Once again we have with us Professor Alan Paterson from the University of Strathclyde law school, whom we decided we wanted to give evidence again. We heard from him on 27 February. I apologise to Professor Paterson for the late start of the meeting.
It is fair to say that although legal aid quality assurance has been on the agenda in a number of advanced jurisdictions for some time, some have made greater progress than others have. England and Wales have made the greatest progress, and the Netherlands has shown some interest in that area, so I will talk about them.
That all sounds fairly expensive, but perhaps I am wrong. Have you any idea what compliance costs the measures impose on suppliers of civil legal aid?
No, but I think that you are right that the system is expensive. Input measures are the least expensive. The Scottish Legal Aid Board has introduced some input measures, particularly on criminal legal aid. However, as I said, such measures bite least.
You mentioned franchising, and I presume that some method of quality control is essential if a significant proportion of the operation is to be franchised out. Is it suggested that people who obtain franchises do so on the basis of their quality, their price or simply on their willingness to do the work?
Franchising has given way to contracting, but it was a form of contracting. Contracting in England and Wales is exclusive—in other words, one cannot provide legal aid services, such as giving advice or assistance, unless one has a contract from the Legal Services Commission. Firms must bid to do that work, but, at present, they do not bid on the basis of price.
If people do not bid on the basis of price, on what basis do they bid?
They bid to do so much work—the price is more or less set for them by the Legal Services Commission. However, we might well reach the stage at which people will be expected to compete on price. In order to get a contract, one must show that one meets quality assurance standards, including the input standards that I mentioned—a strong supervisory structure, strong cost controls, file review and practice management—as well as compliance with the transaction criteria.
Do certain firms not get that work after bidding for it?
Yes.
On what basis do those firms not get that work, while other firms get it?
I do not have the figures on which firms did not get contracts. The process, which has been implemented over the past year only, is continuing. Certain firms did not get franchises, but at that time, one did not have to have a franchise in order to do legal aid work, so the problem was not so great. A firm would not get a franchise if it could not meet the input standards that were required. Most people who underwent the process of trying to acquire a franchise found it a valuable experience, because they were asked to implement sound business practices, which, to be frank, the legal profession should have been—and many firms had been—implementing for a while.
That leads me to my next question. It has been suggested that we do not need such a system in Scotland because the quality of solicitors' work is guaranteed by their training, codes of conduct and so on. Is that assertion justified?
It might be justified—we simply do not know.
Paul Martin has some questions about a legal services commission.
When you previously appeared before the committee, we discussed your proposal for a legal services commission. You urged that such a body should have flexibility. What exactly do you mean by that?
It is not just about flexibility. The commission should have a planning and proactive role. The current board has its hands tied by legislation. It does not have a planning role. It cannot say how a pot of money should be spent. Its statutory role is to be a good housekeeper—to manage the fund. The board is demand led—everything depends on who comes to it for money. The board cannot say that it has examined need and provision in Scotland, that it has identified certain gaps and that it would like to fill them. It is within the board's role to carry out an assessment of need and to examine the availability of supply. However, it has no statutory powers to fill gaps that have appeared.
Do you think that a legal services commission should be able to revise eligibility criteria or fee levels?
The Legal Services Commission in England and Wales is partly involved in that area, although decisions are still made by the Lord Chancellor's Department. Recently the commission proposed that solicitors working in areas of priority need—such as social welfare law—should be paid more. I believe that that proposal has now been implemented. I think that that is a sensible approach, as it enables one to say, "These are our priorities, which have been agreed between the commission and the Lord Chancellor's Department." One can then reward providers who are prepared to work in those areas of legal aid.
Do you believe that a Scottish legal services commission could consider such issues as eligibility and fee levels?
A Scottish legal services commission could have a role in that. The English Legal Services Commission has a research arm, as does the Scottish Legal Aid Board, but the English Legal Services Commission research arm has been looking at eligibility, the question of passporting benefits and other issues that have been troubling the committee. The results of the research will have to be with the Lord Chancellor's Department if they are to be implemented, but the commission has had a key role to play.
Evidence has been given to us that suggests that many aspects of the legal aid system are in need of revision. Should there perhaps be the opportunity for an on-going strategic review?
Absolutely. The balance of policy making between the Executive and the commission would have to change, and that is sensible. One cannot take all policy-making powers away from the Executive. After all, it is the paymaster at the end of the day. However, the commission should be doing a lot of the strategic planning in conjunction with the Executive.
Finally, would you like to make any further points that have not been covered in your written and oral evidence?
I think that I have covered most points.
Some oral evidence has suggested the need for a rationalisation of eligibility criteria in terms of passporting benefits with respect to advice and assistance and civil legal aid. What is your view on that?
That is an area that the English Legal Services Commission has been looking into. Rather curiously, as I understand its interim results, it is not in favour of extending passporting across the board. In fact, it is considering getting rid of it. That is curious because, on the face of it, passporting saves on administration costs. However, the commission's microeconomic modelling suggests that it does not increase the range of people who benefit from the scheme. The commission is concerned that it brings in a number of people who, under the current rules, are ineligible for legal aid. The commission thinks that that is a problem. I am not sure that I agree with that, but research has certainly been conducted in that area.
You seem to be suggesting that there is some injustice in the civil legal aid scheme, which has pushed the thought into people's minds that civil law is for the very poor and for the very rich—those who are in the middle miss out.
The commission would not co-exist with the Legal Aid Board. It is likely that, as in England and Wales, the Legal Aid Board would be transformed into a legal services commission, which would do much the same job that is currently done by the Legal Aid Board but would have a wider remit. It would cover planning and policy and would manage the fund and the proper delivery of poverty legal services in Scotland.
I want to return to the fairness of civil legal aid. If awards are made against people who are on civil legal aid, any awards that should be paid to others seem to be swallowed up by the Legal Aid Board itself. Only if there is any residue after the Legal Aid Board has got its money does the individual who has successfully taken a case through the courts get anything.
I understand that you are referring to the clawback or statutory charge, which is a feature of many legal systems. In effect, it works in this way: if a person loses the action, the legal aid is considered to be a grant; but if the person wins the action, it becomes a loan, which someone has to pay back. The loan should be paid back by the other side, but it is usually not paid back in full for a variety of reasons. Therefore, the Legal Aid Board will look to the litigant who was given legal aid to pay it back from contributions. Usually, the contributions will not cover the legal costs, so the board needs to look to any winnings that have been achieved. I can see the Treasury's rationale in doing things in that way.
You spoke earlier about a possible case for a 100 per cent contribution for higher up the income scale. Were you suggesting that that would protect against the costs that you have been discussing?
No. You may ask why anybody would pay a 100 per cent contribution. The answer is, first, that the contribution can be spread over a substantial period—some jurisdictions have experimented with contributions being paid over a very long period indeed. Secondly, some people say that the real advantage of legal aid is that, when people lose, their liability to pay the other side's expenses can be, and usually is, modified by the court, even if they have to pay 100 per cent of their own lawyer's fees.
You suggested that the state should pick up 100 per cent of fees higher up the income scale than it does at present. Would you suggest that that be extended to all costs?
No—I may inadvertently have misled you. When I talked about 100 per cent contributions, I meant clients paying up to 100 per cent of the contribution. The sliding contribution scale would mean that, after a while, clients would be paying 100 per cent of their costs, or rather of their contribution. They might do that, first to spread out the contribution over a longer period and, secondly, because if they lose, their liability to pay the other side's expenses may be modified by the court.
You mentioned that the amount of money that is disregarded has not been updated for a number of years; neither have the rewards for advocates and solicitors participating in the schemes. You stated that there is some concern about that. How could and should the fees be updated and subsequently maintained at an acceptable level?
It is true that there have not been annual increases in fees for advocates' or solicitors' legal aid work. If I were a Treasury official, or the Scottish equivalent thereof, I would say that it is interesting that the unit cost per case keeps rising year on year. In other words, cases cost more each year, despite the fact that fees have not gone up.
You say that the unit cost of cases has risen. If solicitors' and advocates' fees have stayed on a straight line, would not it be fair to argue to the Treasury that the rise is due to increased Crown Office court costs rather than solicitors' and advocates' fees, although that is not an argument against reconsidering their fees? Solicitors' and advocates' expenses have gone up, but their fees have stayed on a straight line. Are you suggesting that solicitors and advocates are somehow extending the system so that they can earn more?
I am not aware of research to show why the unit cost has risen; I merely observed what a Treasury official would observe—that although fees are pegged, the unit cost keeps rising. Why the unit cost keeps rising is an interesting question and more research is required. The allegation that some of the rise is caused by lawyers cost chasing is easy to make but it has not been substantiated. I believe that the supplier-induced demand thesis, which some economists espouse, is an easy one that is not fully borne out by the facts. Economists have considered the matter in England and Wales. It is true that lawyers are economically rational—in other words, if you give them an incentive to work one way, they will work that way and if you give them an incentive to work another way, they will work another way. The allegation that solicitors or advocates are inflating their fees is not one that I would make, nor do I think that the facts would bear it out.
I did not make that allegation, but it is a logical conclusion to draw. If their fees are on a fixed line, they cannot affect the overall unit cost of cases. Their fees would be excluded.
That assumes that the same amount of work was done in previous cases as is done in current cases. It may be that changes in the law or in procedure mean that more work has to be done.
I do not want to put words in your mouth. I accept what you say about higher payments perhaps being needed in some areas, especially for advice and assistance in social welfare cases, to try to encourage people to go in that direction.
My answer is both. The question of what is an appropriate level of fee turns on our expectation of what is a reasonable salary. I cannot answer that—what the state is prepared to pay legal aid practitioners is a question for policy makers. From my discussions with civil legal aid practitioners, I am persuaded that, by and large, the fee rates for civil legal aid practitioners in Scotland are, across the board, on the low side. In particular areas, such as social welfare law, people labour under a particular disincentive, because it predominantly involves advice and assistance.
You say "on the low side", which is a fairly measured comment. One of our witnesses described the legal aid system as being at "the stage of meltdown". Was that an exaggeration?
I am not sure that I am prepared to comment on—
I presume that, if it is at the stage of meltdown, next week we will see no civil legal aid cases.
Scottish Legal Aid Board research is mapping provision and considering the number of outlets and the number of solicitors that provide advice and assistance. The figure has gone up in the past seven years. The board has also looked at the number of lawyers doing civil legal aid; that figure, too, has gone up in the past seven years. Therefore, to say that no lawyers are willing to do civil legal aid work is not true. However, to say that there are disincentives to their doing civil legal aid work is true, and I am not sure that that is a good thing. What we do not yet have from research—although we hope to get it—is evidence on whether people who used to do a lot of civil legal aid are no longer doing it.
If I were the Treasury official looking at the system and I heard that more practitioners were coming forward, I would ask why I should pay them more when I was getting more volunteers at the current rates.
We do not know who is doing the work or how much they are doing. Something like 75 per cent of civil legal aid work is done by 25 per cent of the profession. A similar picture prevails in England and Wales. The English have concentrated resources on that 25 per cent. By and large, the franchises and contracts have gone to those people, on the argument that specialists in legal aid will be more committed to the system and will have more throughput, which means that there will be a greater economy of scale.
I thank you for your evidence, Professor Paterson. It has been helpful.
Previous
Item in Private