We move on to the meat of today’s business, which is to continue to take evidence as part of our scrutiny of the Scotland Bill and the relevant legislative consent memoranda.
I am the MSP for Aberdeen North, deputy convener of the committee, and a member of the Scottish National Party.
I am emeritus professor at the University of Frankfurt in Germany and I have been advising a number of international organisations all my life, mainly on taxation and decentralisation issues.
I am the MSP for the Liberal Democrats for Glasgow. It is relevant to the committee’s work to mention that I was vice-chair of the Steel commission, which was the Liberal Democrat party’s contribution to moving towards federalism.
I am the principal of the University of Glasgow. Previously, I was a professor of economics, and I chaired the independent expert group that gave evidence to the Calman commission.
I am the member of the Scottish Parliament for the Edinburgh Pentlands constituency, and a member of the Scottish Conservative party.
I am a former director of the Institute for Public Policy Research. I chaired the independent commission that was set up by the Welsh Assembly Government into financing the devolved authority in Wales. We made an effort to do so in a way that would be consistent with the general scheme of devolution in the United Kingdom.
I am the MSP for the Central Fife constituency, and I am a member of the Scottish National Party.
I am a professor of economics, specialising in public finance, at the Université de Montréal. I have worked for various international bodies, giving advice on decentralisation, and for the federal Government of Canada and the Council of the Federation, which is a body grouping the provincial premiers in Canada.
I am a Labour MSP for the Highlands and Islands.
Those are the formal participants in the round-table discussion. Also at the table are people from the parliamentary research services and various clerks. I make specific mention of the two expert advisers to the committee: Jim Gallagher and Professor Ulph.
I will give you a general view—in five minutes, I can do no more.
Thank you. I am keen that everyone has an opportunity to say an initial word on the record.
I will start with something that I read in the paper this morning—there is no firm relationship between fiscal autonomy and growth. It would be risky to make that case. On the other hand, I agree with what François Vaillancourt said about the need to have fiscal autonomy on top of spending autonomy in order to make a Parliament fully accountable to its electorate. It would also set the right incentives for making the region grow stronger than it would without that fiscal responsibility. However, there is no automatic relationship between the two; it all depends on the quality of your policy.
I have been pre-empted to some extent. The broad structure of the bill is coherent and I have no quarrel with it in principle. The more autonomy that you have, the more freedom of action you have, but that tends to mean that you lose some of the insurance characteristics of being in a larger fiscal entity. It is a matter for the Scottish people how far they want to trade off freedom of action against a safety net or risk-sharing structure that exists in a larger fiscal union.
I am happy with the general structure of the bill because it fits well with the proposals and recommendations that my expert group made to the commission. As Gerry Holtham pointed out, where you sit on the spectrum between greater risk and greater accountability is a political issue and not an economic one. We pointed that out to the commission from the start.
We should move directly to the structure of the income tax powers, which, as people will be aware, has been subject to extensive criticism. I would like to explore some of that criticism. There is concern that we will not have access to the fruits of growth because we will get a smaller proportion of revenue from the higher tax bands, as they are currently structured, and that the Scottish Parliament may have to raise its income tax rate to offset the decline of income tax as a share of total revenues. It is said that we should also be concerned about the impact of one Government’s tax changes on another—the vertical fiscal externalities. I urge people to address directly the issue of how the income tax power should optimally be structured.
You raise a mixture of points. In the first place, you cannot entirely eliminate spillovers. If the British Government does things with its tax policy, it will affect the prosperity of France to some extent. France is a big trade partner; if we impoverish ourselves, it will suffer. The search completely to insulate your policy against a neighbour’s policy is a mirage or wild goose chase. However, you should structure arrangements to minimise spillovers and to ensure that, as far as is possible, risks are allocated in the right place.
Can you highlight the effects of the current proposals on how risk is shared and on accountability?
There is an interim arrangement for which there is nothing to be said. It is totally indefensible—I do not know why anyone would even contemplate having it. I would junk it straight away. I can give you chapter and verse on that, if you would like.
We will come on to the transitional arrangements.
Under the interim arrangement, the Scottish authorities will not reap the benefits of their actions or pay for the consequences of their mistakes. Because, in effect, the deduction from the block grant will be indexed to your tax base, you will be able to do whatever you like to the tax base and be compensated in the block grant. You do not want to do that. The incentives in the arrangement are all wrong. It is also unnecessary. I cannot see what useful purpose it serves if you structure the system properly, especially given the smoothing arrangements for tax revenue that are built into the bill.
Part of your submission, which covers that general area, deals with the issue of deflationary bias. You engaged in at least part of the debate that is going on.
I do not have an exact figure, but although it is very probably true that simple Barnett would have given you somewhat more revenue in the past eight years than what is currently proposed, it is absolutely predictable that what is proposed will give you more money than Barnett in the next 10 years. That may be one reason why the Treasury wants to impose this intermediate nonsense on you: to stop that happening.
But, given that the general direction of taxes throughout the developed world is to move away from income taxes—direct taxes—to indirect taxes, how would the proposals affect us in the end? If general taxation continues to rise, but the share of it that comes from income tax—let alone the individual levels—is smaller, would we end up with a smaller amount of money to spend because we are reliant on a tax that will be proportionately smaller in the overall tax take?
There are two separate points. First, I would again be cautious about extrapolating from a particular historical experience. After the second world war the top rate of income tax in the UK was 96 per cent, and we did not have a value added tax. It is pretty clear that in 50 years we have moved from direct tax to indirect tax. Now, the basic rate is at 20p and VAT is at 20 per cent. How much further do you think that tendency will go? I do not think it safe to assume that the trend will continue to move in the same direction. It may be—
There has been a steady rise in VAT. There was a temporary blip when it went back from 17.5 to 15 per cent, but it is now at 20 per cent.
But would you forecast that income tax would be at 10p and VAT would be at 30p in 10 or 20 years’ time?
The base of VAT could be broadened and it could be put on things such as children’s clothing and food. Any Government that wants to do so can continue the direction of travel, not necessarily just by using the main lever but by changing the tax base itself.
I absolutely accept that. As I have said, you cannot assume that indirect taxes will continue to rise at the expense of direct taxes, although that might happen to some extent. However, I also point out that the Scottish Government’s revenue comes from two sources: taxation and a block grant. The block grant is structured around expenditure, which means that if the UK Government continues to switch money from direct to indirect taxes any extra expenditure will—as long as the money is spent—be reflected in the allocation via the Barnett formula. You are pointing not to an absolute squeeze on the total level of Scottish resources but to what is certainly a possibility that over time the grant will grow in importance relative to taxation.
If a higher proportion of money comes from the block grant instead of taxation, will that not have the same sort of gearing effect that has made it very difficult for local government to make autonomous decisions? After all, to raise an additional 1 per cent of finance, it has to raise council tax by 5 per cent.
Yes. Of course, under the bill, only 20 per cent of revenue will come from taxation. If you wish to increase revenue, you can have very exciting-looking percentages of the tax take.
It is true that, at the international level, there was significant pressure particularly on top income tax rates and marginal rates for top income earners have been brought down to manageable levels.
Can you spell out for those of us who are not economists what you mean by “elasticity”?
Elasticity is how a tax increases relative to its tax base. The tax base of the personal income tax is a big chunk of GDP—another part is, of course, corporate income, which is not included—and given that personal income is more or less increasing in line with GDP, it can be related to GDP growth.
I agree that there are a number of considerations around progressivity and ensuring that the income tax take does not increase with income.
What are the lessons from Canada?
I am in general agreement. Even if it is true that the share of income tax and all taxes will go down in the UK until 2020, that does not vitiate the choice that has been put in front of the committee by the Scotland Bill. Income tax is still the most proper tax to initiate devolution of taxation power in Scotland.
But there are alternatives. A basket of taxes could be used. The assumption is being made that income tax is the only option. If there were a basket of taxes, the total tax base could be reflected, rather than just the income tax base. That would address the problem of whether there was a differential between direct and indirect taxes.
If you are to start something, the one to start with is income tax, in my opinion. That is not to say that you will not do something else 10 years from now, but let us demonstrate to the Scottish people that you can administer or manage one tax properly and then go on to a second one—the one that is most related to current spending. That is the perspective that I would advance.
Why do you suggest two stages, starting with a fixed sum—the surcharge—and the 10p—
I am not suggesting that, but I am saying that such an arrangement would give you flexibility. You would be allowed to modulate which group you targeted. If you believe that Scotland should be a millionaires’ paradise, you do not target the rich; if you want to go the other way, that will be the policy choice. Right now, if you go from 10p to 11p—we are obviously discussing tax increases, although tax decreases are of course nicer to sell—everybody goes up by 1p. There is no choice right now—an increase from 10p to 11p would be reflected on everybody. Flexibility is always preferable in tax policy.
I am mindful of the time. We should move on from income tax to corporation tax.
I was going to try to widen things out, convener.
I would never recommend doing that.
In Germany, we have only a tendency towards broadening the share—I include VAT, corporate income tax and other smaller taxes in that. We do that because we mistrust sharing one single tax; instead, we have structural divergence. I have seen that done in other countries, too. Once you go for value added tax or corporate tax, you need an allocation formula, the basis of which is the number of inhabitants. That takes you back to the Barnett formula. In a way—if you wished it to be so—the Barnett formula could be a tax plus borrowing share mechanism. It would be relatively appropriate to do that, as Barnett links to the functions that are devolved to Scotland. You already have a mix; we are not talking about income tax on its own.
I think we need a bigger basket.
Bernd says that there are more taxes in Germany, but they are just assigned—the devolved authorities do not have the ability to alter the tax rates. There are difficulties with VAT, for example, in that European legislation places a restriction on having different VAT rates in a given jurisdiction, but also because variations can lead to smuggling and huge trade distortions. It is all too easy to buy kit somewhere and move it somewhere else. There are big problems in that regard. If you want to have the power to alter rates, you really want to look for taxes where the base is fairly immobile. As I understand it, that is very much what you want to do. Your ability to alter VAT rates is negligible—forget it—whereas your ability to alter income tax rates, particularly basic rates, is fairly substantial.
But you suggested discussions on the matter in your report. We will come to how the Canadians manage it in a minute.
Yes. We produced a scheme that we said that the devolved authorities should have the ability to opt for, but we did not say that they should opt for it—that is a political decision. It is a good example of the general trade-off that you face. If you maximise your freedom of action—which you generally want to do—you also run a lot more risk. If you are happy with a £0.5 billion fluctuation in your budget and having to give up several hundred million pounds to stimulate business, there you are. It is not free, if you see what I am saying. You buy your increased freedom of action with a lot more instability of revenue and a lot more risk being run.
Surely everyone has told you that that could be addressed in the same way that volatility around income tax is going to be addressed: through appropriate borrowing during the cycle.
In principle, but there would be much more volatility. The problem is not different; it is just of a different order of magnitude.
The scale of corporation tax is not quite the same as that of income tax. It would depend on what proportion of that tax was devolved. If it was all devolved, what you imply would be correct, but only part of it might be devolved.
The expert group highlighted the volatility to the Calman commission. It is probably the most volatile of all the major taxes that could be devolved. There is also the issue of tax competition. We reviewed some evidence from Switzerland that showed that, where there is competition on corporation tax, there has been a race towards matching lower rates of corporation tax and a shift from corporate taxation to personal income taxation. That perhaps flies in the face of what we are trying to achieve, which is assigning revenue to maintain some level of similar expenditure on public services.
The UK Government is considering corporation tax flexibility in Northern Ireland at the moment. If the Northern Ireland Assembly is permitted to set its own corporation tax, why do you argue so strongly against that in Scotland?
If the Northern Ireland Assembly were allowed to do so, you would have a strong case for having the same facility. However, if I were a betting man—which I am—I would lay you fairly attractive odds against the Government ever allowing that. It has just promised to consider the possibility; I do not think that it is going to agree to it.
The evidence that we received from the Exchequer Secretary to the Treasury and from Michael Moore, the Secretary of State for Scotland, was that the Government does not rule out the possibility of doing it. Michael Moore suggested that Northern Ireland is a different kettle of fish altogether. I did not get the impression, from our discussions with both ministers, that a separate corporation tax in Northern Ireland has been ruled out. If that has not been ruled out, would you say that the Scottish Parliament must be able to set corporation tax in Scotland if we are not to be at a disadvantage to Northern Ireland?
That is the point. If the Northern Ireland Assembly were given the ability to reduce corporation tax in Northern Ireland, it would be explicitly because the UK Government thought that the need for economic development in Northern Ireland was greater than in the rest of the UK. If corporation tax were to be used as an instrument of regional policy, bigger cuts would be allowed in poorer parts of the country, so Northern Ireland and Wales would get to cut corporation tax by more than Scotland because their income per head is a lot lower than Scotland’s.
However, south-east England—
That area would not be allowed to cut at all.
Let me finish my point. Of course that area would not be allowed to cut at all. Income per head in south-east England is far higher than that in Scotland. We would be at a positive disadvantage if Northern Ireland and Wales were allowed to cut corporation tax but we were not.
That is the point—those areas would be trying to put you at a disadvantage. That is discrimination in favour of the poorest areas, so of course it involves discriminating against everybody else. That is the policy’s whole point.
If income across regions is to be compared, it should be real income. After correcting for price levels, the same difference will not always be yielded.
That leaves on the table the question of provincial corporate tax.
That is it—I am saying that devolution is not needed to achieve the result that I described.
Nobody suggests that using just one taxation measure is the key to economic growth; a basket of measures would be involved. That is one reason why some of us suggest that a range of taxes should be available. Even if we relied on one tax, several other measures—some of which you just highlighted—could be used. For example, some of the money that was raised could be spent. The basket of measures would help.
I understood that Professor Spahn said in his opening remarks that what matters is how policies are applied—whether to spending or taxation. It has been implied that growth is impacted by how policies are applied, not by the fact that they exist. Devolution of the powers of itself would not give rise to economic growth; that would result from investing in roads, education or whatever. Is that correct?
As some of our colleagues around the table have said, the greater the flexibility, the more accountability and the better the opportunities to address issues. Policy decisions on spending will also stimulate growth, if that is the choice. A policy driver or series of policy drivers is required to make that happen.
Is that not just one possible tool? You do not give enough credit to the tax competition restrictions and other restrictions that would apply, even if Scotland were independent, never mind part of the union. It is reasonably clear that tax bases cannot be moved all that much without introducing administrative complexities or arrangements under which the total tax take across the United Kingdom is less. Those issues have been touched on.
But there is historical evidence to suggest that the current unitary arrangements have led to differential growth in the UK—and it has certainly not been to Scotland’s advantage.
I want to comment on historical evidence and Northern Ireland corporation tax. Professor McLean presented evidence last week. He said that Northern Ireland had the capacity to set corporation tax between 1920 and 1972, and it proved to be a tax avoiders charter. If I recall his evidence correctly, he mentioned the Vestey family, who have had a remarkably successful record in avoiding paying UK taxes and were particularly good at exploiting the situation—legitimately, I may add, as I do not wish to libel the Vestey family. Will Professor Holtham or others comment on that aspect? Was that looked at in the context of your discussions vis-à-vis Wales, and how could the issue be addressed?
You might have differential rates of corporation tax either as a matter of regional policy or, more likely, because you devolve corporation tax—although the trouble with doing it centrally is that there are all sorts of issues with European Union legislation. Either way, if you have differential rates of corporation tax, you have to make it clear that the rate of tax depends on the economic activity in the area and not where the company puts its brass plate or where its head office is, which are irrelevant. At the very least, you have to use the proportion of the payroll that is paid to people in the area, although there are more complicated formulas, which are used in the United States for example, that look at turnover and where capital investment has taken place. You have to make it clear that if a company is going to enjoy a lower rate of corporation tax, it is because it has activities in the area and not simply because it sites an office there.
I am very anxious to move on, so this is the absolute final word on corporation tax.
We should not necessarily look at varying tax rates for corporate tax. That is the issue, and it could be a nuisance in the union. In Germany, we have a single tax but the tax base is allocated to the states on the basis of payroll. That makes a state interested in attracting payrolls. Since the war, Bavaria has attracted businesses based on payroll, which are the modern services. It has had remarkable development, even though the tax rate has been uniform. You should not forget that, if you have a formula for allocating the tax base among regions, it can help to stimulate certain activities.
Thank you. We will move on to grant reduction. We have already heard from Gerry Holtham some outline of the Holtham commission proposal for a proportionate reduction. Professor Boadway made a different suggestion last week—I know that some of you have had the opportunity to read the evidence. Finally, there is the proposal in the UK white paper promising no detriment. We are trying to explore whether that is right. What about the indexation of the thresholds? How should the plan be developed, and where should it be negotiated on an on-going basis?
We did not propose a mechanism in our report but, having had the benefit of the Holtham commission’s work, my view is that you should try to insulate Scotland from any changes in the tax base that take place at UK level and, as Gerry suggested earlier, that you should therefore look at ways of indexing the adjustment to changes in the UK tax base. That would take account of the fact that if the UK Government started to play around with thresholds or allowances, that would be reflected in a modification.
What would be the problem with using the adjustments to the UK tax base and not just the UK income tax base? I presume that using the UK tax base would address my concern about shift from direct to indirect taxes, which other people have suggested might be sorted because the grant would go up. Why not use the total tax base?
That takes us back to the points that were made about how, to some extent, the grant implicitly picks up some of the other spending decisions at UK level. If I understood you correctly, you are concerned about what would happen if there were a switch from direct to indirect taxation. That would be picked up by the sort of indexation mechanism that Gerry Holtham has suggested.
Yes. If we think about it, what Brian Adam suggested would work against the devolved authority, because, for example, if the UK Government switched from direct to indirect taxation it might define the tax base as a whole as unchanged, which would not help you at all, whereas if it reduced the income tax base it would have to increase your grant. Income tax is what is devolved; therefore that is what is threatened if the Government alters the base in some way. You can build in automatic compensation via the block grant, so that if the Government messes with the income tax base it can be corrected. It is better for the devolved authority to index to the same tax base that is devolved; that protects you from that tax base being manipulated.
There is no perfect solution—I said that in a more general sense in the context of income tax. I presume that most systems have to make more structural changes to the grant formula from time to time, as oddities occur and are built in over five, 10 or 15 years. I would appreciate hearing about the international experience in that regard.
In Canada we are much nastier than that. The federal Government will change a tax base by introducing tax expenditures or increasing the personal exemption and that is it—the provinces adjust. If you want more revenue, given the change in tax base, you just have to increase your tax rate. You might want to say that there is an implicit contract, whereby eventually the equalisation grants will be adjusted, but that is certainly not explicit. There is no indexing, no relationship, no formula. There are examples—1972 and 1977 are very good ones, but there are others—of the federal Government just saying, “Sorry. For my purpose, I need to do this.” Alternatively, if the tax base has increased and there has been a desire to reduce tax rates, it has said, “Go ahead.”
It would solve most of the problems.
Yes, there is no arguing over that. It is a clean-cut and clear solution. I think that it is a wonderful and very original idea.
It does not solve the problem, but it has the advantage of reducing the problem of the initial estimate that the UK Government makes about what the Scottish tax base is worth. If that is cyclically distorted—if it is too high or too low because Scotland is at an unusual cyclical point—and the UK Government does not give you enough or it gives you too much, as long as the Scottish economy is in the same cycle as the rest of the UK, as the UK recovers or comes off the boom or whatever, its tax base will change and that will be fed back automatically via the indexation. To some extent, that will offset any errors in the initial calculation of what the Scottish tax base is worth.
Let us move on to short-term borrowing. We might come back to the transition mechanism, but I am keen that the borrowing issues get an airing.
The short-term direct borrowing proposal is probably motivated by the desire to smooth the tax developments. The mechanism that is proposed is a smoothing mechanism because the income tax would not be handed over month by month as it was collected; it would be provided on the basis of a forecast, which would be made in advance and put into the Scottish budget. On the basis of that budgeted amount of money, Scotland would get contributions from central Government. After the event, there would be a reconciliation based on the taxes that were actually collected. That mechanism is found in Scandinavian countries. I have met it in Denmark and Sweden, and it works fine to mitigate the vagaries of the business cycle. Therefore, I think that once such a mechanism is in place, there is less of a need for short-term borrowing for tax smoothing.
Is it not true that the current arrangements would mean that we would use up more than the current capacity? The gap for this year is bigger than the capacity that is available over a four or five-year cycle. The overall capacity to borrow to meet short-term needs appears to be inadequate.
Do I understand your question correctly if I say that it is a matter of who does the forecast and whether we have a forecast for the Scottish economy that is separate from that for the rest of the economy? A regional forecast would, of course, take care of the matter. You say that Scotland’s cycle is always a bit behind events. That gives you information on what happened in England last year and you make your own forecast, as the Treasury does its forecast. If that is the core of your question, then the answer is to make different forecasts for different regions.
I will support what Bernd Spahn said. Forecasting for two, three or four years out, especially over the last period, would have led to very erroneous forecasts. Why not introduce a system of more rolling forecasts, which I think would be better? What Mr Adam said is absolutely correct. We need to look at the proposed size of the mechanism, because if such a system had been in place over the past couple of years, it would not have provided enough finance. It needs to be big enough to handle most situations, which would have nothing to do with mistakes made by the Scottish Government but would simply be the result of a cycle. It would need to be adjusted.
Do you also agree that we need to know something about Scottish cycles as well as UK cycles and at least have an evidence base on that?
More work for economists in Scotland—I am sure that he will agree.
If you looked at the calculations in the paper that was submitted by, I think, the UK Government, I am sure that you could go back and trace how they compared to some of the forecasts. We presented some work on forecast income tax versus actual, where you can see that there are certain divergences. You could therefore pretty quickly find out what the size of the short-term borrowing requirement would need to be.
It is a mystery to me why short-term borrowing cannot be above £500 million—perhaps someone can explain that. What is more important, however, is that we are talking pessimistically about borrowing. Let us assume that things go well: you will have a surplus because your forecast for income tax money will be lower than the realised sum. What happens to the surplus? Do you keep it, or does it roll over at the end of the year to Westminster? If I understand it, rolling over is currently allowed, but it is not a right of the Scottish Parliament. When it is your money, however, how will you differentiate it from the grant? One of the normal consequences would be that, at the end of any year, any surplus—whatever the source; it will be commingled and the source will be impossible to identify—should be kept by the Scottish Parliament to spend. You should build up your own cash reserve, which should not be part of the Westminster Administration. That is very important.
Absolutely. If you got that done, it would be not just a matter of detail but a radical change. Once the Westminster Government had voted the money it would be yours. It would go into an account somewhere and the UK Government would not be able to claw it back. If you do not do that, you run into the problem that François Vaillancourt pointed out, which is that if you underspend on grant money, Westminster can take it back—but how do you tell grant money from tax money?
If there was an underspend in the first two parliamentary sessions, the end-year flexibility was retained by the Treasury and released only with its agreement, because it wished to have some say on how the money was spent, so I sympathise with your point. It is not quite as rigid as that now but, nevertheless, the Treasury retains an element of control.
It would be an important juridical advance if you could secure that.
Would it be useful to have research on the economic cycle in Scotland and how it relates to the UK cycle? Would that help with building in a forecasting mechanism?
Yes, and research on forecast errors, too. Absolutely.
It is not as important as you might think. The Danish municipalities do not necessarily make an economic forecast of the activities in their jurisdiction. They make a budget forecast of what they expect the revenue to be. How do they do that? It is probably done very much out of their thumbs. As long as they have an autocorrective mechanism, they will not overstate the requirement. They know that, if they do that, they will get the money this year, but next year they will be in debt to the central Government. Anticipating that, they try to gear the revenue according to their needs on the expenditure side.
We will move on to capital borrowing. People might have things to say about the transition mechanism at the end, if we have time to discuss it, but I think that the capital borrowing side is much more significant to the committee’s deliberations.
Again, my first remark is that the UK Government has produced a number, but it was sucked out of its thumb. I do not know where it came from. It seems to me that the right consideration is to say that the capital allocation within the Barnett grant is at least partly financed by UK-level borrowing, so the additional borrowing that it is legitimate for Scotland to make is the capital expenditure that it wants to make over and above that capital allocation, and that will now be underpinned by its own tax capability.
Of personal income taxation.
It is a matter for you, but you might decide that you would not want to spend more than 5 per cent of taxes on debt servicing. If taxes are worth £5 billion, 5 per cent of that is £250 million, so you would not want to spend more than that. If the interest rate is 5 per cent, you get to £5 billion.
It may explain how we got to £5 billion, being £3 billion plus £2 billion.
I agree, except that, as Gerry Holtham pointed out, the £3 billion is the part that comes from the grant allocation. That suggests that £2 billion is a bit of an underestimate and you might want to give the Scottish Parliament more room for manoeuvre. If the calculation gets you to around £5 billion, whatever the serviceability calculation, that is what it should be. It should not be based on some other, exogenous element.
In connection with that, very shortly £1 billion a year will go to service off-balance-sheet borrowing for private finance initiative/public-private partnership projects. What influence would that level of debt repayment have on the Government’s capacity to borrow for the future?
As I understand it, that is Barnettable. In other words, if the UK Government is spending on PFI deals money that is coming out of current expenditure because the deal is treated like a lease or something, Scotland gets its share of that when the spending is in devolved areas. Whether your own PFI is higher or lower than what Barnett would give you, I do not know.
It is higher. Scotland made a lot of decisions about how it was going to finance things that meant that we chose, as a proportion of our income, to have rather more such deals. Obviously that has implications, unless there is a mechanism to correct it.
Government bond issuance is genuinely cheaper than doing PFI, but if you have these long-term liabilities you would prudently take them into account when deciding how much of your budget or tax receipts you want to devote to debt service.
On this issue, and comparing a devolved Scottish Government raising money by issuing bonds with the UK Treasury doing the same, is it the experience in countries with federal systems that the cost of borrowing is higher for the subnational Government? If we had a bond-issuing capacity, would we end up paying more for it than the UK Treasury would for raising the same money, which we could presumably then borrow from the UK Treasury? Is that the case?
We got a couple of investment bankers in and said, “We’re the Welsh Government and we want to issue a bond. How much will you charge us?” They said, “45 over gilt.” Scotland might be a little more creditworthy than Wales—say you are 40 basis points over gilt. In general, if you issue your own bonds you will pay slightly more. What I found very surprising was that the Debt Management Office is extremely accommodating. If you go to it and say, “I want to borrow at six and three quarter years,” it will not issue a six-and-three-quarter-year gilt, but it will lend you at six and three quarter years and will then issue five and 10-year gilts and it will take the risk of the mismatch between its loan to you and the loan in the market. It will also lend to you at fixed rate or floating rate or through sinker or vanilla bonds. It would be unusual for you to find it a better deal to issue your own bonds. If you want to be able to do that for demonstration purposes, that is fine, but generally speaking, financially, you would not do better than borrowing through the DMO.
Is there any macroeconomic reason why the Scottish Government should not have bond-issuing powers, in terms of the UK’s borrowing, bursting limits and all that sort of stuff?
No. Once you set a limit, whether you borrow through the DMO or issue the bonds yourself should not be a matter of concern to the UK macroeconomic authority. However, you would be paying for vanity if you issued your own bonds at this point.
On that point, one of the bits of evidence that we got last week was that rather than having an agreed cash limit for borrowing in relation to bonds, you would let the market dictate how much of a risk it reckoned you were. That would price you out at a certain point because you would not be able to afford to issue bonds at the rates required or to cover the risk. Is that a reasonable alternative to a limit?
No. The markets price you out when you are already bankrupt. Just look at the situation—you simply cannot rely on them to react in time. Indeed, they will not react until they want to kill you.
As Gerry Holtham said, it is always difficult for the market to genuinely assess the risk and, with subnational Governments, there is always the implicit feeling that national Government will come in with a bailout, which artificially depresses the interest rate on such bonds.
The national evidence from Canada and the US suggests that borrowing is more expensive for provinces or states than it is for the central Government. Moreover, those bodies have no access to a central bank and are rated not triple A but double A plus or whatever. However, we do use the market. I realise that this might be a bit too close to issues that are going on in Europe at the moment, but I have to point out that there are no bankrupt provinces in Canada. In any case, I would be cautious about generalising from the experience of borrowing by Portugal or Greece, which are sovereign not subnational countries. Some US states are in bad shape, but they are trying to correct themselves. The US federal Government provided a partial, temporary bailout of the state budget, but that is being phased out—indeed, this is the last year—and we will see the real impact next year. However, the reaction over there has been, “Well, we’ll do this,” and, as I said, the provinces have borrowed with no problem. That said, I agree that the amounts involved are not in themselves a justification and, if the UK is giving a share of taxation powers to a subnational Government and the Scottish Parliament, that Government and Parliament should have a share of access to the market.
Both.
Then if the tax revenues are 20 per cent of your budget and the grant 80 per cent, I suggest that £200 million of that £1 billion be charged to the borrowing capacity associated with the devolved tax. After all, the decision on this spending was taken before the tax was devolved. If the grant that would have entirely financed that spending will be reduced, you will have to correct the borrowing capacity off your tax revenue and go with the remainder.
The whole point of PFI and PPP was to take these things off balance sheet. Of course, such a choice is no longer realistic. Nevertheless, the market pricing mechanism for the system was above the Public Works Loan Board rate and, in some of the early projects, there was considerable concern about what that rate was. For most, the term of the debt was 30 years; the peak repayment for servicing it is coming up quite soon—I cannot recall the exact year, but it is in the foreseeable future—but it will amount to £1 billion a year and will take some time to work its way through. That said, we will establish some creditworthiness or capacity to borrow against that should we either go to the market directly or issue bonds.
Given the time that we had, we have not done that badly in flagging up all the issues that we wanted to cover. Perhaps we should use the last couple of minutes to allow our expert witnesses to put on the agenda issues that they have not had the chance to mention and, more important, to allow our members to ask certain questions that they want to raise with the witnesses.
There has been and will be a lot of negotiation between the UK and Scottish Governments on the effects on and changes to the grant mechanism and whether there will be any detriment in that respect. Can Professor Holtham in particular tell us how robust the intergovernmental arrangements are and whether they provide equality of arms and allow a kind of principled decision-making process on outstanding disputes—of which there will be many, as there always are in these situations?
I do not think that the arrangements are very robust. Other people have correctly said that there is still a perception in the bureaucracy in Whitehall that the devolved authorities are just like other Government departments and that they can be treated as such. That mindset still exists. As part of the process of changing that mindset, it would be good to have slightly more formalised dispute resolution mechanisms.
We have also discussed the issue with the Office for National Statistics. It is interesting that the second tier is not in the national or public sector accounts. The fact that devolved authorities are being treated like a central Government department does not show up in the statistics—or it shows up in them, but what you want is a second tier: this is central Government, this is regional government and this is local government. We have been told that that is easy to do; it is simply a matter of political will.
As far as the Office for National Statistics is concerned, it is also a question of budgets. However, I agree that there ought to be a third tier of government in the UK, and it ought to be in the national accounts.
My question is simple. Is there a link between the decentralisation of revenues and improved economic growth? Is there any evidence of that link? Is there evidence that one follows the other?
As Bernd Spahn said earlier, no. There is no evidence relating to decentralisation and economic growth that really stands the test of time. One paper will say that there is no link, one will say that there is, another will say, “I’m not sure,” and a fourth will say, “This way I get it; this other way, I don’t.” I refereed a paper last week on that issue, which cited all the literature. There were three paragraphs, for the yeas, the nos and the don’t knows, and around four or five studies on each.
Your positive examples were based on the decentralisation of expenditure and the expenditure decisions that would be taken by a subnational Government in relation to transportation, education and so on. I do not want to put words in your mouth, but I think that the live issue is about the decentralisation of tax-raising powers, because we already have significant decentralisation anyway.
If decentralisation had an impact on growth, that would be where the most likely channel would be to target taxation better. It is difficult to say that the way in which the decentralisation of expenditure is being discussed now would not make sense. If you are willing to have decentralised corporate income tax and allow a race to the bottom so that Scotland becomes a haven for people who move here because the rest of the UK has a higher corporation tax rate, you might buy false growth, until someone else does the same thing. Think of Ireland.
There is absolutely no statistical relationship between fiscal autonomy and growth, nor can there be. If you look at the range of variables that influence that relationship, you can see that all you have to do is change the data slightly and you will get a different result.
There is some casual empiricism. I usually give the examples of Lorraine in France, Saar in Germany and Wallonie in Belgium, which were all problem areas after the second world war, and compare them with Luxembourg, which did not have anyone to help it out, so it had to be inventive and generate something new to make its economy survive. Luxembourg totally restructured its economy after the second world war, whereas those other regions, which were in a comparable situation before the war, did not, because they knew that their national Governments would bail them out.
Changing taxation could conceivably make a contribution to economic growth. Taxation is distortional and discourages people, but it gives you money to do things such as put in place infrastructure. You have to balance the two sides and try to find an optimal level of taxation.
I thank the witnesses for coming to today’s meeting. I much appreciate the fact that some of you have travelled long distances. It is unfortunate that not everyone who was invited felt able to come, perhaps for understandable reasons, but I appreciate the effort that you have made. I have found your evidence stimulating.
What you say is true of the interim arrangement. I argue that indexing the grant reduction to the Scottish tax base introduces a strong bias. People have expressed scepticism—they may be right to do so—about the extent to which moderate changes in taxes impact on the base, but at least we know the direction. If you put up tax, the base will not grow relative to the way in which it would otherwise have grown; if anything, it will do nothing or will shrink a bit. If grant reduction is indexed to the base, I do not care if my base shrinks when tax is put up, because that shrinkage is covered by the fact that I will be paid a bigger grant. If I do things the other way round and cut tax, I take a hit on my revenue, in the hope that that will generate more activity and a bigger base—too bad, chum, because if the base increases, the grant deduction will increase with it, because the deduction is indexed to the base. That means that there is a bias in favour of raising rather than lowering taxes.
That is the essence of some of the Cuthberts’ evidence, which suggests that, paradoxically, the UK Treasury would benefit from any rise in growth that was produced by a cut, along with other measures, but the Scottish budget would shrink.
That is true only under the interim arrangement. Under the long-term arrangement, you do not need to worry too much about any rise in growth that benefits the UK—unless you really hate it—because, basically, you are benefiting yourselves. Under that arrangement, the two things are compatible. If you cut tax and grow the base, the UK will get a bit of the benefit, because it shares the base, but you will also get benefit. Only the interim arrangement is completely pernicious.
To clarify, the Cuthberts’ point was a little different, because it was not to do with the grant reduction; it was to do with the response of income tax take to different changes, which is almost a Laffer curve effect. In essence, it was to do with the elasticity of the response.
All our experts have said that personal income tax is the place to start in giving the Parliament more fiscal responsibility, but every single one of you has expressed concern about some of the mechanisms, such as that on borrowing, and some of the analysis that the UK Government has—or has not—done. There seems to be a suggestion that the limit of £2.2 billion on borrowing has been plucked out of thin air.
If you forced me to choose, I would choose making the grant reduction mechanism robust in relation to changes in the income tax base in the UK and removing the transition period. That is the highest priority, because otherwise the measures will cause a lot of resentment and potential conflict. Fixing that would take out a lot of the conflict and would create an adjustment mechanism that was acceptable and transparent at the outset. However, a close second priority would be setting proper limits on the borrowing requirements.
My first choice would be the same as Anton Muscatelli’s. My second choice would be to ensure that you keep the money over years, so that you can build up a reserve and it no longer goes back to the Westminster budget. The commingling argument is the way in which to get the Treasury to agree, because it will be unable to distinguish where the money comes from once the system has been implemented. That is important for long-term responsibility. If people can take away your money on a whim, that does not make any sense.
I will be greedy—there are three things that I would do. One is the same as Anton Muscatelli’s suggestion: get the budget offset mechanism right. That is fairly simple and I do not think that you will get a lot of hassle from the Treasury about that, because what is it to the Treasury? I believe that the Treasury will do that. I also suggest getting rid of the interim measures, although I do not know whether the Treasury will do that.
I have nothing to add. I share those priorities.
I thank our witnesses for their evidence. Perhaps one evidence session follows another, because we invested a large amount of time last week trying to establish whether in the academic literature there is a robust academic base for the link between fiscal decentralisation and growth, and we have certainly heard some definitive evidence on that from the witnesses today.
I am pleased to welcome to the next part of our meeting Sir Kenneth Calman, the former chairman of the Calman Commission on Scottish Devolution, and Iain McMillan, a former member of the commission. Does either of you have any short opening remarks?
It was a privilege to chair the Commission on Scottish Devolution, and I am delighted that a bill has been introduced as a result. Our remit was set by the Scottish Parliament. An amendment to the remit—that the commission should consider independence—was defeated, although I would have been delighted to develop that topic had it been included. The process began with no fixed agenda; it grew from evidence received, visits, meetings, submissions and so on. An interim report was prepared and widely distributed. It was the people of Scotland who generated the agenda and I am grateful to all who contributed. The report’s conclusions were unanimous.
I do not want to add too much because I echo in every respect what Sir Kenneth said. Unlike him, I have contributed to the debate from time to time on behalf of the CBI, but not as a member of the Calman commission. As he said, the commission has not met since we reported in June 2009. I simply add that I am pleased that the committee has invited Sir Kenneth and me to be here today. We are very happy to assist the committee and will answer your questions as well as we can.
Thank you. I will kick off the questioning. In light of the remarks that you have both made, I invite you to comment in a personal capacity, given that the commission has not met for a year or 15 months.
I was impressed at how many of the recommendations were in the bill. Having been through a similar process with reports in another place, I thought that that was important.
I want to come in on that point. I recognise that not all the recommendations in the Calman report need legislative powers, but do you have a figure for how many of them have not been taken forward? You have mentioned a few.
I do not think that I do. Some of them, of course, do not need to be taken through the bill—they must go through the Scottish Parliament, so it is not for the bill to handle them.
I cannot give a figure, but I can cite a number of the recommendations in terms of required legislation. The aggregates tax and the air passenger duty, for example, were not taken forward in the bill, although the UK Government said that when the European judgment in respect of aggregates taxes is through it hopes to devolve that one. The policy in respect of air passenger duty still has to be developed and agreed, and something may happen there.
My reading of the bill suggests that many of the things that are not in it will be picked up in a number of different places, as Iain McMillan said. It seems entirely appropriate for this scrutiny committee to continue to keep an eye on that; indeed, so should the Scottish Parliament.
Thank you for that. The reason that I ask about the recommendations—I am well aware that not all of them need legislative powers—is that, when I asked the Secretary of State for Scotland that question, he could not tell me. I had hoped that you would be able to give me a more definitive response, but it seems that neither party can.
I thought that Iain McMillan gave you quite a full response, did he not?
He certainly gave me a full response on some of the recommendations, but not a number.
It is entirely proper that this scrutiny committee picks that up and makes that point.
I agree, although I have a slight reservation. It would depend on what replaced APD. It could well lend itself to devolution, but if it did not meet the criteria that Calman set regarding the immobility of such taxes, there may be a case for reviewing that. Certainly, however, our default position would be to support the devolution of that duty if at all possible.
It would be exactly the same for the aggregates tax. I think that the Scottish Parliament should have a role in that process. Once the European legislation is clear, there will be an opportunity to consider devolving it.
Thank you for that response. I was going to come on to the aggregates levy. When Calman made that recommendation, the issue was already being considered by the European Commission. In essence, nothing has changed. The Commission is continuing to make its recommendation, and I happen to know that it should go ahead.
I do not have a problem with the committee doing that, although any timescale will depend on one or two other things, such as how speedily the European Union gets through its issues. Air passenger duty could be put on the table but, as Iain McMillan says, the point is to ensure that the principle of devolving it remains appropriate. If so, the answer is yes.
In the previous evidence session, I was struck by the comment that one or two people made, that there is an air of the Scottish spending being a sort of Westminster departmental spending—that that is the way in which the Treasury views it. In the context of borrowing limits, how the grant is worked out and other things, there will be a number of areas in which there will be negotiation, discussion, judgment and the application of principles. I have two questions on that. First, in retrospect, do you think that the principles of dispute resolution—the joint ministerial arrangements and so on that were worked out in the Calman commission—are adequate or do they need to be developed? Secondly, particularly on the question of the borrowing powers, do you think that the principles have been sufficiently identified, as opposed to a figure having been plucked out of the air for the capital and smoothing borrowing powers?
The discussion on borrowing powers that you have just had was extremely helpful. If I was convener of the committee, I would want to pick up on it, clarify it and go back to something that might be more definitive than the figure. That would be a helpful thing to do.
The point was about the mechanisms for resolving disputes. Is it not a case of the UK Government saying to the Scottish Parliament, “This is it on the grant, and this is it on the borrowing power. End of story”? Should there be more scope for manoeuvre?
There needs to be scope for manoeuvre. The question is whether writing down complicated ways for people to talk to each other is a way forward. Sometimes that is about people, and part of the Calman report was about the respect agenda. The two Parliaments and Governments need to respect one another, and if there is an issue about the borrowing powers or how things work financially, they need to get together. You can write anything you like to try to make mechanisms stronger, but people have to want them to work. Collaboration is as important as what is written in the bill.
Is there an issue with the development of the principles? I have the idea that there are golden rules, if you like, that surround the question of how much we could borrow, how far that could go before it interfered with the UK’s macroeconomic role, and how we would deal with issues that could be detrimental to the Scottish budget and ones that are not. Obviously there are lots of judgments to be made Do you think—having heard the earlier witnesses—that there is scope for development of the principles that have to be applied?
There might be, and I will let Iain McMillan pick up on that. The only other seemingly relevant point in the earlier discussion was that many financial issues are about changing the governance of Scotland and how it operates. That is the bit that matters. What is the policy going to be? Finance will support the policy, but if you do not have the right policies, the governance of Scotland will not change. Sometimes we need to consider policy development as much as the way in which the money flows.
That is absolutely right. When I read the command paper, I got the sense that there is a genuine will to be collegiate about resolving disputes and differences. Indeed, the command paper mentions a taxation committee of UK Government ministers and Scottish Government ministers getting together and resolving all sorts of issues, such as changes to the tax base, which is an obvious issue that was discussed during the earlier part of the meeting.
In his opening remarks, Sir Kenneth referred to Mr McMillan being the director of the CBI. For the sake of clarity, Mr McMillan, can you confirm that you were on the Calman commission in a personal capacity, and that you are appearing today in a personal capacity as a former member of the commission rather than as a director of the CBI?
That is absolutely right. I was on the commission as an individual, and I am here with Sir Kenneth in my capacity as a commission member.
That is on the record. There is now no confusion.
I will make a brief response before I ask Iain McMillan to comment. You put the question to the previous panel: Anton Muscatelli’s response was pretty straightforward. It was the response that we got as we discussed it in the commission. We decided not to recommend devolving corporation tax at that point.
We looked at our terms of reference and the evidence that came before us. The commission tried to strike the right balance between improving the financial accountability of the Scottish Parliament and Scottish Government and ensuring that arrangements are in place to continue stability. We looked at the balance between a degree of tax devolution and continuation of the block grant—a grant that would be reduced to offset the new devolved tax revenues. We weighed up those two and then looked at the suitability of other taxes as candidates for devolution. In that regard, we were much influenced by the advice of the expert group and the evidence that came before us. We feel that the recommendations that we arrived at strike that balance. Indeed, that was not only Ken’s and my view, but that of all the commissioners.
The fact is that long-term-trend growth for the UK is around 3 per cent whereas in Scotland it is 1.8 per cent. I know that we are in a bad situation, but the differential means that the gap widens all the time. Why should we not look at things that would encourage businesses to locate to Scotland, thereby encouraging growth? Is it not true that a number of Scotland’s leading businessmen have called for exactly that? I refer to the likes of Jim McColl, Tom Hunter, Tom Farmer, Peter Burt and even David Watt of the Institute of Directors.
I do not recall those individuals giving evidence to the commission. We went by the evidence that was put before us and the advice of the expert group. In their evidence earlier this afternoon, Anton Muscatelli and others explained the volatility of corporation tax receipts. Commissioners were alive to the issue: we took advice in that regard.
Do you not accept that sustainable economic growth will be one of the main things in making Scotland a better place? If corporation tax is not devolved, what other instruments should be available to the Scottish Government to influence growth?
One strong piece of evidence that we heard was on the importance of the economic union and the social union. Our recommendations have a fair bit of regard for that, too. As Anton Muscatelli and others explained earlier, the link between devolved taxation and economic growth is highly controversial. Although there may be a link in overall expenditure terms, my sense is that there is no evidence that increasing the tax powers of the Parliament would result in that. Certainly, that is my sense from today’s evidence. François Vaillancourt gave evidence to us about that in the course of the Calman commission, and he said then what he has said today: we do not know the answer. In our view, the evidence was not strong on the matter.
Are you suggesting, in that case, that it was not one of the aims of the commission to devise a system to improve Scotland’s wealth?
That is a really strange question. Of course there are issues around improving Scotland’s economic mechanisms to make it a better place and to give it better economic growth. The question that you have focused on is whether corporation tax will do that. The answer that I have got from today is that it would probably not, and that there are downsides to that approach.
Are you suggesting that, in order to stimulate economic growth, we do not require any further powers?
I do not think that I said that at all, and you know that I did not say that. That is a complete misinterpretation of what I have just said. It is actually quite funny.
If I have misrepresented you, I apologise.
That is fine. Good. I can at least laugh about it—and I will not complain.
I will phrase it in a different way. What powers, that they do not have currently, do you believe the Scottish Parliament and the Scottish Government require in order to influence growth?
There is a great deal within the remit of the Scottish Parliament that could already do that, including in education and on the legal side. There is a lot that you can do now. You can change a lot of policies without any influence from Westminster. The Scotland Bill would allow you some additional financial ways to do that. We felt, having discussed the matter, that devolving corporation tax was not appropriate at this time.
I wish to pursue the matter slightly further. The businesspeople to whom Brian Adam has alluded might be in favour of such a move while Scotland was at the bottom end in relation to corporation tax, until Wales, Ireland or Northern Ireland undercut the rate. There would be a different view then.
I am not sure about that. The idea of some kind of corporation tax credit was discussed earlier, although the conversation was not developed further. I am not sure that it would work.
I want to make one other point. It is striking that many of the options that Mr Adam has raised and which have been discussed today could actually be pursued. That is not the issue; the issue relates to the risk and how far the risk goes. If you are prepared to take a big risk, you can change things. If you are not prepared to take a big risk, particularly in the short term, to make sure everything works, you probably will not do anything. The changes could be made—that is not the issue. The issue is how big you want the risk to be and whether you are prepared to manage the risk if things go wrong.
That is helpful; I am grateful for your answers.
I was pleased about that. [Laughter.]
Indeed—I think we share that view.
In one sense, that was a technical issue. When the original Scotland Bill was drawn up, there was a fixed number of health-related professionals, and registration for all of them was reserved. That seemed appropriate. Since the first bill was passed, a number of new professional groups have popped up, and currently there are two jurisdictions in which they are registered. It seemed to be complicated that professional groups who are likely to move from one place to another have to re-register one way or another. I think that I am right in saying that teachers are already quite separate in Scotland and England, which makes for some complications. The commission’s recommendations were an opportunity to tidy up the situation. If the professional groups had all existed in 1998, they would have all been included.
Can you tell us whether there was any request from the professional groups who are affected to have them included, or did the request come from other groups? For example, did you get a request from the dental technicians, which is one group that is affected, that you should consider reserving their registration?
I would have to look back at the details. If I remember rightly, the issue came up early on because people were generally concerned. It came up from other professional groups, too.
I have some concern that the recommendation came from a professional group that is not affected, but we have not heard from the professional group that is affected.
You would have to tell me who you think that is.
We hope to hear from the professional group that is affected, and it may be that there is merit in the argument, but it would have been appropriate to hear from that group.
We can look back and double-check that point, but all I can say in response now is that the issue came out early on and has been in all the publications that we have presented. There have been no negative responses from the professional groups—unless you know something that I do not.
No, I do not, but I would have heard directly from the professional group concerned.
I was slightly surprised by your question, because we made the recommendation public and people know about it, because it seems to be entirely reasonable that professional groups such as dental technicians should be able to move from one part of the country to the other, and because there has been no aggro at all in relation to the issue. However, we will check to see where the concern came from. It came up quite early on—
I understand that it came from evidence from some of the royal colleges. In other words, it came from some doctors, although it would affect not doctors but new groups, such as dental technicians. As I understand it, dental technicians did not contribute to the debate. We want to ensure that they have the chance to do so at this stage.
They had every right to be part of the debate and I see no problem with their—
I am not suggesting that you denied them the opportunity—
We would not do that—
I am just saying that you did not hear from them.
We made all our recommendations as public as we could do and we have had no concerns back—unless you can tell me something.
I think that we have aired most of the issues that we wanted to discuss. As always, the witnesses are welcome to write to us with follow-up evidence or to clarify matters. Are there further issues that members want to raise?
I want to ask whether, given the importance of infrastructure investment in Scotland to economic growth, the witnesses are satisfied with the capital borrowing provisions in the Scotland Bill.
We did not put a figure on capital borrowing. We made two recommendations in respect of borrowing. First, we suggested that the existing short-term borrowing facility of £500 million be kept under review. Secondly, we thought that it was reasonable that the devolved Government and its legislature should have powers to borrow. It was put to us that, given that local authorities can borrow, it is strange that the Parliament cannot do so. We were persuaded by the evidence to make the recommendation.
There is concern, given that during the next four years there will be a 36 per cent cut in the capital budget, that the capital borrowing power will not kick in until 2015. The £2.2 billion cost of the replacement Forth road bridge will probably use up all the capital borrowing that is available to the Scottish Government for the next 10 years, which will limit the number of other infrastructure projects that can be developed. In the circumstances, and particularly in the light of the Forth bridge’s being the number 1 transport priority, would an upper limit be more acceptable?
I talked about the upper limit.
I am aware of the time—it has been a long afternoon. I thank the witnesses very much for their time and their evidence. I conclude the public part of the meeting.