I formally welcome all the witnesses who will give evidence today.
I would like just to pull out a few points from our submission. We must recognise that there has been a lot of controversy since the inception of the private finance initiative. For example, there was sustained local opposition to the Skye bridge project. One of the most significant factors locally is that, as a recent survey showed, only one in 10 senior public sector financial managers expressed strong support for the statement:
Thank you. The next witness is Philip Grant, who is head of infrastructure finance at the Bank of Scotland.
I will keep my comments brief and focus on what we fund and why we fund it. I will also make a few comments on the issue of value for money in PFI/PPP and on the cost of private capital, which is a feature of the on-going debate.
I will stop you there because we need only brief introductory statements. I am sure that you will be able to bring out your other points during questioning.
Thank you. I am the technical director at CIPFA. I am joined by my colleagues, David Dorward from Dundee City Council and Lynn Brown, head of corporate finance at City of Edinburgh Council. Both my colleagues are practitioners and have first-hand experience of working with PFI schemes.
I ask Bill Davidson of NorthLink Orkney and Shetland Ferries to address the committee. Am I right in thinking that you will speak in a personal capacity, based on your experience over a number of years?
Yes.
I thank all our witnesses. We have a range of questions to put to you.
As has been stated, many of the arguments relating to PFI/PPP and more traditional methods of finance are political. What do you see as the major improvements that are offered by taking the PFI/PPP route? If there were unlimited funds or easier access to funding for capital projects in the public sector and there were real choices, would significant benefits still be offered by taking the PFI/PPP route instead of using public sector funding?
I could list benefits of the PFI/PPP approach from my experience, but I would like to highlight two in particular. First, the whole-life cost of a facility is considered—the provision of an asset and a service—and there is no concentration on the initial capital cost. I can take members to a hospital in Scotland that was built under the old lowest-capital-cost regime. It has cost an absolute fortune to run and maintain from the day it was opened. There have been maintenance, heating and lighting costs, but the layout of the wards is such that staffing levels must be much higher. The head of one patient and the feet of two others can be seen from the nurses' station. Consideration of lowest capital cost meant a lowest-capital-cost product, which inevitably costs a fortune to run.
Are you referring to Ninewells hospital in Dundee?
No.
I was just checking.
Why is one approach related to the public sector and the other related to the private sector?
Traditionally there has been an emphasis on lowest capital cost in the public sector rather than on the whole-life cost of a facility. That was a failing in the way in which projects were carried out in the public sector.
Could not we simply insist that if the public sector itself were to procure, it should consider the whole-life cost, too? Why should a project go to the private sector before that approach is taken?
I agree that if the public sector took a PFI/PPP approach to projects and considered whole-life costs, there would be considerably better value for money over the life of those projects.
I will not accuse you of being a late convert, but when you were involved at the front line in the public sector, did lifetime costs feature in any of the projects with which you were involved? Did they feature in preparatory discussions with clients, or were they excluded from the discussions?
We never considered the full lifetime costs at the NHS. Capital costs were considered. Frequently, unusual decisions were made so as to spend capital budgets by the end of the financial year. That was a result of how the NHS worked at the time.
Brian Adam wanted to say something, but I noticed that Lynn Brown offered to comment on the same question. I invite her to do so. Brian Adam will then have an opportunity to say something.
I am speaking from a City of Edinburgh Council perspective about what happened in our recent PPP. At the outset, there must be a public sector comparator that considers the whole life-cycle costs if unlimited money were available from the public sector. That is compared with the PFI model. The difference is risk transfer. Risk is moved to where it can be best managed. The bottom line is that if the public sector comparator provides better value for money than the modelling on PFI, one should not go ahead with PFI. There should be incredible detail so that anyone can see the whole outline and final business case. That should be considered at the outset.
Mr Davidson suggested that one of the advantages of PFI/PPP is nailing down the whole project in advance, but given the length of these contracts, which tends to be 30 years, the services that are to be delivered will change. How do you allow for the flexibility that will be needed in the system to accommodate those changes? Some of the changes that will happen in the public sector procurement process will be as a consequence of changes in the nature of the service delivery.
You are right that there will be changes. The health service is a classic example of that. In the 1960s, lots of people had to go into hospital for major ulcer operations, whereas nowadays that is done almost on a day-case basis. The incidence of disease and the way in which we treat it change considerably, and the types of facilities that we need change considerably, so the buildings must be designed to be flexible.
Can you give us some examples of where that has happened, or are you just saying what should happen in future? Is it correct that none of those contracts has got to the end yet?
That is the problem. There are no examples to point to where we can say, "That was a 15-year deal and they carried out refurbishment just before they left." Financing, for example, for road resurfacing is built into the financial plan. The money is there to be drawn down at the appropriate period, to fund the costs of the works that are to be done.
I will address that final point. With the projects that we undertake, it is normal for the public sector to establish a standard of facilities at the point of handover. That normally includes quite a large amount of what would be termed life-cycle spending towards the back end, particularly from about year 25 to the end. The funders, for example banks or fund providers, ensure that during the project there is sufficient reserving of cash so that at the point when work is required, cash is available to be spent on the facility, because it is important to them as lenders and shareholders for the contractual obligations on standards to be met.
PFI/PPP has not been running for an enormous length of time and, as you say, none of the contracts has come to an end. In your opinion, has there been any significant change, since PFI started off, in how organisations set up arrangements and put them into place? You mentioned Edinburgh and Glasgow schools refurbishment.
I think Vernon Soare mentioned a change that we have seen recently. One of the original arguments for PFI was that it would allow investment in public services without its being considered part of the public sector borrowing requirement. There has been a significant change away from that. With most PFI projects that are being signed off now, my impression is that the investment is considered part of the PSBR in the sense that PFI is being recognised as a way of financing the investment. In essence, PFI is just another way of borrowing money.
I wonder whether you could identify what sorts of areas are more appropriate for PFI/PPP. In the first session of our inquiry, one of the witnesses said that he believes that PFI works well with projects such as prisons and roads, but less well with hospital and school projects. I am aware that that contradicts some of today's evidence, particularly Bill Davidson's. Is there are a general view? It is clearly not a case of one size fits all.
I would like to amplify that. Across the piece, are we learning which risks it is more appropriate to transfer? Rather than asking about schools, hospitals or roads, we should ask whether we are learning for which things the private sector manages the risk better and for which things the public sector manages it better—or is learning to manage it better.
I am not sure that that is the question that I am going to answer.
If you answer the first one, you can pass on the other one.
I will deal with whether we are learning about PFI projects. In Dundee, we had a PFI on a waste energy plant back in 1993-94. The contractual basis of that and the negotiations that we went through were complex. In our current work for education—on schools—I have noticed a significant improvement in the pre-tender stage and in the structure of the contracts and the negotiations. In that respect, the Scottish Executive has got its house in order by promoting PFI, which it was not doing five or six years ago.
The public sector comparator is an important issue. Is one always available? We discussed the matter at a previous meeting and that was identified as the problem. Can you construct a reliable model?
One of the issues with the public sector comparator is that you are often looking for a new method of service delivery that involves capital and services being wrapped up together and provided through a partnership. It can be difficult to find a public sector comparator that allows a like-with-like comparison, because PFI brings a new slant to delivering a service. Therefore, you may not always be able to find an exact public sector comparator.
I can speak only for the City of Edinburgh Council. We would not go ahead without the public sector comparator, because it is crucial to prove to the Scottish Executive and to our auditors that we are achieving value for money. I cannot speak about elsewhere, but the assumption is that the money is available. You then consider the transfer of risk and who would best manage it, to produce the bottom line figure.
Have you always been able to put together a public sector comparator?
Yes. You have to do it before the outline business case, before you go to the market and say that you are interested in going into a PFI project. The bidders and those who want to enter into those projects with us are also looking for that. The public sector comparator must be in place for the outline business case. It is updated for the final business case, when the deal is signed.
When Andy Wynne speaks, I ask him to clarify a point that he made earlier. You talked about some projects being on balance sheet. Will you explain what you meant by that? I thought that they would necessarily be off balance sheet. Perhaps I picked you up incorrectly.
There are two closely related issues. One is whether the asset will be considered an asset of the public sector entity: will the hospital building be considered to belong to the trust and appear on its balance sheet. Connected to that is whether it is considered to be part of public sector borrowing and within public sector borrowing limits.
I thought that you said earlier that, since June, most NHS projects have been on balance sheet. Does that mean that they are not PFI projects?
No. Before then, a condition of a project's being considered a PFI project was that it was off the balance sheet and therefore not part of public sector borrowing. Since then, Alan Milburn has said that that condition is not necessary; a project can still be considered a PFI project if the building is on the balance sheet of the trust, for example. The capital investment will now be included in the public sector borrowing limit.
Does that mean that, in these cases, the asset—the hospital or whatever—belongs to the health board once it is built and that what remains is a maintenance contract for the lifetime of the health board's asset? I cannot see how it can be on the balance sheet if it does not belong to the health board.
There is a difference between the accounting treatment of the asset and the legal position. It is possible for the asset legally to belong to the private sector consortium and still be on the balance sheet of the public sector organisation.
Let me describe the experience in Scottish local government. If a PFI scheme was put on the balance sheet, it would score against the local authority's capital consent, which would defeat the object. No authority could afford to initiate a PFI scheme on the balance sheet. Therefore, one of the priorities is to get the external auditor for each public sector body to certify that a scheme is off the balance sheet.
That was our understanding, which is why we were surprised by what Mr Wynne said. As this is a crucial point, I shall allow a couple more questions on it. I ask David Davidson and Brian Adam to ask their questions briefly.
I understood that what a council would be looking to put on the balance sheet was the fact that a facility was available. In other words, a facility could be treated like a long-term lease and there would not be a capital transaction on the balance sheet. That is what has caused the confusion. The fact of the council having a legal right to use the facility has a value, but it is not a cost to the service—it is a notional situation. I presume that, under resource accounting and budgeting, if there is a charge at all it will be an annual charge based on the usability of the facility rather than the capital transaction costs. Is that correct?
There are two, different, situations. In PFI projects, the asset may or may not be on the balance sheet. For most PFI projects involving the health service, prisons and roads, the assets are on the balance sheet of the public sector entity and are part of the public sector borrowing requirement. As David Dorward said, the exceptions involve local authorities—perhaps in the building of schools. In those situations, local authorities do not have a choice. This is important and it goes back to the public sector comparator. The choice is not between using public finance and using a PFI or PPP; the choice is between investing in schools and other infrastructure assets or not investing. The public sector comparator is not a level-playing-field option appraisal between direct investment and a PPP; it is an exercise that is necessary to show the Treasury that the PFI option will provide value for money and will be affordable.
The discretion that local authorities and other public bodies have over maintenance budgets has meant that choices have had to be made between maintenance and services. Although there is considerable wisdom in building in lifetime maintenance costs, there may be a significant adverse effect on other services that are provided by such bodies because they will no longer have that discretion. When will that start to bite?
I am not sure whether that point was aimed at a particular witness or whether it was just a statement.
No one wants to answer that question.
Before we move on to questions about best value—
Convener, Lynn Brown wants to give an answer.
One of the key things is affordability. What the council can afford needs to be considered. For example, City of Edinburgh Council can afford its current schools PPP. The council is not losing the discretion to spend on other areas. The PPP actually helps. Because 16 per cent of Edinburgh's schools will be new, money will be released that can be invested in the maintenance that is required in the schools that are not new. The PPP allows a switch of resources.
I worked in the public sector for 30 years and it seemed to me that maintenance costs were cut every time there was a financial problem. We are now seeing the eventual costs of that: a totally disastrous infrastructure. Often, the infrastructure requires total replacement. I experienced that in a number of sectors.
We must restrict ourselves to questions rather than statements, otherwise we will not get through all our questions.
The proportion is small. When people are exposed to the statistics about the level of public sector procurement that is still carried on within a set framework, they are surprised that the public sector has not completely committed all its procurement options to PFI.
It often appears as if that is the case.
In our experience, the extent to which PFI works well is largely a function of how much experience people have of dealing with PFI. Earlier, you asked where the improvements have been. The improvements have been in projects that are based on accommodation: hospitals, schools, prisons, court buildings, police stations and so on.
The convener mentioned that only about 10 per cent of capital investment comes from PFI. People may not be surprised that so much public procurement is still financed by traditional methods because the cost of capital that comes from borrowing with a Government guarantee is much lower than the cost of capital from the private sector.
In an earlier answer, you mentioned different methods of delivering public services. Can you expand on that? What else did you have in mind?
We are keen that the capital control framework in local government should be freed up, so that local authorities are not tied in either to providing a service themselves or to opting for a PFI project.
I would like to set out for the committee the alternatives to PFI that we have used in Edinburgh. We support CIPFA's view that PFI is one among a range of options.
Those are useful examples. Am I right in thinking that the council establishes not-for-profit companies?
No. New Edinburgh Ltd, which developed Edinburgh Park, is 50 per cent owned by the EDI Group. It has shared dividends—it is a dividend distribution company. We are developing the waterfront with Lothian and Edinburgh Enterprise Limited. We are a 50:50 shareholder and the assumption is that we will reinvest in the waterfront.
Do you see EDI and similar companies as just an alternative form of public sector investment?
We see that as an alternative form of partnership between the private and public sectors. It is an option for us for public investment in large services.
But it releases local authorities from the constraints that they are under in terms of having direct investment into new capital projects.
It does not count against our capital consent but it is a different regime. It works in the private sector with a board of directors and so on. It is wholly owned by the council—we are the only shareholder.
When it comes to deciding which partnership you are going to go into—you described a number of them—do you consider the end project and a means to deliver it, or do you consider the avenues and what you can deliver through those avenues? You have obviously developed a critical management style in your department.
We look at what the council wants to achieve with its investment, then we consider the best vehicle to do that. The bottom line is always what the council hopes to do with investing its assets.
So basically you consider the end product then the way to deliver it.
The best value for money for delivery, yes.
Your leisure services are a not-for-profit, charitable company. Did you compare that against the possibility of a private finance initiative for those services? Why was that model chosen? Was it a political decision or was there a financial basis for it?
We looked at that back in 1997/98. We had to ensure that we were working within the compulsory competitive tendering legislation. We considered different options and the one we went for was the one that the council felt was the best option in terms of what it wanted to achieve with its leisure services. That option was able to deliver enough investment for the council to reinvest and have no closures.
I am just wondering whether some of the other witnesses might say that that was not the most efficient or financially beneficial way of doing it.
Your inquiry is happening at an interesting time because a lot of work is going on in the public and private sectors to develop the PFI model that we are discussing today. From a local authority requesting that a director be appointed to the special purpose company to represent the council's interests, to a local authority wishing to have a partnership where the council makes a form of investment within the project to ensure that its interests are aligned with that project, there is an increasing appetite among local authorities in particular to become more closely involved in the delivery of their projects through a partnership model.
You have given us considerable food for thought, but we have to move on, as there are a number of areas that we want to cover.
I would like Lynn Brown to expand on the different models. How do you judge best value when choosing a model? How can we determine which of the options of PPP, PFI and the public sector route offers best value? Are there any projects whose outcomes have clearly demonstrated that better value has been obtained through the use of private finance than would have been the case through the use of public finance?
That is a difficult question to answer. With regard to the regeneration of the city—Edinburgh Park and the EICC were very much a part of that—the council did not have a shopping list of options from which it chose PFI. The council owned the land and wanted to control what happened in that area. The option that it chose of having a wholly owned company with expertise brought in from the private sector suited that purpose.
There are two aspects to making the decision between direct public sector investment and PFI or PPP. On one side, there are the figures that the accountants have provided. One will be told that project A will cost one sum and project B will cost another sum. On the other side, there is the subjective element that relates to which project is thought to be most likely to produce better services. It is important to recognise that both sides are involved in the decision. It is easy to look at the figures and tell which project is cheaper, but the decision about the quality of the services must be a political one, as it does not involve the comparison of like with like.
That point is important. There is a suspicion that the pint pot is determined and then things are squeezed into it. If a PFI hospital has problems, bed numbers and staffing are reduced. That happened, for example, with the new Edinburgh royal infirmary, which is one of the models that the committee will consider. Because PFI hospitals seem to be more expensive, the result is a high-quality but smaller service. Is that valid?
I worked in the NHS and spent about 15 years doing a variety of projects for it, so I know it fairly well. You are correct that a typical PFI hospital has a reduced number of beds in comparison to the existing bed stock. One of the characteristics of the NHS acute sector is that its use of beds is not very efficient. The reason is that most hospitals are not oriented to the type of health care services that are delivered today. Research shows that, in an average acute hospital, a person who goes in as a cold case for an elective procedure can spend up to 80 per cent of their time waiting for something to happen. An awful lot of time and effort is wasted in current NHS hospitals.
The best PFI hospital schemes are those that engage with clinicians for some time at the design and bidding stages to ensure that the clinical aspects of the care model that is wanted are represented in the design. A partnership between trusts and the companies that provide the services is required to ensure that the care model and the service delivery model are compatible. A lot of work is put in at the trust, clinical and private sector levels to ensure that good schemes are compatible at the design stage.
I will pick up on the two examples that Bill Davidson gave. One was about a pharmacy closing at noon and the other was about a hospital with no mortuary. I am puzzled as to why those situations would have been different under PFI. I presume that the example of the pharmacy has something to do with running an existing establishment—what you describe is just inefficiency in running the establishment. Were you suggesting that the contractor should run the whole hospital and therefore that contractors are more efficient?
I will respond to the second point first. I was using that situation as an example of a hospital that was built through the old public sector finance route. There were only enough funds to build the hospital in two phases. Funds were allocated for phase 1, which was built. Four hundred patients were to be transferred into that building and services were to be delivered there, but phase 2 had not even been designed, let alone built. The hospital was going to operate on two sites, several miles apart. No one had provided for a mortuary in phase 1. The scheme was originally a whole, but it was cut in half.
Are you saying that split schemes would not exist under PFI because enough money would be available for the whole scheme?
Yes. On the pharmacy, I was drifting towards the point that, when PFI began, there was a lot of discussion about how far down the service spectrum to take it. Consider all the services in a typical hospital. We start with maintenance, engineering and cleaning. We continue through the service spectrum to, for example, laboratories, the pharmacy, radiology and the provision of nursing services and then to the doctors and surgeons. There was much debate about how far through that spectrum the outsourcing of services to a contractor should go.
That argument would apply equally well further up the spectrum. The logic would presumably be to contract out the nursing and clinical services as well, would it not? Go on: be provocative.
I accept that, if we want to push the argument to its limit, we will likely end up with what I describe as the Kwik-Fit approach to medicine. Thirty years ago, we took our cars to the local dealer for everything, but now we go to different specialist outlets for tyres, exhausts, brakes, windows, electrical work and body work. Those places specialise in small parts of the overall care to our cars, but we still have general dealers to whom we take the car for the complex parts. Most NHS hospitals are clogged up with people who do not need high-tech expertise to deal with the routine work. From the perspective of efficiency—I accept that there are many other factors—that is not a good way of delivering health care services.
Given your experience of PFI and PPP, what is your understanding of the costs and time associated with determining whether such a project is worth while? In particular, I would like you to apply your mind to the value of the current process for determining public sector comparators. For example, is the discount rate realistic or sensible?
I will give a swift response and then allow others to respond. A characteristic of a PFI or PPP project is the phenomenal amount of time, effort and money that goes in before the contract is signed. As a result, the period up to the signing of the contract is considerably longer than for a conventional project. However, our experience shows that the construction phase of projects—be they roads or hospitals or whatever—is diminishing dramatically because more time has been spent on the planning phase, which means that more work can be done in parallel and the asset can be delivered much more quickly. I feel that the time and money that is spent up-front on individual projects is well worth while to ensure that all the details have been sorted out before people rush into digging foundations and laying bricks.
Is it right and fair that the significant costs involved in that part of the process are not considered in assessments of whether the public procurement route or the PFI or PPP route should be taken?
The costs are obviously included in the successful bidder's price. He has to recover his costs—
Yes, but the point that I am making is that those costs are not included in the assessment of which of the two routes should be taken. They are discounted.
Yes, there is an interesting point on whether an allowance should be made for those costs in the public sector comparator. We talked a lot about public sector comparators on the way to this meeting. They are not a soft touch. The data that one puts into them have to be based on something. For example, in a roads project, one has to consider the evidence of previous experience, late delivery or over-budget delivery before one puts numbers into the public sector comparator—
In the A74/M6 PFI, the costs of the development process were not included in the public sector comparator. Audit Scotland felt that that was inappropriate. When that factor was included, the benefit—or otherwise—to the public purse was marginal. You have answered the point about time scales, but I want to ask all the witnesses whether the costs of the development process should be taken into account.
You probably are correct. The only point that I would make is that, as more experience has been gained, the amount of effort and time required for the process has reduced rather than increased.
For the City of Edinburgh Council, the rules changed halfway through. The auditors said clearly in the code of practice that development costs had to be written off in the year that they were incurred. Previously, local authorities had assumed that they could do that over the 30 years of the concession.
Are you saying that PFI or PPP is becoming a cheaper product to develop and therefore a more affordable option?
It is becoming cheaper to develop. Whether it is more affordable depends on the affordability factor for the particular project. For example, the City of Edinburgh Council was lucky in having a number of surplus sites that were attractive to developers. That put our affordability at a certain level. Each project in each council will have a different affordability factor.
Do the other witnesses agree that, across the country and in different sectors, there is a trend towards reducing costs in the new partnership exercises?
There is a clear trend. Efficiency is coming through in the procurement programme—in the bidding and development costs of projects. To be honest, there is still a long way to go. On average, projects take 18 months to develop. The private sector must go through various stages starting with the OJEC—the Official Journal of the European Communities—all the way through various acronyms. Costs may be incurred at four or five stages until the preferred bidder is chosen, and all that cost must be taken at risk.
We used to say that any PFI project would progress as fast as the slowest person—the most inexperienced. Sadly, it has been my experience that people from the public sector are frequently the most inexperienced. When people turn up for a new project, the financial, legal and technical people know one another from previous projects and know exactly how far the banks will go, but the public sector people are not very good at building on the experience that they gain from one project and taking that to another. The one exception is in the Ministry of Defence's purchasing of major equipment. It has a central pool that moves from project to project. In Scotland, health bodies and local government share little information.
That situation is changing. The City of Edinburgh Council, its officers and their advisers have been more than a match for the private sector in their ability to keep pace with the project and to deliver to the timeline and to the expectations of all parties. The Scottish Executive and local authorities have done much to have the public sector and the people who represent it operating efficiently through the process.
It must be appreciated that elements of the development review would have to be conducted even in a traditional procurement process. If a large scheme to build eight or nine secondary schools were to be delivered through traditional procurement, a large element of the development costs would still be incurred. Not all the development costs of a PFI should be considered additional costs.
I am happy to accept that, but the initial experience with PFI was that it incurred considerable extra costs that were not included in the assessment of whether a project should proceed.
I will return to your initial question. Different options must be considered. People should consider not just one figure, but a range of figures. You mentioned the discount rate, which has been 6 per cent since 1991.
The rate is far too high, given the current fiscal climate and likely fiscal climate in the future. That fact significantly disadvantages the public sector comparator.
A range of scenarios should be considered. We could say, "If we had a 6 per cent discount rate, perhaps the PFI project would be X per cent cheaper, but what would happen if the rate were 5 per cent or 4 per cent?" Other options could be considered in a similar way. For example, you talked about the initial professional fees. We can argue about whether they should be included in considerations, but perhaps we should consider both positions. We can make comparisons with and without all those professional fees included.
From a private sector point of view—
I am sorry, Brian, but we are against the clock. Lots of information has to be obtained, but you must move on to another question.
I will make a couple of other points on the process. We are talking about acquiring public assets and services, so the user or the citizen ought to have a voice. How does that work? There has been considerable public disquiet before and after some projects. How does such consultation fit in with the pattern of PFI/PPP?
I have a comment on the involvement of citizens' or users' views. From local government's point of view, the best-value initiative has brought into sharper focus the need to consult citizens. I am not saying that that was not done before, but best value has introduced a new framework in which to do it.
Brian Adam suggests that commercial confidentiality is a problem. I suggest to the committee that it recommend that, when such comparisons are undertaken, the details of the option appraisals—the comparisons between the PFI project and the direct public investment—are made available at some point. That would allow research to be undertaken to consider across the board the relative costs of PFI and direct public investment.
Before I bring in Lynn Brown, I should say that that is my experience of PFI contracts. I will be interested to hear the experience of other witnesses, in particular Mr Grant, as he mentioned the Glasgow schools project.
I will speak from an Edinburgh perspective. The point about consultation is a good one. Consultation is crucial to PPP being taken forward positively.
In many ways, if a local authority is involved in a school project, the private sector regards the local authority as the body that represents the interests of the communities that it serves.
That was the point at which the problem to which I referred arose. Once the preferred bidder had been announced, and the plans had emerged, local communities said that they wanted more than that, or something different, but by then it was too late to influence the process.
It all comes down to the public sector stating its service and facilities requirements. The private sector consults extensively on its design. It holds focus groups, goes out into the communities and holds meetings. It wants to gather information so that it can produce the optimal solution.
In Dundee, PFI has delivered through a joint-venture company in which the local authority is a 40 per cent shareholder. The deal for the plant was completed in 1997 and the construction was completed in 2000. Since then, six-monthly reports have been presented to the local authority, in open session, on what has taken place at the plant and the financial arrangements between the local authority and the joint-venture company. We have also set up a better-neighbourhood agreement with local community groups, so that the joint-venture company can hold regular meetings with the local community about the operation of the plant. We did that not because the plant is a PFI vehicle, but because we wanted to take on board the local community's concerns about the type of plant that was being provided under the PFI venture.
I want to move on to what happens once a decision—whether PFI or PPP—has been made. In your experience, what are the critical factors that make the public-private split a success and what evidence do you have to demonstrate that point?
The co-operation between the local authority—or the trust, or whatever the public body is—and the private sector is increasingly being held up as a sign of success. Good schemes are those that are regarded as genuine partnerships. "Partnerships" tends to be an overused word in this sector, but in some projects there is a close relationship between the public and private sectors. For example, we are involved in the funding of Law hospital, which opened earlier this year. The management of that project is a shared responsibility between the trust and the special purpose company, or SPC. Senior representatives of the trust and representatives from the private sector meet at a monthly forum that has a set agenda of reviewing the quality of service delivery and making specific recommendations. That is a genuine partnership. Everyone relies on the contractual framework, but overlaying that are strong partnership relationships. When people rely on just the contract and the contractual relationship, that level of co-operation and understanding is lacking and that can cause problems for a scheme's operation.
Do you have to tick particular boxes to assess where the project is going after the contract has been signed? Are there specific points that are critical if both sides are to feel that the project is going where it is supposed to go?
Yes. On any scheme, after a contract has been signed, the next major milestone is commissioning—the point at which the asset or service is provided. There has been much learning from experience over recent years, in particular over the past 12 months, about the importance of co-operation during transitional phases and during the commissioning of assets. That is a key point. Once the asset is operating, the whole risk matrix changes. Up to that point, there is, in effect, a construction environment in which there is a well-established means—transferred straight from the construction industry—of monitoring progress and risk in delivery.
I will answer, then ask Lynn Brown to talk about performance indicators and other matters in some of the contracts in Edinburgh.
It would be helpful if she also talked about the effectiveness of the monitoring arrangements.
Philip Grant talked about a spirit of partnership and not relying on a contract. That is key, but a contract is still needed because the process is output-driven. The regime that is linked to that means that, if our partner does not deliver, we have comeback because of the contract. We would not go to each page of the contract to win our point, but the existence of the contract helps in any argument.
As that answer demonstrated, it is difficult to point to a success in relation to PFI. It is still early days. The first PFI contracts were signed in 1997, which means that the oldest are only four years old. Given that the contracts are supposed to last for up to 35 years, four years is not enough time to see how things are going.
Is there a danger that, because a council that has entered into a few PFI arrangements has tied up a large part of its revenue stream over an extended period, the flexibility of its budgeting arrangements will be lost and it will be locked in to a spending plan for a long period, even if circumstances change?
That is a problem. We said earlier that it could be argued that an advantage of PFI projects is that they will avoid the backlog maintenance situation. In the health service, individual health trusts have chosen to cut back on maintenance and to maintain services in other ways. If those trusts feel that they do not have enough money, they have chosen not to maintain their buildings sufficiently but to spend the money on nurses, doctors, accountants and administrators.
Bill Davidson's submission states:
When I wrote that, I was thinking not so much about the IT side, but about school facilities that might be affected by demographic shifts.
Various points have been made about accountability, relationships and, from the public perspective, who is responsible for what. The Edinburgh model covers a wide variety of partnerships. How do you decide who is accountable for what in building your models? What experience have you had with that? When Mr Wynne gave his introductory evidence, he suggested that the Parliament would be the final arbiter of which models were to come into play. The purpose of this exercise is to try to get a feeling for that. When we discuss this subject, accountability is always mentioned in relation to public perception and how people respond. How do you define and handle accountability in the early stages of establishing different types of partnership?
Accountability is an issue. The City of Edinburgh Council follows the guidance in an Accounts Commission document, "Code of Guidance on Funding External Bodies and Following the Public Pound". We are aggressive about accountability, because public money is involved.
I will answer the question, but I want to say something first about tying up maintenance or revenue budgets. There must be a strategic view at local public service body level, and at a wider level, of what PFI and more traditional forms of public sector procurement are used for. If people take a piecemeal approach and decide to sort out a backlog with PFI, that would be poor in two ways. First, a lot of revenue budget may end up being tied up in PFI payments. Secondly, a strategic view on prioritisation will not have been taken. What is the wider picture? What cross-cutting service picture is emerging on how to progress?
Public finance should be cheaper than private finance, given the risk-spreading capacity of the public sector and its access to tax revenues. Is not that a strong argument in favour of the use of public rather than private sources of finance?
We are intrigued by that question—it is a chestnut that comes up regularly. We undertook a simulation before I left KPMG. Members should not ask me too many technical details about that, because staff did it for me. We took the figures for a conventional PFI deal that we had just closed with bank finance—it was sorted out as a complete deal—and compared them with the figures that we would have got if we had financed the deal with public sector borrowing at the rate at which the Government could borrow in the market at that time. We compared the net present value over the 25 years of the concessions. We took all the capital expenditure, and all the life-cycle and maintenance costs and discounted them back for common comparison. The difference between the two deals was 3 per cent. That would be the potential saving over the life of the project of moving from standard commercial bank finance to public sector finance.
I notice that a representative of one of the banks wants to speak, no doubt about the banks fighting back.
Four years ago, for example, the blended cost of capital of the whole private funding package in a PFI scheme would be about 9 per cent. The cost for transactions closed in the last few months of a scheme will be closer to 7.2 per cent, which is because of a number of factors. The first factor is competition between funders. The margins for debt that are provided by banks like ours have dropped over the same period from about 1.5 per cent to less than 1 per cent. That is at the lower end of where a commercial bank will drive for return. Secondly, bond markets have developed. Wrapped bonds and index-linked bonds have emerged in competition with banks. We compete with them vigorously. The result of that is to introduce more competition to drive down the cost of private finance.
I was surprised that in the two accountancy papers we received there was little content from an accountancy point of view on how risks are valued in the process. How do you value risk in your competitive marketplace? Is it a science or an art form?
It is a competitive art form in many ways. In such circumstances the private sector is being asked to take a commercial view on the risk—over an extended period of time, as you have noted—and to take that risk away from the public sector and take it on itself. There is extensive due diligence with technical and professional advisers on all aspects of schemes, such as life-cycle costs and various other risks. In those projects an inordinate amount of time is spent validating the assumptions that are used in them and in making judgments on risk. Extensive sensitivity analyses are done on complex financial models in order to understand the impact of costs being greater and the cost of service delivery being greater, and what that does to the robustness of the project.
In our submission and publication on PFI, we make the point that there has recently been an appreciable difference between the cost of Government-backed borrowing and borrowing from the private sector. That might change in future, but that is why we have said in the recent past that it is probably not a good idea for a public service to go into a PFI deal if it is looking for a building or something like that. That is especially true if one assumes that after getting the right contractor to build it, the contractor will manage the project with you so that you do not get a bid-cost overrun.
Profit is inherent in the PFI system and is generally assumed to be much more than the cost of capital. I have recently seen a couple of estimates of such profit in the order of 12 per cent to 15 per cent. We should ask ourselves how the PFI option is more efficient. In the prison sector, efficiency has been brought about by employing fewer warders, warders working longer hours for less money, and non-provision of pension schemes that are as attractive as those in the public sector. That is one of the costs of going with PFI. It might well mean that there is less employment than in the public sector comparator.
That is a major aspect of the problem and is one of the main reasons for public opposition to PFI and PPP projects. It is only part of the equation but it is an issue. We are particularly interested in the protection of employment of public sector employees.
I do not think that a PFI project will necessarily mean a reduction in the wages or pension rights of individuals who are employed by that company.
Not necessarily; however, the evidence shows that that often happens.
Control of that rests with the public authority that is letting the contract. That authority must make it clear in the project specification that the contractor who wins the contract must pay fair wages and comply with the current situation regarding pensions. The whip is definitely in the hand of the public authority. If the authority is remiss and allows such situations to go unmonitored, I am sure that the private sector will be only too ready to abuse its position. However, it is the public authority's responsibility to ensure that the contracts that it enters into under PFI protect staff in those circumstances.
That is important. I accept that.
The transfer of employees is an important part of the PFI process. It is covered by the Transfer of Undertakings (Protection of Employment) Regulations and is an extension of the outsourcing part of those. An interesting pilot scheme is taking place—in which three of our hospital bids are engaged—using the retained employment model, which is being delivered through the Department of Health. According to that model, management of employees passes to the private sector, but their terms and conditions and their employment status remain with the public sector. We are awaiting the decision, which will be given in the next few weeks, on whether our projects will have to progress in that pilot scheme using the retained employment model. The ways in which management can address your concerns about the terms and conditions of employees are being considered.
That is an important issue. We will have a session specifically on employee-related issues later in our inquiry.
I would like an explanation of what a wrapped bond is. We are moving from PFI to PPP, and you have hinted that there could be further developments in that area. What is your view of the not-for-profit trust approach, especially as it is linked to the idea of raising funds through bonds?
A wrapped bond is simply a bond that is credit enhanced. In other words, the holder of the bond benefits from the covenant or the quality of the person who is wrapping the bond, who effectively guarantees the bond. An organisation with a AAA rating guarantees that the bond and the holder of the bond do not have to rely on the performance of the project, but on the performance of the wrapper. The AAA entity wraps round the credit risk, and that reduces the cost.
I would not say that organisations come to a project without thinking about it too carefully. Life assurance companies and pension funds do not invest their money lightly, because they must protect it. The wrapped bond means that in effect they are not exposed to the risks of the project. Somebody else provides them with a guarantee that, if the project goes pear-shaped, they will still be able to get their funds back. Those funds are frequently people's long-earned pension funds that they are looking for a decent return on over a long time.
I apologise for the pun, but it is time for us to wrap up this meeting. We have covered a wide range of issues, and this has been only the second evidence session of our inquiry. The information that the witnesses have given us in written and oral form will be very helpful, and we appreciate it. At some stage, we might ask for further information if we want clarification of points or issues that have developed in subsequent questioning. Thank you for the time that you have given in preparation for this session and in answering our questions.