Official Report 510KB pdf
The next item of business is our final oral evidence-taking session in our stage 1 consideration of the Local Government Finance (Unoccupied Properties etc) (Scotland) Bill.
I am happy to pick that up. I do not know whether you want any opening remarks, convener. However, specifically on your reference to consultation, it was felt that it would not be proportionate to carry out a consultation at that stage because of the number of properties involved and the scale of the issue. It affects £18 million of income generation in the context of £2.3 billion income from non-domestic rates.
If the consultation is on-going now that the bill has been drafted, is the Government still minded to be flexible about how the regulations will be applied? It was a concern of businesspeople that they had not had the opportunity to feed in. Are you saying that, in spite of that, you are still listening?
Yes. The Government continues to listen on the issue. The consultation has been on-going. The bill gives ministers the power to introduce regulations that can vary the reliefs in the same way that we can vary the small business bonus. The on-going engagement with stakeholders will ensure that they and Parliament are listened to.
I will press you a little on that. As recently as in advance of today’s meeting, you have issued a press release that still talks about £18 million being raised from these properties. You say that you are listening, but you do not appear to be hearing what businesses are saying. There is a very clear message coming from them that these properties are unoccupied because there is a lack of demand and because of the economic circumstances, yet you seem to have taken no cognisance of that. Would you like to comment on that?
The committee should be aware that what we are being asked to approve at this stage is the enabling power for regulations to be introduced to vary the rates relief. We believe that the figure of £18 million that was announced in the budget will incentivise landlords to open up premises and to bring premises back to life. That is the policy that was announced at the time of the budget.
Perhaps you can provide some evidence for that. Throughout the evidence that we have taken, there has been no indication that there are empirical statistics to prove that what you say is the case. In fact, it is increasingly looking as though the whole proposal is based on the Walter Mitty school of economics.
There is no empirical evidence either way. Similar reforms in England were enacted by the UK Government in 2008 and then took place in Wales but, because of the various factors that affect local economies—including the euro zone crisis, the general recession and the VAT hike, which cost Scotland £1 billion—it is very hard to establish empirical evidence to show what impact the empty property rates relief policies in England and Wales have had either way. For that reason, we have learned lessons from, for example, policy on rates relief for industrial properties. We are not simply following what happened in England but are adopting a slightly different approach and continuing the 100 per cent relief for industrial properties because of the experience in England.
What is the cost of empty property rates relief just now?
Over the five-year period, the cost is £757 million. That is the amount that the Scottish Government gives in empty property rates relief. If the proposals were enacted as announced at the time of the budget, it would still cost the Government £721 million in rates relief.
There seems to be an assumption that the 5,500 vacant properties will come back into use. Where is the evidence for that? You are asking us to consider legislation and a proposal that are backed up by no statistics. We have heard witness after witness say that empty property relief will not achieve either of its objectives of regenerating the economy and bringing those properties back into use, and that it could in fact end up costing the Government money, given the public liability.
We are satisfied that the figure of £18 million, which is calculated according to a formula, is robust. That does not assume that 5,500 properties would necessarily be brought back into use, but simply outlines how those properties will receive a lesser relief under the proposal. That is how we arrived at the figure of £18 million, but we do not assume that those properties will all open. Although we aspire to bring as many properties as possible back into use, the figure is predicated not on how many come back into use but on the fact that the relief that the Scottish Government provides is lower. It is down from £757 million to £721 million, which does not seem completely disproportionate in terms of sharing the burden.
The FSB said in its written evidence that it was unfair that we were paying out more for rates relief than we were for the small business bonus scheme.
The Scottish Government has protected the poundage, and the small business bonus scheme, taken in context, has been incredibly helpful. Under our current proposals, we would still give relief of 10 per cent where none is given in England. Industrial properties, which were affected in England, are protected in Scotland, and we have ensured that we are applying some of the lessons that have been learned.
The evidence that we have heard in response to lines of questioning about empty properties in certain parts of the country suggests that there might be geographical differences. In my patch, for example, some folk seem to be willing to hold on to properties until they get the right price even though such a price cannot be sustained in the current market. Others have wondered whether changing the use of certain empty properties might allow them to be let. Are you willing to be flexible and examine some of those issues in the formulation at the end of the bill?
Absolutely. We have asked stakeholders to give us their suggestions, highlight best practice and tell us what might help to incentivise owners to bring their properties back into use, and we will remain a listening Government in that respect. Of course, we will also learn from Administrations in other parts of the UK and, through our officials, find out what policies they are adopting or, indeed, reviewing to ensure that our part of the UK is the most competitive.
I might be about to sound unreasonable, but I should make it clear that I generally support the bill.
I would be the first to say that you are a very reasonable man, Mr Pentland, and I am sure that you will find the Scottish Government to be very reasonable in turn. When we consider the regulations on varying the reliefs, we will bring them back to Parliament before any change is made; indeed, I understand that this very committee will examine the matter. Ministers will not act in isolation and the regulations, which, I hope, will reflect some of the comments that have been made by committees and stakeholders, will still be subject to a level of parliamentary scrutiny.
Given the difficulties that you have already highlighted in separating out the effects of empty property relief reform from wider economic factors, how do ministers propose to monitor the impact of the reforms?
We will remain in dialogue with assessors, councils and all stakeholders to ascertain the impact of the policy. For the reasons that you fairly acknowledged, it will be hard to produce evidence on how many properties are brought back into use, because we will not be able to isolate the policy from other policies that might have had an impact, such as the small business bonus or support through the regeneration strategy, and other factors that might determine the economic climate in which the business world operates.
Do you have a period in mind for reviewing the impact of the bill?
There is the budget process, from which the policy emerged, which is on-going. We must regularly consider the income from non-domestic rates, so of course there will be on-going monitoring of the perceived impact of the policy and the actual numbers. It is worth remembering that all non-domestic rates are returned to local government, and that that part of the local government settlement is assured by the Scottish Government.
The Finance Committee’s report gave me extreme concern. You said that you have provided evidence to the committee about the £18 million. Do we have that evidence, or are we able to get it?
We are able to get it.
There remain concerns about enforcement. How will the Government recoup the £18 million? Even if you do recoup it—which is not likely, from what you are saying—what will you do with it?
The income that we would generate from the reduced relief as proposed would be generated in exactly the same way as the £2.3 billion raised through non-domestic rates is generated. Assessors identify the properties that are liable and the council collects the rates.
My major concern is that a business and regulatory impact assessment has not been carried out. Do we have the evidence in relation to the national health service and Scottish Enterprise, which was mentioned?
We do, and I can share it with the committee: the impact on the NHS is £0.3 million; the figure for Scottish Enterprise is £0.4 million; and the figure for councils is £1.7 million. Members should bear in mind that non-domestic rates income is £2.3 billion per year. Those figures are calculated on the basis that none of the properties concerned is brought back into use. They represent the cost of the policy to those organisations. I hope that that answers your question.
There are a number of schemes in councils to try to give council properties to community groups and so on, at a peppercorn rent. Would such properties be exempt from the charge?
An organisation or property that is entitled to charity or associated rate relief would continue to enjoy that after the proposed reform. Over the five-year period, the cost to Government of relief to charities is £734 million. The policy will not affect non-profit-making organisations that are covered by charity relief.
So the costs to local government could be less if those groups use the property.
The answer to that question will depend on how the groups construct their assets. We are about to launch the community empowerment and renewal bill, which has the purpose of releasing more assets from the public sector for community use. If organisations have the appropriate constitution and ownership, they could be relieved of non-domestic rates, which I am sure will delight the cabinet secretary, John Swinney.
I fully appreciate the sentiment behind the proposals, but we have taken evidence from Glasgow City Council that the bill might well lead to its having to demolish properties. I thought that the bill aims to encourage regeneration and the use of empty buildings.
I would have thought that the new burden on local government of £1.7 million seems like a drop in the ocean compared with the £11.5 billion that is given to local government by way of the settlement. The non-domestic rate income is given back to local government in full, so it funds the services and is part of the budget process and balancing the books. That would have been made much easier if the UK Government had not savaged the Scottish Government’s budget.
Will you explain a little more fully why industrial premises are not included if the policy is such a great idea and will generate more income and result in more properties being brought back into use?
There was evidence from the English experience that, because industrial premises are so specific by nature, it is hard to adapt them to new use. Therefore, it would be disproportionate and unfair if the empty property rates relief policy was applied in such a bland way to industrial premises. Learning the lessons from England, we felt that it made sense to exempt industrial properties. Some of the more glitzy stories in the press suggested that some industrial properties in England were demolished. There is not a huge amount of evidence on that, but if the policy was not implemented in a sophisticated way, it could have that impact on industrial properties. For that reason, industrial properties are not covered.
Is it not a bit of a contradiction that you are prepared to look at the experience in England in relation to industrial premises but you discount the experience there in relation to retail premises? We know that, as a result of the policy and the pressures of bank lending, the retail vacancies figure rose from 3 to 14 per cent. That is the nearest that we have to concrete evidence, yet you seem to discount it while using the English experience in relation to industrial premises.
There are specific circumstances with industrial properties. It would be wrong to say that the empty property relief policy in isolation caused the increase in vacancies in England. As we have discussed, the international recession, the euro zone crisis and the UK Government’s increase in VAT were in the mix in that context. We have to consider all the factors. The policy was introduced by the previous UK Government in 2008 and has been sustained by the current one. We will learn the lessons from across the United Kingdom on how policies have been applied and on innovative packages to incentivise the use of our town centres.
Do you honestly believe that, in the current economic climate, anything but the teeniest proportion of people would wilfully not try to let their property? A host of people, including the CBI, Scottish Chambers of Commerce and the FSB—the list goes on—as well as the Finance Committee in its damning report have told us that the major cause of empty properties is the lack of demand in the current economic climate.
Perhaps Margaret Mitchell should reflect on the fact that the UK Government does not share her views—the policy of the previous UK Government has been sustained by the current one.
You say that you are listening, but you are not hearing the clear and unambiguous message that is emerging—that this is a counterproductive policy and that you really should think again.
I make the point once more that the purpose of the bill is to give ministers the power to vary the reliefs. We will do that in the context of all our other policies. When we set the reliefs and arrive at that policy we will return to this committee. I am sure that we will evidence how we have taken on board the views of the Finance Committee and this committee and the views of stakeholders and we will show that we are indeed a listening Government.
Like most committee members, I am sure, I welcome the minister’s commitment to continue to listen and to be flexible as to how the policy is finally implemented—particularly the point around speculative development. If someone invests in a property, sometimes—precisely because it is speculative—it might not work out. If that issue is going to be looked at, that is to be welcomed.
I certainly do not think that the move will be counterproductive in certain areas of the country; in fact, I think that it will be welcomed by folk who are looking for premises in areas where rents are still stubbornly high.
You ask a very good question about planning considerations. You will be aware, for example, of the planning consultations that were launched in March, some of which are about simplifying and streamlining the system and being more flexible and responsive. The solution for many town centres lies not in simply expecting retail to come back as it was 10 or 20 years ago but in diversifying their use, and that issue will be picked up in the regeneration strategy that Alex Neil is leading. I will certainly do all that I can within the planning remit to make that approach quick, effective and real.
It has been suggested in evidence that this might not be the right time to introduce such a bill and that bringing back so many empty properties into the kind of use that we hope for might be counterproductive. What guarantees can you give that that will not be the case? What safety measures have you put in place, and what other help and assistance are you prepared to offer to deal, in particular, with the properties in some town centres that, as Kevin Stewart suggested, might not be appropriate for the use that they might once have had?
Let me, once again, set this in context: this measure will effectively generate £18 million-worth of income, whereas year on year the Scottish Government provides £0.5 billion in rates reliefs to a range of different people. We have to put this in perspective. This £18 million burden will be shared among a potential 5,500 properties across the country, but I point out that a host of Government support packages is available from Scottish Enterprise or business gateway, or through local government’s regeneration function, to stimulate local companies and support them in developing new businesses. However, we will no longer subsidise closure and the commercial inactivity of properties that remain closed at everyone else’s expense. A range of measures is available to support individual businesses that want to open up or, as the convener suggested, properties could be released for other functions that would not incur non-domestic rates but would still serve a good community function and complement whatever else is going on in town centres.
You mentioned Scottish Enterprise and business gateway. How much have those partners bought into your bill?
All Government agencies are expected to deliver the Government’s outcomes and all community planning partners, including the private sector, will work together on the regeneration strategy. We will ask everyone for their views on the business rates review, the consultation for which will be launched fairly shortly and carried out over the summer.
Would the minister consider the reforms appropriate if they had no impact on the number of empty properties but succeeded only in raising revenue?
If this was simply an income-generation measure that had an adverse effect on the business community, we would not be progressing with it. However, the Scottish Government believes that it will not only increase income through lower rates relief but incentivise landlords and owners to open up premises that up to this point have been closed. We genuinely believe that the policy is about incentivisation as well as income generation. If it were just about income generation at the expense of the business community, we would not be progressing it.
On the back of that, what other measures were considered in relation to this?
In relation to what?
The policy objective of reducing the number of empty properties.
As I said, the regeneration strategy—which the Cabinet Secretary for Infrastructure and Capital Investment, Alex Neil, will take forward shortly—will outline more of that work. The policy should be set in the context of preserving the small business bonus scheme, which is a highly targeted measure to support small businesses. If we view the policy in the context of the planning reform that we have spoken about and the regeneration strategy, the fact that it will generate £18 million out of a tax take of £2.3 billion means that it is fairly proportionate to the challenge that we face.
I will not ask you to give away any of the cabinet secretary’s secrets.
I was not a member of the Government when the budget was composed, but I am sure that the cabinet secretary had to consider a range of financial options for balancing the budget, which, as I have pointed out, was drastically reduced by the UK Government, whose business rates relief policy is less generous than the Scottish Government’s.
Do you think that the legislative process should be paused while a proper consultation takes place?
As a former councillor, I am not sure that local government would appreciate the Scottish Government saying that it intended to pause the prospect of its receiving new income. We will have time to consider the matter. The bill will not be enacted this week or next week; it will not come in until the next financial year. We have time to consider the regulations, to bring them to Parliament and to implement them in time for the next financial year. We are not rushing to a decision. If you are looking for time to consider our proposals, that is already built into the process.
As a former councillor, I am well aware of the Scottish Government’s previous big ideas. It was at the implementation stage that the difficulties arose. I am glad that you will take on board the result of the proper consultation that is taking place.
It could be argued that the policy in question is a policy of the 2008 Labour Government. I can only commend your party’s Government for coming up with it.
Given the concerns that have been raised—both with us and with the Finance Committee—about the fact that a business and regulatory impact assessment has not been undertaken, why will you not consider undertaking such an assessment?
At the risk of repeating myself, given that the policy will generate £18 million out of a total tax take of £2.3 billion, it would not be proportionate to carry out such an assessment. We are talking about a unitary national system of reliefs, unlike the council tax benefit system, on which there might be 32 different policies. There is a difference between the two systems. It was not felt that it would be proportionate to carry out a BRIA on a national system at that level.
Thanks very much.
First, I thank the committee for asking Derek Mackay and me to give evidence today.
It has also been suggested that there is a danger that property owners who were keeping properties empty for a particular reason might reclassify them as second homes. Has the Government considered that matter and whether the bill should also cover second homes?
We have looked at the matter but it will take more work to formulate a working definition of second homes that will allow us to distinguish between the two types of property. That said, we think that second homes often provide economic benefits to and improve the areas in which they are located, although I admit that the reverse can be the case if there are too many of them. However, that is not the case with empty homes, which is why we have focused on them. We intend to put together a proper definition to distinguish between the two types of property and that will come down to factors such as the length of time for which a property is occupied in the course of a year.
One could argue that it would be more appropriate for local authorities to decide whether second homes have a negative economic impact in their area and so should have the rate applied. Will you consider that issue?
Councils have different views on the issue of second homes and if we want to ensure that the measure is as workable as possible we must take a consistent approach across the country. We will look at the responses that we receive as the legislation proceeds and try to be flexible in the way that Derek Mackay suggested. However, our view at the moment is that a consistent approach to second homes, which we do not intend to capture in this legislation, and empty homes, which we do, is the best way to move forward.
What is your reaction to Waverley Housing’s suggestion that to tackle the problem of empty properties the Scottish Government use more of its affordable housing supply budget to allow registered social landlords to purchase empty properties on the open market or to convert empty retail units to housing rather than focusing on new build?
Although such suggestions are worth considering on their own merits, they should not preclude what we are attempting to do in the legislation. The problem of empty homes goes much wider than RSLs and I believe that the basis of the bill, which is to provide some form of disincentive with regard to keeping properties empty, stands on its merits.
Many local authorities have a lot of empty homes because they are in hard-to-let areas. How can the bill help in solving that problem?
On your first question, we have worked with housing lobby groups such as Shelter Scotland on that matter. The proposed council tax increase is only one of a number of measures that we are considering to bring long-term empty properties back into use. For example, the main aim of the Scottish empty homes partnership, which is run by Shelter and has been funded by the Scottish Government up until next year, is to support local authorities, private owners and others in reducing the number of empty homes and it can therefore help councils in working with owners.
Why are all the estimates based on the assumption that all councils will use the power and charge 100 per cent of council tax or apply the maximum levy?
I am not sure how else a workable estimate would be arrived at. The figure is the potential amount that could be realised.
Why was that approach used? Some sort of variation could have been built in to make a more realistic assumption about the financial impact.
I do not accept that. We have said that the power will be an option for councils to use. Given that, there could be innumerable permutations of some councils using or not using the power and some councils providing different discounts. We could not have arrived at any other meaningful figure. We have specified the maximum that could be achieved. That makes sense to me, at least.
I do not think that starting from such a figure is realistic, and that is never good for a policy decision.
I am not sure whether I understood the last part of your question.
Will you give examples of circumstances that would qualify for exemptions? You will obviously want such matters to be clear and transparent.
That is right. The issues will take time to work through. If it was clear that a sincere effort had been made to sell or let a property, for example, we would not want to punish somebody for a genuine attempt to bring an empty home into productive use. Those matters should be considered further. They are not easy to resolve; we will deal with them in conjunction with our local authority partners. The judgment will be about what is prescribed in primary legislation or regulations and what is left to local authorities.
Would someone be required to keep advertising their home and to incur more costs?
I imagine that someone who was genuinely trying to sell their home would want to advertise it. There must be further discussion about what is a genuine and sincere attempt to market a property. Putting a “For Sale” sign in a back garden would not be a sincere attempt to market a property.
What is your view on the suggestion from Scottish Land & Estates that an additional exemption from any council tax increase should apply when an owner has a long-term empty property that is subject to a live planning application?
What you suggest is not something that I support. It would be quite possible for an owner to lodge a planning application to try to circumvent their liability for additional council tax. When we look at tax issues—of course, we do not currently have many tax powers—we have to be careful to ensure that we do not make it easy for people to avoid the tax. We have seen evidence of that happening over many years in the context of the UK Exchequer, to the substantial loss of taxpayers in this country. It is fair to everyone if the rules are applied consistently and are not easily avoided.
Can you at least give the committee an indication of the timescale for the laying of the regulations before the Parliament?
We hope to lay the regulations as soon as the bill receives royal assent. When that happens will depend on the committee, to some extent, but it will probably be in early December.
There will be no substantial delay.
Some of the more sensible suggestions from Scottish Land & Estates were to do with empty properties in rural areas. Some houses will never be brought back into use, because they are in the middle of fields or up on the top of hills or whatever. Would it be more realistic to remove such properties from the council tax register? Will you talk to valuation boards about some of the bizarre situations in which properties that no one in their right mind thinks will ever come back into residential use remain on the register?
There is some sense in the suggestion, but I understand that currently a derelict property can be removed from the list that is kept by the relevant assessor. If a property is removed, of course, it is no longer subject to tax. It is for the assessor to determine whether a property remains on the list; neither local authorities nor the Scottish Government have control over that.
I realise that that is a matter for local authorities and valuation boards. Is guidance issued to authorities and boards, to encourage a uniform approach across the country to dealing with such properties?
I do not think that local authorities have a role; it is strictly a matter for the assessors. The Government cannot issue guidance in that regard, as far as I understand it. Neither local authorities nor the Scottish Government have direct control over what is a matter for assessors.
I appreciate the offer.
In its evidence to the Finance Committee, the bill team acknowledged that not all councils will apply the maximum levy. Why then was the maximum figure used as the basis for the modelling in the financial memorandum?
I think that I have answered that question as well as I could do. I do not know what other figure could sensibly have been used. Local authorities might want to apply an increased charge to a varying extent—and bear it in mind that we will enable them to use the power in different ways in different parts of the council area—or they might not want to apply an increased charge at all, so there is no limit to the potential for variation.
What is the likely impact of only some local authorities using the powers? Given that that is the key variable that would affect the financial impact of the proposed powers, why was modelling for that not carried out?
It is hard to predict or model on the basis of what individual councils might do. We believe strongly in local democracy, so if a council feels that it is important to use the power, perhaps because it has a preponderance of empty homes that it wants to deal with, it can do so. Another council that does not have the same problem might not do that. It is very hard to model decisions that will ultimately be taken at individual local authority level.
I think that you might have been asked the same questions, minister, no matter what assumptions you made. Are there any other questions on this area?
I have a brief question, which is similar to that which I asked the Minister for Local Government and Planning. Is there not a realisation that vast numbers of properties are unlet because there is no demand for them? Again, that aspect undermines the policy intent.
The straightforward answer to that is to suggest that you look at the housing waiting lists across the country. There is undoubtedly demand for more houses. What we have just now is an underused resource. Mr Mackay made the point that we provide a benefit in the form of the Scottish small business bonus, which is an incentive to businesses. The power in the bill will be a disincentive to being economically inactive by leaving houses empty.
The houses may be empty because they need more money spent on them, but there is no guarantee that the additional finance will be used for that purpose.
No, but we will try to encourage councils to do that. I mentioned the three or four different ways in which we have given money to help to achieve that. For example, we have helped fund some councils to take on an empty homes officer. Such a post is common in England. An empty homes officer can go around the local area and ascertain what houses have been lying empty for some time. I am not trying to suggest that somebody would be happy to sit on a string of empty houses. They might not have the resources to upgrade a house to a lettable standard.
But there is nothing in the bill that would make that happen. It would very much be the choice of councils.
Councils are answerable to their electorate. If they were to take in money and not use it for a productive purpose, they would have to answer for that. The nature of the relationship that this Government has with local government is that we have said that local government has its own mandate and responsibilities and that we leave it to local authorities to take decisions in their areas.
If the policy proved counterproductive and the money did not achieve the policy intent, would it be reconsidered or rescinded?
There are two things to say on that. If the policy was not productive because councils did not use the resources to improve properties—
My concern is that the policy would end up being just a revenue-raising exercise.
To the extent that it reduced the number of empty homes because there was a disincentive for owners to continue to have empty homes, it would have a beneficial impact, even if homes were not brought into productive use through the other route that I mentioned. We are confident that the policy will have a beneficial impact in the way that we have described.
What is the solid evidence for that?
My previous answers set out the solid evidence. There is evidence from the empty homes work that we have done in the south and west of the country. We have evidence on the existing demand—huge numbers of people are waiting, not least because of the prolonged period of the right to buy, which has diminished the public housing stock over many years. We know that there is demand, so we are trying to increase the supply. Perhaps we have enough faith in the market to realise that the additional supply will be met by that willing demand.
I have one quick question. When the bill team gave evidence to the Finance Committee, it acknowledged that not all councils would apply the maximum levy that the proposals would allow. Why was the maximum figure used as the basis—
I think that we have covered that.
Has it been done?
Yes—more than once.
Sorry.
We are probably finished on that issue, so we will move on to the housing support grant. Committee members recently visited Shetland to speak to council officers and tenants. We felt that it was important to understand the historical reasons why Shetland Islands Council is in the unique position of being the one council that still receives the grant. One thing that was said loudly was that the council feels that there was a commitment, followed by a promise, to write off the debt, which the council sees as arising from Shetland doing its bit to ensure that accommodation was available when the oil industry came to the area. It is felt that the debt was almost written off in 1997, but there was a change of Government. What is the Scottish Government’s view on the history of the debt?
You are exactly right about Shetland’s point of view. We have found no evidence of a commitment apparently given by a previous Government, many years before the Scottish Parliament came into existence. We have seen no evidence that a commitment was given by a UK Government wanting to write off housing debt. There was a link in that the UK Government had an interest in ensuring adequate housing supply for people coming to work in the oil industry, but we have seen no evidence that the UK Government—not the Scottish Government—made a commitment to write off the debt. Shetland Islands Council has written to the UK Government on the issue, so it will be interesting to see the response.
Another area that we touched on while we were in Shetland was the potential writing off of the debt as part of the proposed stock transfer, which failed. Our understanding is that the debt in Shetland is different from that in other authorities, in that it is internal. How would that have worked with stock transfer?
As far as I am aware, the stock transfer arrangements for Shetland would not have been different to those for other authorities.
Other authorities’ debts would be from public loans, whereas Shetland’s debt is probably to its oil fund, so it is an internal debt.
I ask Sam Baker to comment on that.
I cannot speak for the Treasury, but my understanding is that the Treasury’s position has always been that it would write off only debt that was owed, in essence, to itself. Therefore, it would not have written off Shetland’s debt, which as you say was an internal loan from one part of the council to another. The Treasury would have written off the debt only if the stock had been transferred. My understanding is that Shetland Islands Council argued to receive grant to write off its debt, but not to transfer the stock. The Treasury would not have considered that.
The issue of an internal debt, rather than a debt to the Public Works Loan Board, has just become apparent to us, probably only this morning, to be honest. It has been quite difficult for the committee to get to grips with that.
We will partly rely on Shetland Islands Council to provide us with information, but we are happy to find that out and come back to the member or the committee on that. However, as was suggested previously, the main reason that stock transfer did not go ahead was a valuation disagreement.
I am pleased to hear that you will try to engage with Shetland about how it manages the process. What we were originally faced with was that either it continued to get the grant or there would be a huge rent rise. There did not seem to be any modelling in between, or any effort. We have had a commitment from Shetland Islands Council that it will look at the modelling. I hope that when you go up you will look at whether there are transitional arrangements that could help the council to make some of the models work and that do not put up the rent of every Shetland Islands Council tenant overnight by a huge amount.
There has been virtually no rent rise in real terms in Shetland for a number of years. Other councils have had that rent rise in many cases. We have to try to treat people on a level playing field.
Minister, you said that you would look for information about stock transfer. When we visited Shetland there was a comment that, in the course of the Labour-Liberal Scottish Executive—I do not know which years—there was a budget line for writing off housing debt. I assume that, if it was ever there, it would have been entirely attached to stock transfer. It would be good for those who were on the Shetland visit, and the others, to get clarification about that point. The position is very difficult, because a lot of the comments that were made were not evidenced, but we are obliged to follow them up if we possibly can.
That is a fair point. Obviously we have a view on a number of those issues and Shetland Islands Council might have a different view. I have not yet worked out exactly how we can do it, but we will try to make an objective assessment of the case. One of the things that we can do is check back to find out whether there was indeed such a budget line.
Minister, you said earlier that there had not been any rent increases for the past so many years, but it is also important to point out that Shetland Islands Council is sitting second highest in a table of rent amounts.
Convener, that is according to Shetland Islands Council. Other tables are different.
The minister can answer the question.
I will come back on that point, but before I do, I should say that I have just been advised that the previous Scottish Executive did discuss a possible grant for Shetland Islands Council, but only on the proviso that it transferred its stock. That was the previous position. We will come back to the committee with more in writing.
As there are no further questions for the minister, we will move into private.
Previous
Planning