Item 3 is further evidence for our inquiry into the methods of funding capital investment projects. The committee agreed that, as the strategic business case for the Scottish futures trust was published after we had taken the majority of our oral evidence, we would invite a selection of previous witnesses to discuss the Scottish futures trust.
I guess I am the only person around the table who was a member of the delivery team that produced the document "Taking Forward the Scottish Futures Trust", so I can give an overview. The original consultation paper on the Scottish futures trust was produced in an environment in which the idea was contemplated of Scotland being able to raise its bond finance directly under the auspices of the Scottish Government. That option is not constitutionally available at the moment, so it was off the table as an objective by the time we commenced work on the strategic business case for the Scottish futures trust.
Mr Brewer may be able to help on a point of information. In some of the evidence that we have had, doubt has been expressed about whether local authorities would be able to work collectively—on a joint and several basis—under the Local Government (Scotland) Act 1975. What is your view on that? Does legislation exist that would enable local authorities to work collectively like that, or would additional legislation be required?
That would be considered at the implementation stage. The remit of the strategic business case was to ascertain whether there is potential benefit. In an option such as that, certain issues will require to be addressed in order to make it work. We considered the broad principles.
For clarity I should add that under the existing legislation two or more local authorities can combine their power to borrow, but there is currently a limit on the amount of borrowing. There are also issues around the security of that borrowing and the calls on the rates and moneys of the local authorities. However, our reading of the legislation is that there is the power for two or more local authorities to combine and exercise the power to borrow.
Our difficulty with the strategic business case is, frankly, that it is difficult to see what model of finance is being proposed. The original idea of the SFT was a reasonable one about aggregating conventional finance. However, that seems to have been kicked into the long grass by the second quango of the two that are proposed in the SBC. The problem is that the whole document is based on the concept of additionality. Frankly, that is a myth. Private finance is not a free lunch; it is essentially bought at a premium.
I know that we are meant to be talking about alternatives to conventional private finance initiative methods, but it is noteworthy that when the paper on the Scottish futures trust was published, it was taken as a given that PFI was more expensive than the not-for-profit model. That has never been proved and every time it is challenged an empty answer is given.
As markets stand at the moment, local authorities can access capital finance from the Public Works Loan Board, which is normally cheaper and involves less administration than bond finance. That is not to say that the situation might not change in the future—access to PWLB finance could be restricted. The fact that access to such finance is not affected by the size of an authority's funding requirement means that aggregation would bring no benefit. The use of bond finance would bring no benefit for local authorities, either.
I have two brief points. First, the remit was to consider efficient infrastructure investment. The cost of finance is a component of that, but it often interacts with other elements, such as management of risk. When decisions are made about how to progress infrastructure development, it is important to examine the whole picture rather than single components.
As regards the business case, I was concerned that the analysis of the cost of capital and the cost of delivering PFI—whether traditional or non-profit distributing—was limited, in that it was aimed at the low-hanging fruit at the level of individual projects. Much of the political rhetoric around PFI, NPD and SFT has been built on that platform, but the analysis that sits behind it is debatable, at best, and some of the calculations are plainly wrong.
I am sorry. I ask whoever has their mobile phone on to switch it off, please.
No, that is me finished.
You mentioned Australia. Do you have any other examples?
The Russians and Norwegians are doing it. Lots of countries that are running budget surpluses at the moment are considering setting up independent-of-Government conduits to direct their investment in infrastructure. There are examples of countries all around the globe where that is happening, but I know the Australian example quite well.
Perhaps you could write to us about the others. That would be very helpful.
Yes.
I want to expand slightly on a point that Dougald Middleton and Paul Brewer touched on. A lot of the proposals around SFT have focused on local authority bonds and other forms of finance. All the focus has been towards the lowest cost of finance that is available. However, if one targets the lowest cost, there will be less risk transfer from the public to the private sector. So, if a local authority issues a bond collectively with other authorities or independently, it will have the ultimate obligation to repay that bond. Under public-private partnership or PFI, that risk is transferred to the private sector.
Local authority bonds are one of the more tangible and obvious findings. However, the things that Dougald Middleton has talked about—investing alongside the private sector and finding the right balance to harness private sector skills along with an effective capital structure; looking at the overall cost of infrastructure delivery rather than the cost of finance—are very much within the scope of the findings. In particular, the concept of working with the private sector to get the most effective overall solution is one that the SFT finance and investment conduit role would be directed towards. Those options are very much part of the findings of the document, but they have perhaps not attracted as much attention as local authority bonds.
It is worth extending the international examples that Dougald Middleton mentioned against the broad base of the discussion that we are having. We are trying to get the lowest cost of capital while getting the best out of the combination so that that is wholly integral with getting the lowest cost of the overall procurement at its heart. The point has been made on several occasions that aiming to consider the lowest cost of each element does not necessarily equate to securing the lowest cost of the whole.
This is probably a question for Paul Brewer. Would it be constitutionally legal for the Scottish Government to underwrite debt as happens in France?
I think that the powers to do that would sit with the Treasury or would be vested in the Scottish Government by the Treasury, but the power to underpin—by which I mean the power to guarantee repayment of a proportion of project debt—currently exists. We have pursued that line of inquiry because we think that the approach could be effective and could help to generate value for money, provided that the risks that go with the guarantee are carefully scrutinised and managed.
I want to make two points. First, when Government does something that distorts competition, we are potentially in breach of state aid rules, so there are questions about legality. Secondly, guarantees are not a free commodity. If we give a guarantee, it means that Government will underwrite and there is a potential liability. As a result of the accounting framework, guarantees must now be recognised on the balance sheet, so we have to acknowledge the prospect that we might have to pay out the money if the risk has been underwritten. A guarantee can be given, but it must be accounted for.
I think that Dougald Middleton wants to pick up on what Mr Brewer said.
Yes—and I also want to pick up on the question that Joe FitzPatrick asked. If we consider some of the London projects we can see how the co-financing model has worked in practice. On the London Underground PPP Metronet Rail contract, the banks were guaranteed to 95 per cent of the principal and they carried out limited monitoring of the contract post-financial close, so in effect the Government was paying a risk premium for a risk transfer to the banks that did not materialise in practice. In the projects in which the approach has worked, guarantees have been to the 50 per cent or 60 per cent level. In such models, enough is at stake that people monitor the contract closely, but the cost of capital is still optimised.
On Angela Scott's point, if the French Government can finance projects in such a way, I presume that the hurdle about European Union laws on competition can be overcome.
We have to look into that and be clear about it. Under the 1975 act, the responsibility for making sure that local authorities are legally entitled to do these things rests with the local authority, so lenders can lend any money they like—if we find that we do not have the legal power to do it, the local authority bears the risk, not the lender. In the strategic business case there was a line that said that consultation had been undertaken with the Government's state aid and a view was being sought, as we need that clarity.
Nigel Middleton described a model and, I think, he quoted the French Government. As the French always stick to the rules, I presume that the European Commission has cleared such financing of projects as being within the state rules, in which case it should not, in theory, be a problem for us.
I might be being a cautious accountant, but we should confirm that we can definitely do it.
I should also point out that John Swinney is making a statement tomorrow, so he might address some of those issues then; we do not know.
Tomorrow will take care of itself. I am more concerned about getting as much evidence as possible today.
Alex Neil said that if the French do it, it must be within European law—which is a very optimistic comment.
If we are not adopting a new idea, what is your best buy in existing ideas?
Essentially, our best buy would be to build on the conventional finance model using the prudential borrowing powers that exist for local authorities. Those powers could be used in other ways on joint projects, as I indicated earlier. However, we would also look at methods of extending those prudential borrowing powers using the Public Works Loan Board and, if necessary, bond financing to finance projects. That would mean no private finance and, obviously, that there would be no profit element for those who are promoting that aspect of financing.
I will respond on points that were made about the French model as some concerns were expressed. The French are conscientious about ensuring that the level of risk transfer in their projects is optimised to give them value for money. The accounting, whether it is on or off their Government's balance sheet, comes second. At the moment, the Eurostat environment is generally fairly benign with regard to how Governments account for such projects under European rules. Typically, they can be led by best value for money and optimisation of risk transfer as they see it. Whether that will continue if or when all Europe adopts international financial reporting standards is a different question; that is the risk.
Are you talking about large-scale projects, small-scale projects, or the whole range?
The cession Dailly tends to be used for accommodation schemes, and PPPs under French legislation that embrace mid-sized to large accommodation schemes—anything from €75 million to €300 million in capital value.
To put this discussion on the cost of finance in context, I point out that we still have—and always have had—a mixed economy in our approaches to funding infrastructure. By far and away the biggest part of such funding has always come from conventional sources of Government finance. Even at what is—certainly for the time being—the zenith of PFI, conventional finance is the predominant approach. The SFT's role, particularly in its early development, will be to focus on efficient procurement across a whole range of infrastructure procurement. Financing models are an important part of that, but the real effort on that will come from SFT finance and investment, which will be created once the development organisation has been established.
On that point about the mixed economy in our models of financing, is there any reason why the conventional PPP model should be excluded when the SFT's NDP model is introduced? Presumably, there is no financial reason why PPP could not be part of the choice that is made available to local authorities and other public sector organisations.
Clearly, political decisions have been taken about what the Government's policy should be. As I understand it, PPPs in their PFI form have not been conclusively ruled out, particularly in cases that involve a high degree of risk, but the non-profit-distributing model will be the recommended approach—if not the absolutely mandated approach—for projects that involve an element of private finance. The majority of projects will still have no external private finance. Many projects that use the PPP nomenclature involve collaboration between the public and private sectors but are not fully financed by the private sector.
I will pick up on the points that have been made about the finance and investment element of the SFT proposals. Obviously, we are speaking ahead of tomorrow's announcement, but that role for the SFT was relatively downplayed in the strategic business case and was not given prominence in the commentary that appeared after the document was published.
I think that the report acknowledges that. As has been pointed out, we need to get the right balance. On the one hand, we need buy-in from the public sector, so the initial development organisation will need to be for and of the full range of stakeholders in government infrastructure procurement. Otherwise, people will see the SFT as something that has been imposed on them and it will be unable to deliver its full value. That organisation has to be established and it must then decide how the finance and investment element proceeds. However, once that decision has been made, if the finance and investment element is to work effectively, it must have clear objectives of its own and must be constituted in a way that allows it to focus on those objectives and pursue them without institutional capture and in the most effective way, which is outside the public sector.
First, I would like clarification on the SFT's independence from Government. If a large local authority wished to progress a project that it felt was important to its area, but the futures trust decided, making use of its independence, that that was not a model that it could support, are you suggesting that it could veto the project?
No. That scenario is a difficult one to foresee. I cannot see how the SFT, no matter how it is constituted, could have the right to fetter the investment or procurement decisions of a local authority.
I agree.
I draw attention to the English model, which is referred to in the strategic business case—Partnerships for Schools. In that model, Partnerships for Schools sits separately from Building Schools for the Future Investments, which is the investment company. Partnerships for Schools does not sit on the investment company and the investment company does not sit on Partnerships for Schools. The decisions on the projects that will go ahead and the selection of the preferred bidders are all made within Partnerships for Schools, which is separate from the investment side. Under the strategic business case for the SFT, the equivalent of Partnerships for Schools has a minority shareholding in the investment company. We should perhaps re-examine that governance issue, because the English model has kept the two companies separate to ensure independence. The strategic business case suggests that the equivalent of the Partnerships for Schools will retain a minority holding in the investment company, so it could bring that influence to bear.
Andrew Gordon has been very patient, but it was useful to follow that issue through.
My point is far less interesting. It is a point of clarification.
I am interested in the views of the representatives of local authorities on what support they are looking for from a Scottish futures trust, bearing in mind that previous models have provided a significant level of financial support to local authorities in undertaking capital investment work.
We used to get about 80 per cent support from the previous Scottish Executive for, for example, PPP projects. When the Scottish futures trust was announced, Glasgow's response was that we were looking for that level of support in cash on the table. I support the views that Donald McGougan expressed earlier and I was interested in Paul Brewer's response, in which he talked about risk transfer. That is covered only vaguely in the document.
I ask the witnesses for their forbearance as I am a new member of the committee and therefore am new to the inquiry.
Level playing field support is the term that was used—it was mentioned earlier. It was equivalent to 80 per cent of the capital cost of a project and we got it throughout the life of the contract. It was a fixed amount, so the authority faced greater costs as inflation rose, but that is the support that we received.
Level playing field support was established to create some equivalence for privately financed projects where funding could not come as a capital grant but it was required to service on-going costs. That is not explored in the Scottish futures trust document because, regardless of the structure of the Scottish futures trust, there are policy decisions to be made about the appropriate form of financial support for infrastructure projects, be they in local or central Government.
That is the historical situation with level playing field support, but if I understand the position, that option no longer exists. When a scheme requires support, regardless of whether it is an NPD scheme or another scheme, the local authority will require some form of central intervention. Otherwise, there will be a colossal burden on local authorities to fund projects. I am surprised that that was not included in consideration of the SFT model, which has major implications for the funding of our infrastructure.
The overall quantum and form of Scottish Government support for infrastructure projects were not part of the remit. We considered structures that would address effective infrastructure investment. Policy decisions about the funding of that investment were outside the scope of the work.
To underline that point, if the Scottish futures trust talked about efficiency savings on infrastructure investment of 2 to 3 per cent, that would be at the margins as far as addressing the infrastructure backlog across local government and other parts of the public sector is concerned. The big issue is that, over the past period of time, we have been able to make some inroads into that investment backlog because of the 80 per cent support. There will be on-going support through the local government finance mechanism by way of capital grants and the support for local authority borrowing that has now been rolled up in the mainstream grant, but that is only around £25 million per annum for Edinburgh and we have an infrastructure backlog that is many times that amount. The amount that the Government, local authorities and health boards invest in infrastructure compared with their on-going revenue expenditure is a separate political issue.
No one else wants to say anything on that, so we will move on to the second issue, which is the proposed role of the SFT as a provider of central expertise in project development. I will start with a general question. A common theme in our inquiry has been a desire to continue to enhance the public sector's skills in contract negotiations and project management, and that is a core theme in the business case for the SFT. What is the best balance between developing skills in each public body and focusing on a central resource? If a central resource is a good idea, how should it relate to existing resources such as the Scottish Government's financial partnerships unit?
The short answer is that a central resource is needed for a couple of reasons, one of which I gave in my submission. From the perspective of the market for the projects in whatever form they come out, it would be beneficial if projects that different local authorities promoted had a degree of similarity. Therefore, rather than delegate too many skills to individual local authorities, it would be a good thing to have a central resource that is responsible for monitoring projects and delivering homogeneity where variations in different projects arise. That is important because of the scale of the market. Scotland is a relatively small part of a large global infrastructure market to invest in. Therefore, such a central resource is important to encourage the scale of investment that is required.
I think that I saw Lynn Brown keen to get in.
I think that you saw me shaking my head.
I agree with what Michael Watson and Lynn Brown have said, which can be reconciled. The concept of SFT development and delivery is not to undertake the procurement function except, potentially, in cases in which projects are particularly large and complex and a set of skills is needed that is not readily available in the public sector. The original concept for development and delivery had two legs. One was the quality assurance leg, which was intended to sharpen up the existing gateway review procedures and to get more consistency and effectiveness in them. The other was to focus on projects and programmes to provide support when large and complex procurement is undertaken, which different bodies in the Scottish public sector need to differing extents. A large and sophisticated council that has a breadth of resources will have less call on outside skills to support it.
The concept is interesting and valuable if we are talking about upskilling, the sharing of expertise or helping with training, for example. I believe that the SFT is now talking to the Convention of Scottish Local Authorities about how that might work in practice. That is a very useful way forward because we need to get the balance right between the client, the specification and what is being enhanced at the centre.
Am I right in thinking that a clear delineation of roles, responsibilities and powers has been called for?
That is optimistic.
We can keep hoping.
It is clear that nobody has any objection to the idea of sharing expertise. As has been said, a range of different teams work in the field at the moment. There can always be better co-ordination, but one of the strengths of the public service model is that we can do that sort of thing.
We support a development and delivery arm of SFT that is fully public sector. Not enough people in Scotland realise that the financial partnerships unit, in our and most bidders' view, does a better job in Scotland than its counterpart does in England. Paradoxically, we have more centralised co-ordination of procurement in PPP and PFI in Scotland, but it is more light touch. I hope that if the development and delivery vehicle is established, it will build on the model of the financial partnerships unit as a guide and co-ordinator rather than a policeman. We see much more of the policeman down south—and sometimes not a very good policeman—with less of a role for clients, elected local bodies and trusts. As a bidder, I find it frustrating not to be able to talk to the people to whom we will provide a service.
I have two points. First, I agree with the point that Andrew Gordon has just made. The SFT's role must be clearly defined. The financial partnerships unit has a dual remit. In part, its role is to promote efficiency and best practice but, at the end of the day, there is a yes/no button in Victoria Quay—the unit can sanction ways forward on individual projects. It is a credit to the unit that it has managed that balancing act pretty well, but there is an inherent conflict of interest in that situation. That would apply particularly to an organisation that was more at arm's length to the Government than the FPU is and more akin to Partnerships UK. It would be a dangerous precedent to give the new body that sanction over projects.
From the comments that have been made, I wonder whether we need a separate SFT. A lot of reference has been made to the skills in the financial partnerships unit and to building on its work. It seems a little odd that a Government that prides itself on getting rid of quangos and which has taken bodies such as Communities Scotland back into the Executive should now be turning an Executive unit into a quango. Could the same effect not be achieved by extending the financial partnerships unit's role?
One purpose of the proposed governance structure is to have a body that is accountable to all the stakeholders in capital investment in Scotland. That picks up on Dave Watson's point, too. At present, the financial partnerships unit sits within the Scottish Government and provides a service to a range of procuring authorities. Where it is providing finance, it is empowered to make the yes/no decision. The concept for SFT as a delivery vehicle is that it will report to an infrastructure board for Scotland, so it will not be a quango that goes off and develops its own remit. As I said, the SFT must be for and of the community of bodies that undertake capital investment. That should make its accountabilities rather clearer than the current situation of the FPU sitting within the Scottish Government.
As a private sector investor in and sponsor of many infrastructure projects, we would certainly welcome an improvement in expertise and capacity. I do not think that that is in question—the comments are really about how that should be achieved. Barclays has been investing in PPPs in England and throughout Europe for about 15 years. In England, where we started investing, similar comments probably emerged about 15 years ago. Good projects were being delivered, but questions were asked about what was being done on capability in the public sector. To a degree, everyone agreed that it was a good idea to centralise expertise and build capacity. However, 15 years on, has there been significant or continuing improvement in the way in which the public sector handles development and procurement? Across the board, the answer is no. The situation is patchy. Some bodies are very good and, at a personal endeavour level, phenomenal.
I have a short and direct question for Paul Brewer. Will the SFT have a yes/no button in the same way that the FPU has?
The first thing that the SFT will be empowered to do is to undertake gateway reviews. In terms of line of command, gateway reviews do not have an absolute yes/no button, but projects will be accountable for the consequences if they do not act on the findings of reviews. If funding streams with an approval attached to them flow through the SFT, I think that their position will be the same as with the FPU at present.
For the sake of the long-suffering public, can you explain gateway reviews for the record?
Certainly. Gateway reviews seek to ensure the quality of capital investment projects across government. The Office of Government Commerce implements them in England right across the board. Adopting the same methodology, the financial partnerships unit conducts gateway reviews on privately financed capital projects in Scotland. That quality control mechanism is applied to different stages of all significant capital projects. The gateway review comes before each significant decision, which means that scrutiny is applied at the right time to ensure that recommendations are taken account of before moving ahead.
Thank you. I thank all our witnesses for the absence of acronyms, apart from SFT.
I have a follow-up question on a point of clarification. The most effective yes/no button in the financial partnerships unit just now is the one around PFI credits and revenue support. Will that sit within the SFT or will the Government retain it? It strikes me that it would be difficult to delegate it.
As I understand it, the only yes/no button that formally sits in the Government at present is associated with the finance that the Scottish Government historically provides through what is called revenue support grant or level playing field support. That funding stream is not in place for future programmes at the moment, and the yes/no button will attach to them only when they come forward.
When we gave evidence to the inquiry previously, we said that it is important to develop skills in capital procurement, but that it is also important to develop skills, systems, knowledge and planning way before the decision to procure is made. We are keen to see that area developed.
I have a couple of questions on the gateway function. Interestingly, it is not explicit in the Government's literature that the new body will inherit that yes/no function for schemes; it will be able to say only no, because there will be no money for it to say yes. Is that right?
The principle behind the gateway function is quality control. The gateway function is not an integral part of the decision-making process on a project. Any large local authority project, whether or not it is privately funded, would be expected to seek a gateway review of its progress as a quality-control check, but the review would not be part of the management decision-making process. The review would make recommendations and the local authority would be held accountable if it failed to take them into account, but there would be no decision-making power through that process. The financial partnerships unit's current decision-making power attaches only to the line of funding, which it can agree to provide or not agree to provide.
If the gateway process is to be a major function of the SFT, how will that function exist if no funding stream is available for the SFT to carry out the function? Therefore, what functions will the SFT carry out? The central Government centre of procurement expertise, which was established after the 2006 review into effective procurement in Scotland and sits alongside procurement Scotland and Partnerships UK, is quite explicit in stating that its functions include:
That was a long question. Does Mr Brewer want to respond?
The detail of the governance has yet to be established. Whether the SFT will be so empowered will depend, I guess, on a decision by the infrastructure board. Such a decision would need to be agreed by the Scottish Government and, if appropriate, by local authorities. I expect that, as an established centre of expertise, the SFT's views will be, at the very least, highly influential in the progress of capital projects. However, whether the SFT sits in the line of direct decision making and has a power of veto is a detailed question of governance. I think that the organisation will need to be established, or at least be in the detailed planning stage, before we will get a clear outcome on that issue. For example, if the SFT were to have a decision-making power on the progress of local authority projects, local authorities would be required to cede their management decision-making process to another body. That would be a significant step. Detailed consideration would be required before one went as far as that.
We have now moved into the third section. The final issue that we want to cover today is the co-ordination of projects to achieve efficiencies in risk, finance and delivery arrangements. As part of that, we will explore the governance and accountability of the Scottish futures trust and how it will interact with the governance arrangements for public bodies on whose behalf it might fund or commission projects. Again, I will ask a question to start us off.
I suspect that we have excessively high expectations of any central body that tries to co-ordinate procurement across all sectors in the short to medium term, simply because the rest of the world does not know what it is doing. At the moment, the financial partnerships unit does about as good a job as could realistically be done. The reality is that the private sector people who are expected to build and service projects do not actually have medium-term programmes to match the public sector as a buyer of their services. We can go out and take all the market soundings that we like, but the truth is that the private sector people whom we are talking to do not really know what they are going to be doing in three years. They have a rough idea, at best.
There is the issue of the time that we are in, which, at the macro level, means a relative shortage of debt capital for projects in the United Kingdom. Bigger players are looking ever more globally for their projects, including those who have historically taken quite a strong interest in Scotland. In Scotland, while overall capital investment continues apace, the programmes for which the contracting community was able to organise itself and achieve a high degree of predictability of future work flow are very quiet at the moment. Compared with the situation two years ago, there is rather less in the programme pipeline. So the uncertainties that Andrew Gordon has picked up on have both those aspects to them. The difficulties that the construction sector is facing and the shortage of projects are going to develop over time. The situation is dynamic and the SFT will have to look forward to when the market will be stronger and be ready to deal with that.
The governance and accountability arrangements are a weakness in the current strategic business case because there is an absence of detail in them. Lynn Brown and Donald McGougan have the post of section 95 officer, which is one of only two local government positions that are required by statute, and they have a statutory responsibility to safeguard public assets and public money. Local authorities also have a statutory duty, to get best value and value for money. Any proposed arrangements must therefore allow Lynn Brown, Donald McGougan and their respective organisations to meet their statutory responsibilities.
The business case claims that there will be efficiency savings of approximately £100 million to £150 million, but that must be put in the context of £40 billion of investment over 10 years, so the efficiency savings are very small. Also, I can see no evidence in the document that the aggregation of finance is going to deliver even that modest level of savings. The UK Government set up the Public Works Loan Board many years ago, and one of its functions was to create that aggregation of finance. It is hard to see how we are going to do that in Scotland.
On the co-ordination and bundling of finance, there is clearly a minimum size of project against which it is cost effective to raise finance. There may be opportunities for local authorities to bundle projects and bring them to the market jointly. Angela Scott touched on the point that in bundled projects you tend to get into difficult issues about joint and several liability across two or more authorities, which is difficult for finance directors and their members to deal with because of the risks that it brings to the table.
I come back to the point that Dave Watson and a couple of others have made about the governance arrangements being relatively vague and not well worked out at this stage. I make it clear that the role of the body that produced the strategic business case was to set out the way forward and outline the potential governance structure. It would not have been appropriate at that strategic stage to make decisions on governance. It is extremely important that governance is examined more carefully and that stakeholders are involved in the process. There was an element of deliberateness in not going into governance in more depth at that stage.
I will pick up on the point about co-ordination. One of the central tenets of the strategic business case appears to be the desire to co-ordinate the activities of a number of local authorities and other public sector bodies. It occurs to me that, to the extent that the financial partnerships unit has been successful, it has been as a result of its financial influence in relation to level playing field support and its legal influence in the sense that the legal structures that are employed are mandatory. Nothing in the SFT proposal demonstrates that there is either a carrot or a stick that will require local authorities to follow that route. I suspect that the carrot has always been the more successful device. If you are trying to co-ordinate a number of local authorities and bodies and to get them to buy in, it will require more than the SFT being a centre of intelligence: a financial incentive will also be required.
I welcome Paul Brewer's comment that governance will be examined in a lot more detail, because it concerns me greatly—governance has been vague throughout the different stages of the establishment of the trust. Two aspects concern me. The first is decision making. Who will make the decision about what gets done and why? There are competing priorities between and within councils as well as between councils and other public sector bodies. The other aspect is accountability. When a project is approved, who will be accountable for its being delivered on budget and on time? The current lack of governance guidance means that the SFT could be accused of having a democratic deficit, because we do not know who will be responsible for deciding what gets done and how.
You want clearer lines of accountability and control.
I want to pick up on Michael Watson's point about the challenge of co-ordination. Scotland Excel is the centre of expertise for local government that was set up in response to the McClelland review a couple of years ago. As I understand it, we are only now at the point where 27 out of 32 local authorities have signed up. There is not yet an obvious carrot to incentivise co-ordination. The challenge for Scotland Excel is to establish where everybody starts from and the time that it will take to get everybody on to a common procurement platform. We cannot underestimate the challenge of co-ordination or the time that it will take to get the benefits from it.
My point relates to transparency and it is one that I made in a previous submission. On assessing and co-ordinating local authorities' decision-making processes for the funds that they spend, you should not underestimate the time taken to plan projects, as I think Andrew Gordon mentioned earlier, particularly in relation to the whole-life costing of projects, transparency and comparing the benefits of, say, a PPP project, which involves costing at the outset of all the maintenance of the asset over its lifetime, with traditional procurement. I would welcome an explanation and delivery of those benefits through an SFT structure, if that could be promoted.
We are coming to the end of this market day; it is wearing late. If there are no final comments, I thank all our witnesses for their contributions to what has been an extremely interesting and important evidence-taking session. I thank you all for sharing with us your experience and expertise, which is greatly appreciated and will be useful and important to the committee when we produce our final report.
Meeting continued in private until 15:38.