, ultimately, the EU is a political organisation and there will be a political reality that needs to be addressed and fixed.
That completes our evidence session. I thank Mr Malone for coming along—we are continuing our inquiries and every piece of evidence is helpful and informative.
Previous
AttendanceNext
“Brussels Bulletin”