The next item is further consideration of the Scotland Bill and relevant legislative consent memoranda. I am delighted to welcome to the committee the Cabinet Secretary for Finance and Sustainable Growth and the Minister for Culture and External Affairs. We have an enormous amount of evidence and a wide range of issues to get through with the first panel. I alert the committee and others to the additional evidence that has become available. I invite the clerk to comment on that.
I apologise if members have not had the opportunity to look through the material that has just been provided to them. I received it at about 20 past 1 today. There are nearly 40 letters, running to about 140 pages. We provided members with copies of the material in advance of the meeting.
It may be helpful for the minister or the cabinet secretary to comment on the issue. Given that the committee met for a pre-meeting at a quarter to 2, it was rather difficult for members to read 140 pages that were received—not electronically—at 1.20.
I am more than happy to comment. When we appeared before the committee in December, I indicated that we had had extensive discussion and dialogue with the United Kingdom Government on a range of issues, both financial and non-financial. Unfortunately, when the Secretary of State for Scotland appeared before you, he indicated that we had not exchanged any substantial arguments, either financial or non-financial, on the clauses.
We will try to give the material due scrutiny later.
I put on record that I will need to be at this afternoon’s meeting of the Cabinet, as it comes at a rather critical point in Parliament’s decision-making processes.
That is understood.
Thank you, convener—that is appreciated.
The committee has heard that Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development figures show that growth in public spending has been higher than growth in income tax revenue in every decade since 1965. We have also heard that the period that the Scottish Government chose for its analysis was untypical. Even the UK Government has admitted that, over the past 10 years, the Scotland Bill would have reduced the Scottish budget by £700 million. The figure that the Scottish Government has suggested is £8 billion. How do you explain the differences in the figures? Do you agree that, although we can argue over the figures, there is no doubt that the Scotland Bill contains a deflationary bias?
Essentially, my point—and this is the point that we make in the analysis with which we have provided the committee—is that, over the period that the Government examined from 1999-2000 onwards, public spending rose at a faster rate than income tax revenues did. That is not atypical. The atypical period is the one that we are just about to enter, in which income tax revenues may well rise at a faster rate than public spending levels. That is for the clear reason that public spending is reducing in what I think it is fair to describe as an unprecedented fashion—it may not be unprecedented, but the precedents in the past century are very limited.
How long will the period that we are about to enter last? When will we return to the previous position of spending outstripping tax receipts?
I expect that we will be back into that period before the Scotland Bill is implemented. It is not for me to tell the committee when the bill will be implemented. From what I can deduce, it is unlikely under these financial provisions that the bill will be enacted until something like 2018 or 2019. By that time, I would be fairly confident that what I would call the norm of public spending rising faster than income tax revenues would have returned. In looking at the dynamics of that period, we have to ensure that, whatever provisions are enacted as a consequence of the bill, a set of legislative arrangements is not enacted that deal with the exception; we should enact a set of arrangements that guides us through the rule. That is a safer way to proceed.
You are suggesting that income tax will rise more slowly than all taxes in general. What evidence do you have that income tax will rise more slowly in the long term than tax revenues in general and spending? You suggest that that is where one element of deflationary bias comes from.
The historical patterns tell us what we need to know in this respect. It is pretty clear that that is the pattern that it would be realistic to expect in the period that lies ahead.
Can you point us to detailed evidence on that, either now or in writing?
With the greatest respect, Mr Adam, I can point only to the historical trends. I suspect that, if I were able to point to future trends, the Chancellor of the Exchequer would be inviting me to gaze into my crystal ball. I certainly think that looking at the historical trends is a very robust way to proceed.
From your engagement with the business community, can you tell us anything about its feelings about the devolution of corporation tax?
To be fair, I think that the business community will have mixed views on the matter. Some members will be very comfortable with and positive about such a move, whereas others will be concerned about having different corporation tax regimes north and south of the border. However, some of that concern would probably be disarmed if the business community had some comfort that corporation tax rates were going to be lower in Scotland than in the rest of the United Kingdom.
In response to Brian Adam, you appeared to indicate that income tax’s share of the tax take was declining. However, figures from the Scottish Parliament information centre on the budget indicate that income tax as a percentage of all UK taxes was 26 per cent in 1998-99; that it rose to 29 per cent in 2008-09; and that it is forecast to remain at that level in 2015-16. I do not expect you to comment on the detail of that, although Andrew Goudie might want to say something about whether income tax’s share of the total tax take is destined always to decline.
I do not think that that was my point. I apologise if I did not make it clear enough but what I said was that public spending was rising at a faster rate than income tax. That is my point about the deflationary bias of the proposals in the Scotland Bill.
I want to follow on from Mr Adam’s questions and nail down some of the numbers. I am looking at the income tax proposals additional information summary, with which you helpfully provided us, and specifically at the four-year spending review period from 2011-12 through to 2014-15. If we look at the Scottish Government’s projections, we see that, comparing the present funding regime with the proposed funding regime in the Scotland Bill, you estimate that there would have been a deficiency and that we would have been worse off by £331 million in 2011-12 and by £61 million in 2012-13, but in 2013-14, £318 million—
So that I can follow carefully what Mr McLetchie is saying, could he just—
I am referring to table 1.
Is this in “Scotland Bill Income Tax Proposals—Additional Information”?
Yes. I think that that is what I said at the start.
Sure.
If we look at table 1 and at the four years of the spending review period from 2011-12 onwards, I think that, in 2011-12, we see a deficiency between the Scotland Bill proposals and the current funding regime of £331 million, on your figures. If we look at 2012-13, we see that we would still be in deficit by £61 million but, when we come to 2013-14, we see that the Scotland Bill proposals would favour our budget positively to the tune of £318 million, on your figures. In 2014-15, there would be another positive outcome for the Scottish budget of £681 million, on your figures. Is it fair to say that, over the four-year period of the spending review—if we analyse what is happening going forward, not looking at the past—we find that the Scottish budget would be the net sum of £607 million better off under the Scotland Bill proposals, on your figures? Is that what those figures tell us?
This really gets to the nub of the issue. It goes back to what I said in answer to Mr Adam’s point about the historical trends. I said that, to me, the forthcoming spending review period is the exception. If we look back at the periods that Mr Adam suggested, we find that public spending is rising at a faster rate than income tax. We are all aware of what is happening during the course of this spending review period. We are having a period of significant fiscal consolidation. We are agreed on that factual point.
There is—
Let me complete this. There is of course a choice to be made here. One can opt for the mechanism set out currently in the Scotland Bill, but we should do it with our eyes open. That relates to my point about the conditions that we are looking at in this spending review period being fundamentally different from those that generally apply and permeate. I do not see why that is a beneficial arrangement for the Scottish economy.
Of course we have a fundamentally different level of debts and deficits in Britain than we have ever had before, even after two world wars. I suggest that a lot of things fundamentally change—
Actually, I agree with Mr McLetchie there: we are in a unique situation. He has marshalled the argument for me in a way that demonstrates that the current spending review period is a completely different situation from the one in which we would normally find ourselves, because of the debt challenge to which he refers.
Exactly, but the issue is whether we accept your analysis, which is that everything will be sorted out and rosy and bright in four years, and we will get back to what you say is the norm for the relationship between tax receipts and public spending, or whether it will take longer. On the subject of whether it will take longer, did the Scottish Government not estimate—perhaps Dr Goudie can help us here, because he was the author—that the period of fiscal consolidation would endure to 2025 and that, in real terms, we would not be back to where we were until then? Was that not an official projection from the Scottish Government?
I will answer the first part of your question, and then invite Dr Goudie to make some remarks.
I will offer a couple of comments. First, the reference to 2025-26 relates to when, under the set of assumptions that we deployed in that analysis, we might anticipate that we will be back to the levels of expenditure in real terms that existed in 2009-10.
Expenditure will be flat, or lower, until we get to that point, but no higher.
On the basis of the assumptions that we have made in that analysis.
Right, so there will be no real growth for 15 years.
In comparison with 2009-10.
Well, yes—the most recent year. Your statement was that, virtually from now, there will be no real growth in public spending for 15 years. Is that correct?
That is right, but the key point is that public spending will reach a trough—probably; these statements are made on the basis of the assumptions that we put into the analysis—in 2015-16. From 2015-16, we do not know the rate at which UK expenditure will grow, but we make the assumption that Scottish expenditure is moving broadly in line with UK expenditure, which in turn is moving broadly in line with GDP at the UK level.
What is the real percentage fall from the peak in your trough?
In expenditure?
In real terms. How many percentage points lower are we at the bottom of your trough?
I think, off the top of my head, that the level is 6.3 per cent below the 2009-10 peak.
And that is in a trough that occurs in 2015-16.
That is on the basis of six years of real decline from 2009-10 to 2015-16.
If we are recovering from a 6 per cent trough in 2015-16 in the period to 2025, our real growth is less than 1 per cent per annum, is it not? It is two thirds of a per cent, by my humble arithmetic.
I must admit that I do not know the exact number, but the key thing is that, over that period of time, it is, broadly speaking, locked into the GDP growth rate for that period.
Right. Is it the case—as you are an economist, I think that you can help us here—that the reason why we have a structural deficit in the UK economy is that public spending has been rising faster than tax receipts, including income tax receipts?
That is true.
What reason is there to suppose that a future United Kingdom Government will make exactly the mistakes that got us into the present mess?
I—
Please, Mr Swinney. I think that Dr Goudie is just drawing breath to answer.
Okay.
It is important to go back to the two fundamental reasons why there may be a deflationary bias. The key point to make is that, in the coming period, almost by definition we do not know with certainty what the trend path for expenditure will be, what the trend path for total revenues will be or, most important, what the trend path for income tax revenues will be. There are considerable risks around those trends, and the technical point is that, under the terms of the bill, you will be relying on one tax to handle that risk.
I accept that, but I am saying that, given the scenario of there being an unprecedented and extended period to 2025 in which there will be no real growth in public expenditure from the peak that we had previously achieved—that is the scenario that the Scottish Government has painted—it must be just as likely that the mechanism in the Scotland Bill will produce a positive outcome for Scotland as it is that it will produce a negative outcome. Is that the case?
The key question is always whether the share of income tax and total expenditure that is actually occurring in a particular year is greater or less than the share in the base year, or the year zero, from which you start your calculation.
Indeed, but we are going to be starting from your trough, are we not?
It depends what ratio you apply in that year, and what deduction you make from the block.
My point is, given your gloomy analysis that public spending will remain flat for that lengthy period, that I find it hard to see how it can be taken almost as a given that there will be an inherent and intrinsic so-called deflationary bias, when the evidence of the four years that you are predicting with some degree of certainty—never mind crystal balls, predictions for 2025 or whatever—is actually quite the opposite. We will actually be better off. Is that not the case?
Unfortunately, I do not have the exact numbers in my head about the performance from 2015-16, but what is important is the rate of growth from the trough and the comparison with income tax over that period. We have not forecast income tax over that time. I do not know whether anyone does—
So, you have not forecast it.
Income tax?
You have not forecast income tax from that time. That is what you said. Is that right?
We have no basis for doing that.
Right. If you have not forecast it, that means that there are no figures on which you can base an assumption. Is that not right? The income tax receipts are one of the components. Is that not correct?
No—that is a misrepresentation of the analysis. Two points need to be made. First, the forecasts that were implicit in the analysis that Dr Goudie undertook were forecasts about tax revenues rather than specifically about income tax. Secondly, the fundamental point, which must be understood, is that public spending will rise from the trough. It will take some time to recover—
It will rise slowly from the trough. We have heard that it will rise only six percentage points in nine years.
Yes, but it rises from the trough—although, of course it will take time to get back to 2009-10 levels. The key point that Dr Goudie made, which the committee must bear in mind, is that the Scotland Bill would lock us into a direct relationship with income tax. As the IMF evidence demonstrated, income tax is rising at a much slower rate than wider taxation revenues in general.
Dr Goudie was inviting us to say that the relevant comparison is a 45-year trend on income tax. I mentioned figures on income tax as a percentage of all tax in the decade since devolution and during the next five years. Will you clarify the position on income tax as a percentage of all tax?
In the nine years since devolution, the Scottish Government budget grew on average each year by 8 per cent. The total tax take rose by 6.4 per cent and total income tax take grew at a rate of 5.2 per cent per annum.
That was not my question. My question was this: during the 10 years of devolution, what has been the trend in relation to income tax as a percentage of total tax take?
I cannot give you a precise figure. I think that I am right in saying that during that time income tax as a proportion of the Scottish block decreased from 49 per cent to 39 per cent, which gives a flavour of the trend that we are looking at. Gary Gillespie will correct me if I am wrong.
The question was about income tax as a percentage of total tax take, not about income tax in relation to Scottish spending. You offered us a 45-year trend, based on IMF data. In the past 10 years, what has happened to income tax as a percentage of all tax and where is that percentage forecast to go in next three years?
We do not have those figures, I am afraid.
It would be helpful if you could write to us on that.
We must analyse the reasons for the trend. I am a lay person and do not necessarily understand all the economics, but it seems to me that the reasons are that we have expanded the use of VAT and national insurance and, in particular, that we have expanded the use of borrowing, against a background of higher house prices and debt levels throughout the country. If those factors remain the same, the cabinet secretary might have a point, but if those policy and factual trends are not consistent—as appears to be the case, given the current situation—does not the stack of cards that has been erected on the 45-year trend collapse around your ears, because the trend is not relevant to the future?
It does not collapse around our ears. You have helpfully provided some of the answers, by talking about VAT and national insurance contributions, which will not be at the disposal or discretion of the Scottish Government or the Scottish Parliament under the bill.
I want to clarify something from the papers that were circulated earlier this afternoon and to which Fiona Hyslop referred. They are obviously difficult to get to grips with. However, they include a letter of 6 July from the permanent secretary to the UK Cabinet, who is in the home civil service, to which a one-page summary is attached that is headed “Financial Responsibility for Scotland Within the UK.” That paper is dated 10 June 2010. I want to clarify whether we have all the documents. The one-page summary is headed “Summary”, which rather implies that it is a summary of something else. What is this paper a summary of?
It is essentially an explanation, for ease of reference, of what we would consider to be the model of financial responsibility. I suppose that one could look at some of the detail in the document “Fiscal Autonomy in Scotland: The case for change and options for reform”, which the Government published in February 2009 and which introduced a concept that was affectionately referred to as “devo max”, but which had acquired the more thoughtful title of financial responsibility by the time that it got to that letter to—
So, it is not a summary of a document but a summary of an argument.
That is fair.
Does that one page represent the most substantive document that was submitted to the UK Government about financial responsibility?
I think—I do not think; I know—that that prompted discussions with UK ministers about the concept of moving to a wider range of powers and responsibilities than are proposed in the Scotland Bill, and that it prompted the extensive discussions that took place between, principally, Dr Goudie and his team and their counterparts in Her Majesty’s Treasury.
So, the arguments that would flow about financial responsibility were not recorded. There is no piece of paper that is more substantial than the one-page summary, setting out the arguments to the UK Government so that it could properly consider them. Those matters were developed in conversations between officials and between ministers.
Dr Goudie can say more about that because, obviously, he was involved in many of the official discussions. However, anybody considering that document alongside the Government publication of the paper on fiscal autonomy in Scotland and the white paper would have got a greater and deeper understanding of the issues; those documents were obviously enhanced by the conversations that took place between officials.
That summary would have been the only piece of paper that we passed physically across to the Treasury. However, perhaps it is worth saying that over the summer months we had a series of detailed conversations with Treasury officials about the full fiscal responsibility approach of ministers, as is broadly captured in the paper that the committee has been provided with in the past few days, which is a nine-page document that summarises the position. The key point is that in the course of those meetings we gave on several occasions quite formal presentations of the views of ministers around full fiscal responsibility, talking through PowerPoint presentations and describing the structure of the argument in great detail. So, even though they were provided with only the one piece of paper that Mr Peacock has described, I am confident that they were fully aware of the views of ministers and the arguments that underlay the positions that ministers were taking.
How would you characterise those arguments? Was it about high-level principles in the sense of the points that John Swinney set out earlier about the Scottish Government’s belief that having more levers would open up options for the Scottish Government and the Scottish economy? Alternatively, in the way that you have done for the questions about the Calman proposals that David McLetchie was pursuing, did you model the financial responsibility model for the Treasury so that it could give it full consideration?
We did two things. One was to address the technical issues surrounding the Calman proposals and where we felt those were difficult. The committee is familiar with those and they are well captured in what the cabinet secretary has said and in the letter that was provided to the convener on 25 January.
Is there no documentation to back that up for us to examine?
No. We provided no documentation. We just talked about the matter in great detail with ministers, and we talked through the presentations with them.
Convener, I point out that a detailed model has yet to be produced for the Scotland Bill. All that we have is an illustration, and the Scotland Office’s caveat is that that has not even had Treasury approval, so there is an issue about modelling in relation to the Scotland Bill, and particularly the requirement in year zero for some kind of balance adjustment, for which there is no technical provision in the bill, for Parliament to approve. I suspect that the Westminster Government will legislate on that within a matter of weeks. That really is a matter for concern about the Scotland Bill.
Minister, when you asked us whether the committee would give full scrutiny to alternative proposals to the Scotland Bill, you meant scrutiny of a one-page summary and no modelling.
I think that you will find that you have been provided with an extensive set of arguments and proposals in the correspondence that has been given to you. I do not think that we could have provided more information to the committee. Compared with what you have got on the Scotland Bill, it is far more extensive.
I turn to the subject of financial accountability. If you have been reading the Official Report of the Scotland Bill Committee, you will know that I have consistently asked witnesses where the 35 per cent figure—the amount of money that we can raise—comes from. Last week, the UK Government told the committee that its 35 per cent estimate was based on an estimate on page 105 of the Calman commission report. Given that some of the taxes that are proposed in the report have not seen the light of day in the Scotland Bill, surely that 35 per cent figure is an overestimate. Has the UK Government provided the Scottish Government with any calculations that show where its claim of 35 per cent has come from?
It has certainly not provided them to me. Dr Goudie tells me that that information has not been shared in any discussions that he has had with the Treasury.
So, no information on that 35 per cent figure, which the UK Government has suggested will be the amount of fiscal responsibility, has been shown to the Scottish Government or to anyone else.
No.
Reform Scotland told the committee that we would be responsible for raising only 26 per cent of the devolved budget. Of course, there is a big difference between 26 per cent and 35 per cent. Is a Government that raises only a quarter of what it spends financially accountable?
I am not sure about that number, either. According to the numbers that I have in front of me, under the current framework, 7 per cent of Scottish tax revenues are devolved to the Scottish Government and it is envisaged that under the Scotland Bill the figure will be 15 per cent. I am not sure where the other numbers come from.
So, there is about a 20 per cent difference between your figures and the amount that the UK Government has claimed Scotland will be responsible for raising as a result of the Scotland Bill.
It is certainly a big difference.
Will you share your calculations with the committee?
I am happy to do so.
I hope that the committee will also write to the UK Government, asking it to explain exactly where the 35 per cent figure comes from.
No.
Last week, the Secretary of State for Scotland said that that £45 million, which under the proposals would come out of the Scottish block, was highly caveated and he refused to put a ceiling on those costs. The week before that, the Institute of Chartered Accountants of Scotland told the committee that the costs of implementing the tax proposals could be high as £150 million. Has the Scottish Government asked the UK Government to provide a detailed breakdown of how it arrived at that £45 million figure?
I cannot say with hand on heart that we have asked for such a breakdown, although we have, of course, made clear in correspondence to the UK Government our concerns about the assumption that the costs of all this would have to come out of the Scottish Parliament and Scottish Government budget. The eighth point in paragraph 3.2 of the statement of funding policy would lead me in completely the opposite direction.
ICAS also said that financial statements from the Treasury normally underestimate the final cost. ICAS was extremely concerned that the more complex it was to put together the database of Scottish taxpayers, the more costly it would be. It suggested that the cost would be in the order of £150 million or possibly more. We all recognise the difficulties that we have had with estimates in the past. Does it concern you that the Secretary of State for Scotland is suggesting not only that the £45 million should come out of the Scottish Government’s money, but that we could face a cost of £150 million or more? Will the Scottish ministers, as well as the committee, take that up with the Treasury at the first opportunity?
We have raised our concerns about the assumption that the Scottish block will pay for the costs of implementing the proposals, bearing in mind the fact that the Scottish block has already paid for one tax system that is now about to be abolished by the decisions of the House of Commons and the House of Lords. To me, that activates paragraph 3.2.8 of the statement of funding policy. I say to Tricia Marwick that we cannot be cavalier about the cost of the system, because it is not a simple system to apply; it is a very complex system to put in place. As Scotland’s finance minister, I take a keen interest in the question, which is why I have cited paragraph 3.2.8 of the statement of funding policy. However, the committee needs to consider carefully the questions that have been raised.
I am aware that Fiona Hyslop wants to come in. We will move on to non-financial matters and return to that issue later.
This is on a financial issue. For clarity, we wrote to Michael Moore on 26 November, outlining our concerns and indicating that properly supported costings backed up by viability reviews would be a crucial test of the bill. He replied, but not in any detail. Importantly, he said:
The issue is what improvements the Scottish Government seeks to make to the bill. We must move on; there is a lot of ground still to cover. Long questions equal long answers, as it happens.
I have four or five areas to go through, which I will try to do quickly. The areas are: higher rate income tax, grant reduction mechanisms, borrowing and something about Scottish Government proposals to devolve energy, employment and benefits. We have taken a lot of evidence on those things with a view to whether there are ways to improve the bill as it stands.
I appreciate that Mr Peacock asked me a question—he did not make a statement or set out a commitment on his position—but when we get on to that ground, we have to accept that the bill proposals are severely constrained and limited. In my opinion, in considering the most appropriate way to proceed, we would do better to open up the whole thing. I refer to the model of full financial responsibility that would enable an orderly set of arrangements to be put in place.
I understand where you are coming from. Propositions have been put to us. I am simply trying to establish whether the Scottish Government has a view on how the bill can be improved in a technical way. From what you say, you appear not to have a specific proposal—
No, that is not—
Part of the reason for asking the question is the contrast between non-financial issues, on which the Scottish Government is coming up with amendments to the bill, and financial and technical measures, on which it has proposed no amendments.
I gave a pretty specific answer to Mr Peacock. We think that the way to proceed on this matter is to equip Scotland with the ability to make a range of flexible decisions that take account of the prevailing economic circumstances. That is the model we believe in; that is our enhancing proposal.
In which case, I suspect that I will get the same answer to my next three questions.
Oh well, let us cut to the chase—
I will ask a convener’s question before we return to Peter Peacock’s questions.
A convener’s question is usually designed to penetrate the issue a little further. I have just given Mr Peacock the answer. We fundamentally believe that the right way in which to proceed is the model of financial responsibility. The manner of the convener’s question suggests that she is casting doubt on the volume of information that has been made available, but has she made any analysis of the material that the Government has published, including the information that we have exchanged and discussed with the Treasury? That is why we produced the timeline. The Secretary of State for Scotland came to the committee last week and he fundamentally misled the committee on the degree of dialogue that has been going on—he fundamentally misled the committee. He came to committee and said that there had been no dialogue on the substance—
Cabinet secretary—
No, no convener. I want to put this on the record.
What assertion is misplaced?
The assertion that the detail is not there—all of it is there.
The detail is there; we have established the depth of the alternative. I am asking you about improvements to the bill. Are there any amendments that you want the committee to make to the structure of the income tax power that is proposed in the bill? This is our final evidence session. We have been studying the bill—as you have—for a number of months. What amendments would you like to be made to the income tax structure?
The committee could recommend to the UK Government that we move to having a much wider range of financial powers, as envisaged under financial responsibility. It would be helpful if the committee were to agree on that recommendation.
Let me ask four precise questions. First, how would you like the income tax structure that is proposed in the bill to be amended?
We may be back on the ground that Mr Peacock was on previously; you may get the same answer to four questions. Fundamentally, the Government’s perspective is that we do not believe that the arrangements in the bill provide the type of financial and economic levers that would enable Scotland to focus on growth.
I accept that.
Your acceptance is an illustration of the fact that the bill must move by a considerable margin to align itself with the Scottish Government’s aspirations for growth.
I absolutely accept that the Scottish Government does not think that the bill is perfect. On our final evidence day, I am asking how you would like the grant reduction mechanism to be improved. The entire resources of the Scottish Government are available to you. What improvements would you like to make to the form of grant reduction?
How the grant reduction mechanism will operate is a mystery tour. Even the United Kingdom Government is not clear about that. Let me quote from the last piece of modelling that we received from it, which was rushed out 20 months after the Calman commission’s report. We received this little ditty from the secretary of state, who said:
You are being asked what the Scottish Government believes is the optimal approach to grant reduction. What is your view?
My view is that the optimal direction is to move to full financial responsibility. If the committee took that approach, it would be doing Scotland a service.
The grant adjustment model is a leap into the unknown. It would be an act of faith by the committee to recommend that legislative consent be given in that area when we do not even know what the Treasury’s model is. That is a very serious point.
You have written to us with a vast array of amendments on the non-financial powers. On the final evidence day, why do we have no amendments at all from the Scottish Government on the financial powers?
How can you amend something that is not there in the first place? The actual legislative proposal is not in the Scotland Bill, which says only that the Treasury will adjust the grant.
The bill amends in law the structure of the income tax power. That is one area. I will give you another example. Which additional tax would you like the committee to include in its report?
You could include corporation tax and a variety of other measures. We have specified that we do not think that VAT should be part of the framework; we accept that that must remain a United Kingdom tax, but a whole range of taxes could be devolved under the concept of full financial responsibility.
I will not go back into grant reduction—I got the answer to the question before I asked it and I will settle for that. I understand where you are coming from.
There are two distinct areas of borrowing: borrowing for revenue volatility and long-term capital borrowing. On the borrowing for revenue volatility, the cumulative limit of £500 million strikes me as being too low to deal with the volatility within a cycle. What would the number ideally be? I suspect that the number might more safely be between £1 billion and £1.5 billion. In the period—[Interruption.] This is not the table that I have in my head—
You have a better one. [Laughter.]
Here it is, in my helpful Scotland Office document. In the four-year period 2008-09 to 2011-12, the cumulative variance is about £1.2 billion.
You are seeking a limit that exceeds the maximum that it has been in recent experience.
I am just saying that £500 million feels to me to be too light. The answer is probably about £1 billion or perhaps slightly higher.
I want to take that a bit further. Whether or not other taxes are added in light of your recommendations, the borrowing powers will maintain, so what the bill says about borrowing is quite important. Do you have specific proposals on how you construct the legislation in a way that allows the flexibility that you are describing?
We can certainly provide the committee with input on that.
But there is not one you have ready.
The timeline that was referred to shows that at one of the meetings with the UK Government we provided draft clauses on borrowing.
It would be helpful to see those.
They are based on the Calman proposals but we will be able to update them in relation to the bill.
That is fine.
That has been covered in what I said to the committee about the extent of financial responsibility. The point is possibly best illustrated by figure 1 in the document, which demonstrates the contrast in responsibility under the different models.
I will follow up Tricia Marwick’s earlier questions. Have you provided costs for the Treasury for running your proposed system?
I will make a point for which I had the data a second ago. The United Kingdom Government has high expenditure on tax administration as a percentage of GDP—it spent nearly twice as much as Norway and almost two thirds more than Finland on tax administration in 2007. Efficiencies can undoubtedly be made in the organisation of such systems in small countries.
Tricia Marwick quoted a figure from ICAS of up to £150 million for the system under the bill. You have no equivalent figure for the cost of your proposals.
I would not like to credit the figure that the Scotland Office gave the committee as worth making a comparison with—the number is a bit shaky.
But you have no number for your proposals.
I am simply saying that we can deliver tax administration in efficient ways in a small country.
But you have no number—that is what I am trying to find out.
I am simply saying that we can deliver tax administration in a small country.
I think that I have got the answer.
I will return to growth, which the cabinet secretary was right to mention. Has the new document—the February 2011 paper called “Full Financial Responsibility”—been sent to the UK Government?
The document was sent to the committee.
Has it been sent to the UK Government? That is what I asked.
Not so far.
Last week, I had a helpful meeting with David Mundell, when I agreed that we would marshal all the materials that had been given to the committee and give them to him after the committee finishes its deliberations.
That is helpful.
The definition of small European Union countries that has been used is of countries with a population of less than 10 million. The countries that have been included in the analysis are Austria, Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Luxembourg, Portugal and Sweden. That is what the analysis is based on.
So it is an average. There is not really an obvious principle coming out of that against the wider figures of the EU, the UK and the mix of countries at the same level as Scotland, is there?
I think it just demonstrates a level of economic performance that is a worthy aspiration for Scotland—we could deliver economic performance at a higher level than we currently perform. UK trend economic performance over that period will be higher than 1.9 per cent; it will be 2.3 per cent.
I want to develop that point slightly, because you made the interesting statement on the same page of the paper that
I do.
I am struck by the fact that a different impression is conveyed in the January paper, “Summary of Full Financial Responsibility & Independence”, where you put forward the proposition that an increase in Scottish public spending of 1 per cent a year would give us an extra £18 billion of resources in real terms for public service over 10 years. You base that very enticing idea on the analysis by Professor Hughes Hallett and Professor Scott that every 1 per cent increase in fiscal devolution might raise GDP by 1.3 per cent after five years. Do you now accept that that statement in the January paper was very distinctly over-egging the position? We might all have agreed with you that a bit more fiscal efficiency, if you like, was possible, but not that there was this historical inevitability that you seem to have taken from Professor Hughes Hallett and Professor Scott.
There is a really interesting point here. This is why I think the work of Professors Hughes Hallett and Scott is very important and why it is appropriate for us to consider it. I think there are two elements to this growth argument. One is about the point, on which I am completely in agreement with Robert Brown, that a large measure of it depends on what you do and what policies you take forward. I have no issue with that whatever.
That is a very good example, and I am prepared to accept what you have said to a degree. However, the fact is that those kinds of decisions can be made at various levels, including by the UK Government and, as you have illustrated, the Scottish Government—
But it cannot.
Please let me finish the point. Yes, there is an opportunity to make technical efficiencies in the system, but the committee is also concerned with the fact that any consideration of where would be the best level to put these powers must take account of downsides to the Scottish economy as a result of some of the movement of taxes that the committee has been examining; whether there will be fiscal tax competition, for example, with regard to corporation tax; and a whole series of other issues.
Those questions fall under the “What do you do?” category. Do you take the good or the bad decisions? Robert Brown is absolutely correct to say that all these decisions can be taken at different levels, but I point out that under the current framework I could not introduce, say, a future jobs fund and get any credit for doing so under the Barnett formula. The budget that would be varied at UK level would be that for the Department for Work and Pensions, which has zero comparability for Barnett purposes. That is where we are.
Has the argument that the devolution of revenue tax-raising powers points in the likely direction of economic growth been overstated? Is it not the case that growth cannot in fact be sustained?
I think that I answered that point when I said that I recognise that there are one-off economic efficiencies, including the one that I have just cited, that can be achieved and then there are certain decisions that have to be made about what you are going to do or to tackle.
Is it the Scottish Government’s view that a 1 percentage point increase in fiscal devolution might be expected to raise GDP by 1.3 per cent after five years, above what might otherwise be the case?
The Scottish Government continues to accept that analysis, although I think that we have said that there is likely to be a 1 per cent increase in GDP. I know that the study by Professor Hughes Hallett and Professor Scott has stated a 1.3 per cent increase, but I think that from the Scottish Government’s perspective the figure will be 1 per cent.
According to the First Minister at the Scottish National Party conference, Mr Swinney, it was not a one-off increase in performance but 1 per cent per annum growth.
The point that I have just made is the explanation that I would give.
Which is at variance with the First Minister’s explanation.
Does the chief economic adviser have any comment to make on that relationship? Might a 1 percentage point increase in fiscal devolution be expected to raise GDP by 1.3 per cent after five years above what would otherwise have been the case?
I expect that you will be aware of what my answer is, convener. Our team looks at and analyses the information and offers its best professional judgment on all these matters in confidential private advice to ministers and, as you will no doubt expect, I would not dream of passing that advice on to the committee today.
With that intriguing answer, I bring this part of the session to an end. I thank the cabinet secretary, whom we have kept from Cabinet discussions on the budget, and now turn to the Minister for Culture and External Affairs with questions on non-financial matters. Trish Marwick will lead off on elections.
The Secretary of State for Scotland will still retain a number of responsibilities, including voter registration, rules on the Parliament’s composition, the procedure for filling regional seat vacancies during the Parliament’s life and rules on disqualifications. Is the minister happy with the UK Government’s response to the committee last week? Apart from the procedure for filling any regional seat vacancy during the Parliament’s life and rules on disqualifications, what other rules relating directly to the Scottish Parliament would the minister like to be devolved?
That is an important point in relation to elections, and it also has an impact on other non-financial areas.
Can you clarify the Scottish Government’s view on whether it would be better to devolve powers on all the relevant matters that relate to drink driving? I am talking about the whole package, including the limits, penalties and regulations on random testing.
Yes, we think that it would.
How do you envisage the system of penalties working? If the limit was set at 50mg per 100ml of blood, for example, would you take the view that for any suspension or withdrawal of a licence, the offence would be lesser at 50mg than at 80mg?
It would be for the Parliament and ministers to decide what the penalties should be in relation to any limits. My argument is that we should at least have the chance, and the powers, to make those decisions about what the penalties should be.
We heard from the Road Haulage Association that the speed limits for heavy goods vehicles should be devolved. In particular, the RHA argued on the grounds of safety as well as environmental improvement that raising the speed limit from 40mph to 50mph on single carriageways would help in terms of safety records and fuel consumption. Can that be done under the current regulations, or would it require a change to the proposals?
It would require a change, which again reflects the limitations of what is proposed in the bill. The RHA submitted evidence to the original commission on devolution, giving precisely the same reasons that you have just set out. A much more watered-down proposal has been put forward in the bill.
We have heard evidence that casts doubt on the necessity of re-reserving the regulation of the health professions. Joseph McIntyre told the committee that members of the Dental Laboratories Association
No. There has been no such request. I noted that when the committee received evidence from professions that will be affected by the proposals in the bill, witnesses said that they wanted regulation to remain devolved.
I presume that the change would bring practical difficulties and weaken the ability of the Scottish Parliament and the Scottish Government to influence decisions, which should be made on a parity-of-esteem basis across the UK. Is that the essence of your argument?
Yes. Re-reservation would also diminish the ability of devolved health professionals themselves to inform and influence discussions about regulation. It is interesting that one of the professions—I cannot recall which one—opened offices in Scotland, so that it could get closer to the Scottish health system. Given the approach of the new coalition Government in the UK, it is clear that there will be increasing divergence between Scotland and the rest of the UK on health policy, so it is particularly important that our health professionals have the comfort of being close to the Cabinet Secretary for Health and Wellbeing and decision making on regulation in Scotland.
In written evidence, the Scottish Federation of Housing Associations said:
The answer to your question is no, and we are concerned about the issue. Provision for section 30 orders under the Scotland Act 1998 was made to support the Housing (Scotland) Act 2001—the convener is familiar with the legislation—and the Housing (Scotland) Act 2010.
It would be very helpful to have an amendment on the RSLs, because there is widespread acceptance that the issue needs to be looked at. A submission on that in due course would be great. We understand the policy position and have some sympathy with it.
We will provide something, if you bear with us. It is a fairly complex area.
We come to the other really substantive issue, which is the Crown Estate.
We have had a lot of evidence—written evidence, mostly—on the Crown Estate, and we will have a session on it just after you have gone. That evidence points overwhelmingly to some change being sought. At one level, the bill makes what could be argued is a fairly token change—the appointment of a Scottish commissioner. At another level, you have argued for full devolution of the Crown Estate to Scotland.
No, but I am aware of it.
Another strand that has emerged is that new forms of accountability between the devolved Administrations and the UK Government—the Crown Estate currently accounts to the Treasury—could be developed. I know that you favour full devolution of the Crown Estate, but do you regard any or indeed all of the other possibilities that are beginning to emerge as a welcome step forward?
There are many possibilities with the Crown Estate. As you rightly said, what is presented in the bill is, unfortunately, just about the most minimal change that could be made. I indicated that in December. I am a bit disappointed that the secretary of state said that he awaited
I take your point on that, but I am trying to get a hint from you. I understand that you argue for full devolution of the Crown Estate, but if the UK Government was not disposed to do that, other possibilities are emerging, and you would want at the very least to see some movement from the current position. You would prefer to go to a fully devolved situation.
It is clear that we think that a fully devolved position would be preferable. The issue is not just appointments, which can be made in different ways; it is about policy influence. That is the key. Policy influence is critical, and we think that that can best be achieved by full devolution. However, I appreciate the argument that has been put by others, and I do not want to prejudge what the committee will come forward with.
You have taken me to the next point that I was going to probe. A current issue is that the Crown Estate has been developing entirely new expertise in offshore renewables and their licensing. It has been pushing to the next round of development and putting quite a lot of investment into offshore renewables, and it has gathered a considerable amount of staff expertise. It may well be possible to construct ways of influencing policy on that in the short to medium term that could be of great benefit to Scotland without necessarily going to full devolution. That may be the UK Government’s preferred position. Are you happy to consider such proposals further in the spirit of moving things on?
I think that the status quo is unacceptable. I would like us all to agree about that, and to agree that the proposals in the Scotland Bill are feeble and need to be improved. The key issue is influencing policy, which can be done in different ways. We are setting out our views to members. The committee has received evidence from a number of other areas, and it is up to the committee to decide on the way forward, but I suspect that anything will be better than where we are now. However, let us not limit our ambitions and the horizons of the possible.
Andy Wightman has provided us with a submission, in which he says:
Yes. That accentuates the flaws in the proposal in the Scotland Bill. It does not engage at all with the issue of democratic accountability, which is an issue not only for the Scottish Parliament. We know that the local authorities that have a keen interest in the matter want to have an input as well. Therefore, the proposal is extremely limited.
An issue that I raised with the Crown Estate Commissioners last week was the potential revenue from offshore renewable energy in the next decade. The Crown Estate commissioner suggested that the revenue for the UK would be between £12 million and £48 million. Some people dispute that and think that the amount will be much higher. Do you think that, even if nothing else changes, Scotland should get a share of the profits that currently go back to HM Treasury? Should Scotland get a share of the profits coming from the Crown Estate Commissioners?
Definitely. Under the Crown Estate Act 1961, the commissioners’ duties are “to maintain and enhance” the value of the Crown Estate
I thank the minister for her evidence. There are one or two areas that we have not had the chance to cover. I am sure that we will cover them in correspondence. Is there anything else that you would like to put on the record?
There are a number of issues. I know that the Lord Advocate will give evidence to you later, but I have serious concerns about some proposed provisions and the lateness of their introduction. I understand that you may have seen some draft—possibly secret—clauses. So have we, but there is a real issue as to whether we will be able, in the time that is available, to have a meaningful discussion about provisions that involve huge transfers of constitutional powers.
I understand that. For clarity, will you confirm that your concerns relate to section 57(2) of the 1998 act, which is not inconsequential, and that you have no concerns beyond that?
No. We have a range of concerns about all the Advocate General’s proposals. Some proposals are welcome, but we have serious concerns, especially about the proposals relating to the Supreme Court.
You are talking about section 57(2).
Yes, but we have concerns about the consequences of some other proposals. After I have had time to discuss the matter with my Cabinet colleagues, I would like to have the opportunity to provide you with our view, while you are drafting your report. This is an on-going issue. As you will hear, it is fundamental to not just decades but centuries of practice. For that reason, the Scottish Parliament should be able to reflect on it fully.
Last week we indicated that we would take further evidence on section 57(2) from relevant interested stakeholders. It would be helpful to have submissions on any other issues relating to legal provisions relatively early, but we are happy to take late submissions on section 57(2). It may or may not be possible to reach a definitive view on the issue.
The information that I have provided to the committee already sets out our view on the proposals of the expert group and on the Advocate General’s consultation. You do not have our definitive position on the Advocate General’s proposals, now that we have seen them.
I understand. Thank you for that clarification. I suspend the meeting for a minute or two to allow the new panel to join us.
We are joined by a large and distinguished panel. Martin Sime is the chief executive of the Scottish Council for Voluntary Organisations; Dave Moxham is the deputy general secretary of the Scottish Trades Union Congress; Lucy Parsons is the project manager for marine renewable energy in Orkney Islands Council; Andy Wightman is a prolific author on these matters and is someone whom I describe as a land reform campaigner—I do not know whether that is a helpful description, but that is how I think of him and there is no designation beside his name in my papers; and Alan Trench, who is an honorary senior research fellow at the constitution unit of University College London and the author of the blog “Devolution Matters”.
I will be brief, because I know that time is tight.
Your submission states:
I am not a technical expert, but I think that that would take the Scotland Bill into completely new territory, which is exceedingly unlikely at this point in the cycle. However, that is more about the track that the bill seems to be set on rather than about whether, in an ideal world, it would be possible to amend the bill to make certain possibilities real for the committee and to give Westminster a choice of whether to go in the existing direction or not. However, my overall view is that I simply would not have started from here. In an ideal world, the whole thing should go back to the drawing board.
I take it that that is the view of the SCVO, but how widespread are the views that you have expressed? Do they reflect the views of the voluntary sector?
That is a difficult question. I have indicated in my evidence to you—which has been validated by the SCVO policy committee, which is elected by our 1,300 members—our disappointments in the bill but also the expectation that our members will have a diverse and pluralistic set of views relating to what is in the bill and what ought to have been in the bill. I am sure that that is the case. We expect voluntary organisations to make up their own minds rather than have some collective or corporate view.
Do you get the sense that the voluntary sector resents the fact that there has been a lack of consultation with it both on Calman and on the bill?
I would not say “resents”, but we expect a better set of processes in the generation of legislation than this bill has reflected. The fact that it is a Westminster bill means that it rather reflects a traditional way of making legislation in the UK, from which the Scottish Parliament has moved on. Our members have a high expectation of detailed engagement on the development of policy options and widespread consultation around the issues that affect them and that come before the Parliament—even before they come before the Parliament—as the subject of legislation. Those standards have manifestly not been reached in the progress of the bill.
In evidence to the Scottish Affairs Committee, the witnesses from the SCVO suggested that there should be devolution of the power to make secondary legislation in the areas of reserved benefits. Can you expand on what you mean by that and explain why you think that it would be of benefit?
I am sorry, but I do not have a brief to go into that. That was maybe a response to the specific circumstances and the rather aggressive questioning that the SCVO delegates seemed to receive at that committee.
The SCVO has also raised concerns about the impact of the bill on charities that receive donations through charitable giving. Can you elaborate on your concerns? Could the bill be changed to address those concerns? Can you also update us on whether your on-going discussions with HMRC have proved fruitful or otherwise?
There are two aspects to that. The first is the ill-conceived proposals that were inserted at the last minute into the Calman commission’s report, for which there was apparently no evidence. The proposals that aspects of the definition of charity law should be re-reserved or harmonised seemed simply to reflect some conversation that had been had over dinner and were not the subject of any consultation or proposition whatever. Fortunately, we managed to persuade the secretary of state that those proposals should not be in the bill. However, we heard recently that they had been raised again by members of the Scottish Affairs Committee with a view to reinserting them into the bill. Those proposals do not reflect the diversity of practice that has emerged across the UK; they are simply a set of solutions looking for an issue, as far as I am concerned.
I do not want to go too far into the process, because you have made your views on that clear, but for clarity, I wonder what you submitted to the Calman commission on this.
I think that we gave evidence to the Calman commission.
Yes, but what did you say to it?
I cannot recall offhand, but we gave substantial evidence on some of the issues that we felt ought to be covered by a review of devolution and the proposals that we thought would fit the needs of our sector and the people it works with. We presented to Calman head on, as we do with any consultation. Aspects of the way in which the commission was set up were not as inclusive as they might have been, but some of the real difficulties in the process have emerged since Calman.
You have made considerable points on, and there is some substance in what you say about the linkages between benefits, which are reserved, and care, which is largely devolved; about the employability issues; and about the national lottery. Were those points clearly made to Calman?
Oh, yes.
Okay, so they were submitted.
No, we have not consulted widely on the Scotland Bill. In fact, our members are largely disinterested in it. The current preoccupation with economists’ views about economic growth is not the kind of thing that gets my members out of bed, nor are all the other propositions in the bill. The substance of the bill does not cover areas that my members are interested in. We have a policy view, which we have expressed to the committee, and it reflects the consensus of our elected policy committee on the matter.
As you rightly said, the bill is the sort of thing that voluntary organisations from different sectors and within sectors will almost inevitably have different experiences of and views on.
When a particular issue is at stake—for example, you have heard from the Scottish Federation of Housing Associations about the insolvency propositions—it is quite right that organisations make their case in that way.
Can I ask you more particularly about—
We are very pressed for time.
I just want to ask about this one area, if I may.
Sure.
The substance of what you have said is really about the difficulties that exist, not least in employability and so on. The divide between reserved and devolved functions has to go somewhere, and wherever it goes there will be issues. Is that not best dealt with by tackling the matter on a partnership basis, taking the functions as they are, saying, for example, “Look, there are oddities here and the voluntary sector’s activities are made difficult,” and trying to arrive at practical solutions by applying the powers at both ends? Is there not quite a lot of—
Absolutely. That is how it works from day to day, but we are reviewing devolution after 12 years and considering legislation that will change it, and I believe that there is a case for capturing that experience and seeing where substantial legislative change needs to be made. That change needs to reflect the moving ball of public policy in different arenas. Legislation might well be the best way of resolving any long-term problems with the interface between, for example, health and care.
Martin, please stay with us, as we might well raise other issues of interest.
I will be brief—I promise—in agreeing with Martin Sime about process. Organisations such as ours with a relatively wide membership and democratic process to be observed have found it difficult in the timescales provided to go into the bill in depth and provide the kind of modelling that is required to back up some of the assertions that I am nevertheless going to make. I am probably prepared to go out a bit more on a limb than Martin is able to. It is also an excuse for our not having provided written evidence or comments on specific clauses.
Thank you. I think that my voice is going to fail me.
In its submission to Calman, the STUC recommended that immigration and welfare and social security be included—and, indeed, in perhaps more depth than Calman ended up recommending.
I want to return to the point that Robert Brown raised about where we draw the line. We have received interesting evidence that, as we have control of council tax, we should perhaps have control of council tax benefit and that, as we have housing policy, we should have housing benefit. We have heard that there are issues on the boundary of social care. If we are going to dig holes in the ground, the landfill tax and the aggregates levy perhaps go together. There has been a lot of thoughtful work on that in the written submissions.
We were persuaded by the Calman commission’s view that it is important to maintain the basic sense of social solidarity being equal across the UK. However, some changes at national or local level already imply deviation from that to an extent. Issues such as council tax levels and the quality and nature of tenure already impact on the expectation that an individual has for their welfare. In a sense, we said that that social solidarity framework is good, but if we already have policy that has the potential to impact on it and to make things in some way less even, let us at least ensure that that policy is consistent.
A specific example of that is attendance allowance and how that money was lost in Scotland as a consequence of a decision that we made on free personal care. That is fairly clear evidence that those two things were linked and ought to have been dealt with in that way. There is still a sense of grievance to an extent that the money was lost.
At the risk of delving back into debates that took place earlier and that will be continued in future, it is fair to say that we have looked at the evidence and come to the conclusion that the case is not proven. To proceed on the basis that a more wholesale devolution of taxes would by its nature either grow or shrink an economy would be a mistake.
What should the bill’s main purpose be? If it is not about stimulating the economy, creating jobs and allowing the creation of more wealth for redistribution—perhaps to support the voluntary sector—what is its point?
The bill has several points. One main point is that the Scottish Government’s actions in spending what is currently 60 per cent of public moneys in Scotland should be better reflected in the balance of the funds that it receives. Shifting the mix away from a pure block grant to a system that reflects the tax base somewhat more is important. The Scottish Government already spends 60 per cent of the moneys that are available, and reflecting that is a key aim of the bill.
I will return briefly to corporation tax. You do not want a race to the bottom and you seem to suggest a UK policy on, and a UK level for, corporation tax. However, much of the evidence that we have received makes it clear that the UK Government is at least considering devolving to Northern Ireland the right to set the corporation tax rate. If Northern Ireland had power over corporation tax, would Scotland need to be able to set its own corporation tax rate, to allow us to compete on a level playing field?
I understand your question, but you ask me to hypothesise about something that I do not agree should happen. Even if such devolution happened, some grounds would be different, such as the relationship between the south and north of Ireland. My fundamental point is that the mechanism is poor and is certainly poor for maintaining in the medium to long term a sustainable and fair economy.
I thank Martin Sime and Dave Moxham for their evidence. They can stay with us if they wish to; if they cannot do so, we will understand.
We made a pretty short submission in which we said that we would like the bill to go further. Happily, our interests are generally aligned with those of the Crown Estate, because the value of its sea bed is enhanced by the success of the industry in which we have a major interest. The question is what happens when our interests are not aligned. We are more interested in the policy and the practicalities, as a previous witness said, than in the revenues that go directly to the Crown Estate.
It is important that the legislative opportunity is used to progress the debate on the powers and governance of the Crown Estate Commissioners, which has run for years and years. As Calman and his adviser, Professor Gallagher, observed the other week in London, the Calman proposals are fairly minimal.
You heard it said to Fiona Hyslop that there is the pretty token position of change in the bill and full devolution, which you and the Scottish Government support, but some intermediate positions are also beginning to emerge. You have suggested one: ensuring that, if there is not full devolution, Scottish ministers appoint the commissioner for Scotland. Calum MacDonald has submitted a very interesting paper. There has been some discussion—this perhaps relates to the Orkney interest—about how the devolved Administrations, which have a particular interest in developing renewables and in the current activity of the Crown, can influence those policies more successfully. Will you give us your observations on those intermediate approaches?
Anything that improves accountability and the ability of the Scottish Government and Scottish Parliament to make policy over these Crown rights, which, as I say, the Scottish Parliament already owns—these are Scottish public rights—is to be welcomed. I would have no problem if the committee were to recommend some of those intermediate options. Calum MacDonald’s paper is extremely interesting. It comes from his direct experience as a minister and a forestry commissioner. The one big difference between the Forestry Commission and the Crown Estate is that the Forestry Commission commissioners are accountable to Scottish ministers and the Scottish Parliament has all the powers of policy making over forestry, which is not the case with the Crown Estate.
Given the flow of revenues that might result from the kind of fundamental change that you are talking about and the stage in the development of the Crown’s activities in relation to the next big industry, which arguably will have enormous climate change implications, would it be wise to separate Scotland from the access to expertise and a big pot of resources south of the border from which we could benefit disproportionately to our population share? Would it be possible to retain access to those benefits with the changes that you have rehearsed?
The two benefits that you have outlined are finance and expertise. Expertise in any topic is there to be bought by any organisation that wants it. If the Crown Estate Commissioners were no longer responsible for administering the Crown Estate and it were Marine Scotland or another body in Scotland, that body would buy in the necessary expertise. I do not think that expertise is the problem; there is expertise in Britain. Whoever administers the rights will seek to employ and exploit it to develop the offshore marine renewable industry.
Lucy Parsons might want to answer my next question, as it relates to a point that she made earlier.
I would say that there is a risk. We have an industry that is at a very early stage of development. There is valuable expertise, and continuity and momentum are also valuable. An amendment might bring everything to a halt while we rearrange things and recruit a team. Yes, you can hire expertise, but it has taken the Crown Estate a couple of years to get to the stage of having a competent team to handle the leases at the speed that we want to move. We have something to lose on that front.
I will move on slightly, to ask Andy Wightman a question. You mentioned a few moments ago that Scotland could, in effect, take control of some of these matters—you said that we had the legislative competence to do that. Will you say a word about that? Is that view supported by other legal minds in the system, or is it contentious? How do people regard your view on that?
It is not my view—it is just a statement of fact. You should read the Scottish Law Commission’s “Report on Law of the Foreshore and Sea Bed”. The fact is that Crown property rights are devolved to Scotland under paragraph 3(1) of schedule 5 to the Scotland Act 1998, and that has been recognised by the Treasury committee; it is not a matter of opinion.
Would you say that the Scotland Bill is your preferred route for tackling the set of issues that you have discussed or, notwithstanding what happens with this bill, could they still be handled through the mechanism to which you have alluded?
It would be very messy for the Scottish Parliament to try to rearrange Crown property rights—they are of some antiquity, and that would not be the most productive route to go down. The point is how they are administered, who administers them and where the level of accountability is.
Notwithstanding the significant policy and governance issues that have been played out through the committee, one of the challenges for us is to establish not the desirability of governance or policy changes, but what is appropriate in the context of the Scotland Bill.
One of the problems in that regard is that the Crown Estate Commissioners have muddied the water over the past 10 or 20 years, first by calling themselves the Crown Estate. The Crown Estate is defined in the Crown Estate Act 1961, which states that the
That is the most interesting evidence of the day.
The Crown Estate Commissioners submitted evidence to Calman saying that they owned the sea bed. They do not own the sea bed.
Can you make a distinction between the sea bed and the responsibility between 12 and 200 miles? Does that apply to all of the Crown Estate’s functions and roles?
All of the Crown Estate, as defined by the 1961 act, is administered by the Crown Estate Commissioners. The property rights and interests—the nature of them—are devolved because they are part of Scotland’s law of property. After all, we abolished the Crown as paramount superior in the feudal system. However, the administration of those rights, which is held under the 1961 act by the Crown Estate Commissioners, is reserved. As a body corporate, the Crown Estate commissioners are reserved. The Scottish Parliament cannot interfere with the 1961 act. It cannot interfere with the administration of the act. However, if it wanted to, it could pass a bill tomorrow saying that mussels are no longer a Crown property right.
You have created an interesting area of debate for the committee. Is there any other legal authority that you would encourage the committee to look at in order to reflect on the issues that we have discussed in the past few moments?
I would read the opening pages of the Scottish Law Commission’s “Report on Law of the Foreshore and Sea Bed”, which was initiated by Donald Dewar in 1999 to begin to resolve various problems, one of which was the conflict of interest between the Crown Estate Commissioners as an administrator of the proprietary interests in the foreshore and their duties as a trustee of the public rights over the foreshore. The SLC identified a host of problems back then that have still not been resolved.
I am grateful. That was very helpful in getting on the record the various issues. As there are no further questions on the Crown Estate, we move to Alan Trench.
Thank you, convener. It is a pleasure to appear before the committee.
Take us to a 2:2 and then a 2:1. We are all ears. The Lord Advocate can wait.
Before talking about the things that would be necessary to get it to a 2:1, the first key point, which has been left unclear in the bill, in the accompanying command paper and in speeches—particularly ministerial speeches in the Commons second reading debate last week—is whether the Scotland Bill is the end of a process or a step along a path. If it is a step along a path and it can be acknowledged as such, it makes a valuable contribution despite its flaws.
I urge you to expand on that a little. Compared with the status quo, there will be the mechanism through the UK tax committee, and there is the involvement of the Office for Budget Responsibility and the National Audit Office. Where should we take that range of intergovernmentalism to give the robustness that you seek? In 1998, I observed that many people thought that the process was the end of the road: how wrong they were. What institutional underpinnings would strengthen the formal element?
One thing that the bill and the command paper do is to avoid looking at how the block grant element of Scottish funding works. That element will still account for a substantial amount of the Scottish Government’s funding—the money that the Scottish Parliament can spend. I understand that there are reasons not to approach a review of the quantum of the block grant at the present time. The Chancellor of the Exchequer has taken that off the agenda until the United Kingdom’s finances are restored to health. As members will know, I also have a good deal to do in Wales, where that is a cause of considerable displeasure and alarm, as Wales would stand to benefit appreciably from a review of the block grant in a way that Scotland would be unlikely to.
What will be the character of that line of sight? Every tax director whom we have met has spoken about the desirability of having a single collection agency.
There are plenty of ways of having a single collection agency without necessarily having it just as part of one Government, without the control of others. I am thinking of the arrangements in Canada, where the federal Government collects taxes on behalf of most of the provinces. It collects them for all the provinces bar Quebec—so, for all the English-speaking provinces. All individual taxpayers in Canada fill out a single tax return and pay a single tax; but the money goes directly to provincial Governments as well as to the federal Government. That is all regulated by a detailed document; it is a quasi-legal agreement and it goes into very great detail. That is not the UK way, and I dread to think what such an agreement would look like if it were framed in a UK context. However, it is one possible approach.
I note in passing that no amendments on this financial side have been lodged so far. What you have said has been very helpful.
Could Alan Trench recommend some amendments that might help to improve the bill? In particular, what amendments should we be suggesting to the UK Parliament on the mechanics of borrowing, both revenue and capital and the amounts and the conditions that might be attached? The current suggestion is that there should be an annual limit for revenue borrowing and a total limit that is absolutely tiny—0.6 per cent of the revenue budget. It will be almost impossible for that to work. The same sort of thing will happen on the capital side, where there are restrictions on the amount that can be borrowed in any one year or in any number of years, and restrictions on the total amount of money that can be borrowed.
The borrowing provisions are something of a poser. One of the first questions to arise is whether the borrowing should be done directly by the Scottish Government on the bond markets, or done through HM Treasury—which is what Calman recommended and what the bill suggests.
We are left with the challenge of what to recommend to the UK Government. Most folk are suggesting that the present arrangement will not work. We have heard some thoughts from the cabinet secretary, and he was suggesting a figure of a lot less than 5 per cent—probably about 3 per cent of the departmental expenditure limit per annum as a maximum potential buffer, and not all in the one year. We have to come up with an alternative suggestion.
That is still not an unreasonable figure, except for this fact: although one treats the DEL money as being an allocation as of right and therefore a guaranteed revenue stream that can service borrowing, it is nothing of that sort in law. The legal foundation to the Barnett formula remains very tenuous. It is a statement of funding policy, and it is the unilateral declaration of policy of one Government. I well recall from when I was advising the House of Lords Select Committee on the Barnett Formula that Mr Swinney was keen to point out to that committee that he does not get to sign off the statement of funding policy, even on a technical level, and that agreement to it is signified on behalf of Scotland by the Secretary of State for Scotland, not by a Scottish minister. All the devolved Governments share that concern.
I am interested in your comment about there being too narrow a tax base under the proposals. I wish to contrast that with a statement that you make in your written submission. It states that the system that is proposed under the bill
Yes.
It strikes me that the Government is proposing a constitutional framework that will create a greater degree of autonomy over expenditure and taxes than applies in a mature federal system such as that of the Federal Republic of Germany. I do not think that anyone in Germany says that there is too narrow a tax base, but maybe I am wrong.
You quoted from a short sentence in which I compressed a large number of quite complex ideas. In Germany, practically all taxes are collected by the Länder—
That is collection, not the setting of the rates or the tax base.
Indeed. The reason why I said that there is limited spending autonomy is because of the way in which the German equalisation system works—
I am sorry to interrupt, but I want to be clear, because we have had this debate before. We understand that there is a lot of spending autonomy in the Länder—
There is very little—
I am talking about autonomy in relation to spending on what we might call devolved areas, as opposed to tax setting.
In both cases there are constitutional requirements, which are set out in the basic law, to ensure common living standards across the national territory. Therefore, even if someone lives in a relatively poor part of Germany, such as Mecklenburg-Vorpommern, they will receive a level of public services that is similar to that which is received in a prosperous part of Germany, such as Hessen or Bavaria. That is funded by direct, horizontal transfers from the taxpayers of Hessen and Bavaria, which do not go through the federal Government but are remitted directly—from Wiesbaden or Munich to Schwerin, in the example that I used.
Notwithstanding that, you are saying that the system that we will have if the Scotland Bill is enacted will create greater autonomy than exists in the Federal Republic of Germany.
That is because of the way in which the equalisation system works. For further details, I direct you to a very good presentation by a German colleague from the Bertelsmann Foundation, which you will find on my old website at the University of Edinburgh. He explained exactly how the German system works. I still remember being aghast at the level of complexity and at the absolute level of equalisation according to spending needs across the country. I was sitting there thinking that the system would never work in any English-speaking system, because—
The Canada Health Act does exactly the same thing.
No, it does not—
I am afraid that it does.
No, it does not. The Canada Health Act—
We will have to disagree. There is a federal Canada Health Act, which lays down the standards of health service provision that must apply universally across Canada.
Indeed—but it does so in general terms, rather than in precise terms. I mentioned the Canadian system in the paragraph from which you quoted. Canadian provinces raise—if my memory serves me correctly—about 65 to 70 per cent of their spending. Health care in Canada is supported by a per capita transfer from the federal Government to the various provinces, which accounts for about a third of the total cost of health care. Therefore, the transfer funds a basic level of service in relation to health care for individuals, but the bulk of health care is funded out of own-source taxes that are generated by the Canadian provinces.
Okay.
Yes. That is my understanding. The committee’s learned adviser can put us right if we have misunderstood.
However, in your submission you said that a virtue of the proposals in the bill is that the Scottish Government would get the actual tax revenues, and you were dismissive of an estimating model. I am not sure why you dismiss an estimating model in relation to taxes on earned incomes while regretting the absence of an estimating model in relation to savings and dividends—which was in Calman. I do not see the logic of your approach.
I do so for exactly the reasons that are set out in the Calman report, which was absolutely right on that issue. The administrative complexity and the costs involved with going beyond an estimate of the proceeds of savings and dividends income are such that it makes doing that very hard to do. I would much prefer real figures to be used in every case. However, I want there to be as wide a tax base as possible for the Scottish Parliament. If using an estimate is the means by which we can do that, and the alternative is not having that element of the tax base, I would accept that as being the lesser of the two evils.
We will talk about evils at another point.
That is true, which perhaps suggests that there should be a different approach to CGT. I threw that suggestion in partly in an attempt to follow the logic of Calman, which is absolutely right—in all of the arguments about fiscal federalism it is agreed that taxes relating to land are the best ones to devolve to lower levels of Government, whether they be subnational units such as Scotland or even local authorities. However, I accept that there are profound flaws.
I am acutely aware of the passage of time, so we will end this part of the meeting. I thank the panel members for their attendance. We will suspend to allow the Lord Advocate to take her place.
Our final witness today is the Rt Hon Elish Angiolini QC, the Lord Advocate. I am delighted that she has joined us and I apologise for the lateness. We sometimes have long meetings on the committee. I understand that this may be the Lord Advocate’s last appearance at a parliamentary committee before she steps down at the coming elections. On behalf of all members of the committee and, I am sure the Parliament, I thank her for her public service and wish her well in the future.
I ask the Lord Advocate to make any opening remarks, after which we will move to what I hope will be rather brief questions.
I do not intend to make opening remarks. I am happy to proceed immediately to questions.
The significant issue is section 57(2) of the Scotland Act 1998. When we had the Minister for Culture and External Affairs before us earlier, she expressed understandable anxiety that proposed clauses on the issue are not in the public domain and she spoke about the need for on-going consultation on the issue. Today is very much about taking stock of where we have reached thus far. You will have had the opportunity to see the evidence that we received at last week’s meeting.
I add to those of the convener my good wishes for your future after the election, Lord Advocate.
I thank members for their good wishes.
I want to be clear, because we need to have a sense of the overarching scheme before we try to fiddle about with the details to ensure that they are right. Do you dissent from the general proposition that there should be a constitutional role for the Supreme Court? That is the central issue that takes us beyond the treaty of union and the sole jurisdiction of the Scottish courts.
The Supreme Court’s constitutional role is crucial in the context of the Scotland Act 1998, and not simply in relation to criminal proceedings, but because of general issues of competence between and among the various devolved Administrations. It has the role of reconciling issues regarding the competence of ministers as well as the role of assessing the parameters of devolution.
In terms of ECHR obligations, is there a cross-cutting level for which we need an element of symmetry across the United Kingdom, whether for criminal matters or other things? Do we not then have an issue about the speed of justice? I am not saying that the Supreme Court is hugely fast, but it is an awful lot faster, if I am not very much mistaken, than going to Strasbourg and it is more convenient for people. Am I right in saying that there are no Scottish judges on the European Court and that it can take three, four or five years to get a determination there? Leaving aside the threshold issue, is there a considerable advantage for access to, and the speed of, justice in having available application, in certain limited circumstances, to the Supreme Court of the United Kingdom?
You will be aware that one of our concerns, which the expert group identified, was the question of delays that are brought about because of the existence of the new tier of appeal, which is what the Supreme Court has brought about for Scotland. There have been instances where the Supreme Court has responded very vigorously. Recently, I referred five cases up to the Supreme Court, which are collateral issues arising from the Cadder case, in order to ensure that those matters may be dealt with and achieve certainty sooner rather than, say, 18 months down the line. I took that factor into account in my decision to refer those cases.
That comes back to the gatekeeper function that you talked about before.
Yes.
It may be something that is easier put in writing later, but I wonder whether you would like to elaborate a bit on it and say how you think it should operate: what the criteria should be and whether it goes beyond just the discretion of the High Court on the one hand or the Supreme Court on the other, and whether there is a framework of golden rules, if you like, that could be set down to guide and, I suppose, to restrict the flow of the tap that comes through that direction.
It could be left to the courts to develop their own jurisprudence, based on an ordinary provision of leave. The difficulty with that, however, is that it would not give the courts a steer as to what should be considered. Although, as I mentioned, the expert group referred to international obligations, that can be fairly small beer in terms of the nature of the subject matter that is under consideration.
Is it not just a breach of human rights that leads to a miscarriage of justice? We are not quite as open as that perhaps suggests.
The suggestion that you have articulated is a very wide proposition, because those things are not mutually exclusive. We have our common law and our law of evidence. Fundamental rights, which have been recognised for centuries in Scotland and which are also characterised as human rights, or convention rights, are not at all mutually exclusive; they are not two separate streams of jurisprudence.
That does seem to speak to the desirability of our making some progress, albeit at this 11th hour of trying to reach agreement. I simply say to the Lord Advocate that for those of us who are non-experts—of which I freely admit I am one—there seemed to be a considerable degree of agreement among the stakeholders around the table that the bill was the right way to resolve the issue.
As I said, the Advocate General has been open to discussion on that, and we intend to meet later. I have offered the assistance of my officials to make observations on what the problem may be. I am not sure whether the people who were here last week had seen the draft clause: they certainly had only a very short period in which to consider it, given that it materialised only the night before.
How many challenges have there been to the legislation as opposed to acts of the Lord Advocate, which have been the centre point of the issue?
There have been challenges to legislation and to the common law. I am happy to write to the committee with details. Mr Gibson, who is the head of the appeals office in the Crown Office, advises me that we are aware of at least three cases that would challenge the vires of the legislation in relation to the Lord Advocate.
“Potentially” is the operative word, I presume.
Absolutely, but it is that security that is relevant when you are talking about consistency of approach. Likewise, if a trial judge breaches article 6 by making an outrageous direction to the jury, in which he misleads the jury about the law, that would be justiciable under the Human Rights Act 1998 and therefore would not go up to the Supreme Court.
I think that we need to sort out some of the details of this matter at a later date, for the sake of clarity.
I appear before you with two hats on. I am here as a member of the Government and as the Lord Advocate. The constitutional role, which involves the issue of partial referral, is a retained responsibility in that there is no collective responsibility with my colleagues in that regard. The same applies to the prosecutorial role. My other portfolio functions are a matter of collective responsibility with the other ministers. I have no portfolio responsibility as Lord Advocate other than that of giving advice and legal advice to my colleagues, and I am responsible for the advice that they are given. Policy is a matter for ministers rather than for the Lord Advocate.
Obviously, a lot of detailed discussion will go on between the Advocate General and yourself. What will interest the committee with regard to where we ultimately alight on the issue of what can or cannot be said in the initial LCM that will come before the Parliament is the question of how much distance exists in terms of principle, so I will ask a couple of questions that will try to probe that.
That question is premised on the misapprehension that all public authorities make their way to the Supreme Court, and that there should therefore be consistency in that regard. However, that is not the case in criminal proceedings at the moment. A decision by the court in criminal proceedings would still be for the appeal court in Scotland to deal with. There is not evenness, in that regard.
But on convention rights—
Yes, on convention rights as well. The High Court of Justiciary is a public authority in terms of the Human Rights Act 1998, but if it is sitting in a criminal matter, section 124 of the Criminal Procedure (Scotland) Act 1995 would apply, except in so far as the matter is a devolution issue, and the matter only becomes a devolution issue because of the Lord Advocate.
So there is, in that sense, an issue of principle as well as the emphasis of—
Yes, I think that your assumption is that the convention applies in all cases. I have to make it absolutely clear that the Lord Advocate is not suggesting that she should somehow have a limited susceptibility to convention rights challenges. Of course, it is absolutely imperative that the Human Rights Act 1998 applies to her in the same way as it applies to other public authorities. What I am talking about is the route by which, and the level at which, all those issues are determined by courts. The expert group and the Advocate General are attempting to limit those two truly constitutional issues. My concern is that the draft provisions—which I suspect will change substantially—do not achieve that, so I believe that substantial work is required in order to ensure that they deliver what the expert group and the Advocate General wish to achieve.
In that vein, the committee has said that, although we think that the situation is slightly unfortunate, we understand the reasons why the matter emerged at so late a stage in the process. We should simply allow further evidence to come forward toward the end of the month. At that point, we will see where we are and decide what we feel able to say to the Parliament. You will clearly be working until the last minute, and we wish you well with those discussions. Please write to us at the end of the month, when there is greater clarity around the issues and you might have been able to find common ground on the drafting—or not.