Good afternoon and welcome to the 11th meeting in 2010 of the Finance Committee, in the third session of the Scottish Parliament. I have received apologies from Tom McCabe and Joe FitzPatrick. Stewart Maxwell will be present as a substitute member for agenda item 2. I ask everyone to turn off their mobile phones and pagers, please.
At this point, based on information from the General Register Office for Scotland, 18 per cent of Scotland’s population is under the age of 15 and 20 per cent is over the age of 60. Over the next 20 years, that 20 per cent will increase significantly to somewhere in the region of 1.7 million of our 5 million population, which is 34 per cent. One third of our population will be over the age of 60.
I am contributing to that statistic every year, which is a bit of a worry.
My area of expertise and interest is with the oldest old people because it is in long-term care financing, which is probably going to present one of the biggest challenges. Scotland is very similar to England in that it faces a very large increase in the number of people over the age of 85. Over the next 25 years, the number of people in that age group will more than double. That group is, of course, where the need for long-term care is greatest.
Given NESTA’s focus on innovation in the private sector and public services, our argument is that the challenge that faces public finances over the next few years only sharpens some of the questions about the long-term demands and expectations that have been circling around public services for some time. Of course, it is wrong to talk about opportunities, given the scale of the challenges that we face, but the twin challenges of the short-term demands of saving money, and the long-term demands coming from demographic change should, nonetheless, force us to think about new approaches in public services to deal with those twin pressures.
Can you give us any indication of the scale of resources that would be required to meet those challenges? Can you give us any statistics to let us understand the scope of what we face?
Obviously, the further out one gets, the more speculative some of the numbers become, but our reading of research that has been done elsewhere is that a cumulative figure would be around £300 billion in extra costs across the United Kingdom by about 2030. That is gathered from a number of sources, but we think that they are pretty respectable sources.
On the face of it, that is one of the most worrying aspects of the enormous change in demographics. If we continue with the current models of care, we will need very big amounts, which will be difficult to achieve under current budget projections. We have been thinking about the issue for quite a long time.
As Malcolm Chisholm suggests, it has been broadly agreed that those are the directions of travel that we have to take. We argue that the scale of the fiscal challenge should not deter us from taking bolder steps in those directions, but should instead be the impetus for making real changes and setting out on a 10 or 20-year journey towards ensuring that more preventive approaches are not at the margins of public services but are in the mainstream. I think that there is broad agreement about that policy framework, but the challenge is to make it happen. The innovations that we look at around the world show that significant savings can be made—in the range of 20 to 40 per cent—if you really go for those approaches and implement them on quite a large scale.
I sound a note of caution, in that we have rather little evidence on the savings that can be made from prevention, although that is not to say that we should not be trying it. The tension will always be around where you put the money. Do you put it into prevention and helping people who have relatively low needs at the expense of those who have extreme needs? That is a very difficult political decision to make. The fact that you are facing financial constraints will make it even harder to put the money into prevention, because you will be fire-fighting the whole time.
I will give a couple of examples of good things that are already happening and that have made a real impact. Free travel has had a significant impact on the lives of many older adults because they are more able to go out and socialise together, to access amenities in their cities and so on; it is also important in a rural context. It is a positive thing, because it is about active ageing. It is not about looking after people when they develop a problem but about people accessing things for themselves.
It is important to be active physically and mentally.
Brian McKechnie’s comments have emphasised the wider agenda to do with the contribution of, and opportunities for, older people, of which we are very aware in Scotland. We must remind ourselves of that when we talk about care costs. I should say for the benefit of our guests from England that the current Administration and the previous Administration have sought in one way or another to implement Scotland’s strategy for an ageing population.
Let me add a point on the benefits of having an ageing population: older people themselves do a lot of the caring and provide much value in that way.
We hear what you say on that.
I am not an expert on the systems that have been put in place or tried for admission avoidance. It is clear that emergency admissions are extremely expensive, so it could be lucrative to target them. Systems that have been used around the country suggest that that is an area in which there may be scope for improvement.
I want to challenge our focus on efficiency and where we can save money. I completely understand why that is the priority in the current context, but the best examples of radical reform of public services often start with the question, “How can we make this a better experience for the users of public services?” rather than with the question, “How can we save money?” If that way of thinking is followed through, it often leads to the development of a much more effective service, which tends to be much more efficient because it does what the user wants. Often, such services are based in the community and involve giving people support and advice and helping them to build up their social networks in the community rather than in an institutional setting. It could be dangerous to focus only on where we can save money and not to look at better and more effective forms of public services from across the UK and around the world that we could learn from, the adoption of which would lead to much more significant savings being made.
Can you give us any examples of such best practice?
An example of best practice as regards accident and emergency admissions is the virtual community wards project that is being trialled in Croydon. Croydon Primary Care Trust looked at the data on where its costs were coming from—that is often an important starting point—and realised that just 5 per cent of patients were the cause of half its costs. It therefore began the virtual community wards experiment, which involves giving people care, management and advice in their own homes. The provision is organised as it would be in a ward, but is based in the community, which is a better setting for many of the patients concerned. It also means that A and E wards tend not to incur those costs.
That was interesting. I want to follow up on the idea of achieving efficiency with regard to costs and efficiency for the service user.
Who wishes to take that one?
I am a bit lost on Linda Fabiani’s question. Can you repeat the two halves of it?
Yes. Let us go with the first half. We hear stories to the effect that, across different local authorities and areas in Scotland, there are different standards of care, and that different components are funded or not funded. Would it be better all round if there was some kind of national standard? Is it the case that there are differences? If so, how could we make that better?
I am not an expert on variation in Scotland, but there is certainly variation in England. I have no reason to think that the situation is different here. The question whether Scotland should have a national system or local variation is a difficult one. There was discussion in England, which seems to have faded, about how disability benefits are used and whether that money would be better put into the care system. Some of the argument against that was that disability benefit is a national system with standard rules that everybody knows, which delivers a common entitlement to everyone, with no variation among localities.
I understand that delivery is split between health boards and local authorities. Of course, unpaid carers also make a contribution that is difficult to assess. Would it be more efficient to have a one-stop shop or service point to deal with delivery, rather than split it among the 32 local authorities and all the health boards?
Dr Harris, do you want to respond to that question?
Yes. I will do so in a broad way by saying that, philosophically, we tend to be quite critical of the idea of national standards because they can inhibit the kind of radical reform of public services and the local variation that are often very important. Users of services may have very different needs and see them in very different ways. National standards and all the apparatus of measurement and management that comes with them can inhibit users in articulating what they feel they need and can inhibit their getting it. Too often, we try to decide on behalf of users of services what they need—albeit that we do so for very understandable reasons—rather than create a bit more freedom in the system for them to be able to articulate and determine what they need.
I would like to hear the customer’s point of view from Mr McKechnie.
I hope that I do not represent the customers totally. There is regional variation, but the reasons for it are quite complex. One of the major challenges is that our older population is not evenly spread throughout Scotland—some areas have high numbers of older adults. For example, areas such as Dumfries and Galloway suffer the double whammy of younger people moving away and people moving there to retire, so those areas have higher levels of older adults, which means that the system comes under more strain. Unfortunately, if councils are charged with ensuring that everyone receives a reasonable standard of care but their budgets are constrained due to higher levels of need, there will be fluctuations in provision. The fluctuations are not massive, but there are differences among areas in Scotland.
That is indeed an interesting issue, but I want to take a step back a bit. The questioning so far has focused on those economically inactive older people who might be seen as a cost but, given the demographics of a population that is growing older, I want to focus on how we configure matters so that we have increased numbers of economically active older people. For example, I was recently approached by a constituent who works for Borders NHS Board—the Borders area has a very similar demographic profile to that of Dumfries and Galloway—who is being compulsorily retired. She does not want to retire, but she is required to do so. She thinks that that is nonsense, and I tend to agree with her. How should the public sector, which is probably the biggest single employer in many of our constituencies, be configured to reflect the workforce? Should different types or patterns of employment be available, so that older people can continue as employees? Is any work being done on that? Is there any indication of how we might go forward with that?
I have done a lot of research on that issue specifically in Scotland. It presents an opportunity, but we also need to understand how things are changing and developing.
My understanding is that the outgoing United Kingdom Government committed to a review of the default retirement age, which is what you are talking about. It is intellectually hard to see any justification for requiring people to stop working just because they have reached a certain age, especially as in the long run we are increasing the retirement age in recognition of the increasing length of time that people live, the cost of pensions and so on. It seems hard to justify continuing with the current default retirement age legislation.
Like many organisations, we think that we need to start thinking about developing a set of services to help people before they are suddenly retired, whether for health reasons or because they reach a particular age. That is another example of the need to step back and look at what the problem is, because in the longer term we could save significant sums of money if we helped people to retire and prepared them for the transition from full-time work to a more mixed work-life balance. We expect a lot of those services to be based in the community and run by social enterprises, voluntary groups or co-operatives that would help people to prepare for the change rather than it coming, as it does now, as an abrupt change in their life for which they are not prepared.
A considerable amount of the evidence that we heard from earlier panels of witnesses said that we should focus spend on the younger end of the age spectrum and not make cuts there. I would welcome this panel’s views on that, given what Mr McKechnie said about 18 per cent of the population being under 15 and heading towards 34 per cent of the population being over 50. Is it just a case of doing the simple maths and saying that 18 per cent of our spend should be on the younger element and 34 per cent should be on the older element?
I should probably go first. No, there is no question but that we must invest in young people. That investment is really important, although there may be some aspects that we can look at again. The immediate economic impact of younger people is modest—young workers tend to be lower skilled—but their skills and experience will build over time, and we must invest in them.
There are two sides to the matter: whom we spend public money on; and who pays for that—or where we raise the revenue to pay for it. One reason why the Westminster Government did not initially opt for a policy of free personal care is that if it was financed from general taxation, the burden would fall predominantly on younger people, some of whom have low incomes and not much in the way of assets.
The question relates back to the issue of efficiency. Broadly, the more we spend on a public service, the better it will be. Clearly, spending much more on services is not an option that is open to us now, which is why we need to rethink some of our fundamental assumptions about services, particularly from the point of view of users. We need to think about the real purpose of services, about what users really want, and about whether there are more effective ways of meeting those needs. That is not the same as asking whether we should spend a bit more or a bit less on services. The question is far more fundamental than that.
That mention of education brings me neatly to my next question, which is about universal provision.
Who would you like to answer that?
You just fire away because you started.
I would not want you to go away thinking that I am in favour of means testing to the hilt—there are considerable disadvantages to means testing whether for social security benefits or other things, because it puts people off claiming what they could be entitled to. However, if we must focus spending where it is likely to be needed most or can be of most benefit, we have to start thinking about it. As I indicated before, there are some people who receive benefits who can afford to pay the costs of transport, care and so on. We have to ask if that is the best use of resources.
How does that fit with the £300 billion in extra costs that you said we would face by the year 2030?
It does not fit well with that, and I do not know how those costs are going to be met.
Do you care to offer any thoughts on which components of care should be paid for by those who can afford it?
Care homes in Scotland and England already charge people for so-called hotel costs. There is a debate to be had about the split between the care component and the hotel costs of care homes. People are used to paying for housing and their everyday living expenses, so it seems quite reasonable to charge for those. Care at home is trickier. If I understand the position correctly, Scotland has free personal care at home but other kinds of domestic help are charged. One of the difficulties with that is that although some people might feel that the most important thing for them is personal care, some people with equivalent needs might prefer to have some domestic help and do the personal care tasks themselves. Who are we to tell them otherwise? Perhaps the way to do it is to say that people are entitled to a certain sum of money towards whatever care they need at home, and they can choose how to spend it. That is how personal budgets would work.
Mr McKechnie?
From our experience of the older adults learning programme at the university, I think that anything that is free is not necessarily perceived as being valued. There is a benefit to charging people for something; they value something that has a cost associated with it. If you are given a gold bracelet free of charge, you do not value it in quite the same way as you would if the person who gave it to you told you that they had to pay £2,000 for it.
Yes, but is that the same thing as a free bus pass?
Well, it is still referred to as the penny ticket by various people. The bus pass has a low cost per head in Scotland and it is highly valued, in that it gives people a lot of freedom. There would be a cost involved in taking a portion of that back—it would be like the dog licence issue, when the cost of collection was greater than the cost of the licence. I am not sure about that.
Do you have a view, Dr Harris?
The issue must be addressed on a case-by-case basis. There is a real danger in applying a general approach to very different types of service and forms of provision and assuming that the outcome will be the same.
I am interested in what you said about a new welfare settlement. There is evidence that large numbers of older people do not claim all the benefits to which they are entitled, often because of the bureaucracy that is involved, and I guess sometimes because they do not need the money. In the new economic times that we are entering, uptake might be much greater, because people might feel that they need the money. Do the witnesses have any idea of the budgetary implications of everybody taking up all the benefits to which they are entitled?
I do not have statistics on that. There is significant under take-up of benefits and suchlike, for a variety of reasons—bureaucracy is a major one. It is surprising how many older adults would rather that the money went to young people in some way. There is massive intergenerational exchange, whereby money is passed from older adults to their children and grandchildren. There is an attitude of self-sacrifice and a willingness not to take money that people think might somehow reach children and young people.
I know pensioners who use the winter fuel allowance to pay for Christmas presents for their grandchildren, because they do not need it for their heating.
I can dig out a few numbers. Some time ago, I did work on the take-up of means-tested benefits by older people, with my colleague Steve Pudney, who is at the University of Essex. Two main points came out of that. First, it tends to be the smaller amounts that people do not take up. If people are entitled to large amounts, which by definition means that they have relatively low incomes, they are much more likely to claim. However, that is not the whole story. The second point is about the delivery system and the information that is available to people. When we look at the patterns of the combinations of benefits that people take up, we find that people who receive pension credit, or income support as it was in the old days, are likely also to claim their entitlement to the other two main means-tested benefits, which are housing benefit and council tax benefit. That is to do with the way in which the system works.
David Whitton is right to point to a bigger issue. As we come out of an economic recession, there is a danger that we will move into a social recession. The time when the costs of the economic recession begin to feed through into greater demand on public services—we know that there is a time lag in the effects on ill health, mental health, worklessness, family breakdown, offending behaviour and so on—is the very time when we will begin to cut services because of the broader public finances. That means that we need to think quickly about some different models of service provision. That cannot happen overnight, but we need to try to deal with some of those costs imaginatively in the short term as well as in the long term.
So is your idea that we would roll up all the benefits into a single payment to make it more efficient? When someone reached a certain age, they would get the payment. They would not have to make a claim and it would be an allowance rather than a benefit.
There are a couple of reasons why that could seem attractive. First, it could give the individual greater flexibility to allocate some of the money in different ways. Secondly, we have seen that the more budgets are pooled in that way, the more it gives different providers of services, assistance and support opportunities to combine services in imaginative ways. For example, we know that silos have been a problem in public services. Different services or departments are responsible for different things, so they have their own performance measures and so on. They might deliver the services very well within those boundaries, but they are not always very flexible and do not have much incentive to find ways of combining services in more efficient ways. That kind of mechanism could help with that problem.
Finally—this may seem a daft question—is there any evidence to suggest that people retire to Scotland because we have free personal care and the rest of the country does not?
I do not have any evidence for that.
Is the model that we should aim for, then, one that looks after people at home as much as possible rather than in residential homes, care homes or hospitals? Should we focus more resource on such community-based care—if I may describe it like that—and less on the rest?
I am not particularly suggesting that as a model, but older people tend to say that they want to stay at home. One can understand that. We need to be a little bit careful because not much work has been done on those on the margins who might be able to stay at home but might need to move into residential care. I suspect that many people do not want to contemplate a time when they will be unable to live in their own home. That said, I am sure that there is a lot of merit in targeting money at providing care for people in their own home.
Are there any particular types of people who are most disadvantaged by the current long-term care regime in the UK?
An issue that is perhaps made worse by the current legislation, under which free personal care is available to those at home but not to those in residential settings, is that local authorities potentially have an incentive to place people in residential care because that will be cheaper than providing care in the person’s home. For that reason, we are in a rather peculiar position at the moment.
The final questions will come from Jeremy Purvis.
Professor Hancock makes an interesting point, which probably also apples to where people die. Perhaps due to the cost profile, many people die in hospital even though they would prefer to die at home if a suitable care package or palliative care was available.
Obviously, that is one of the more challenging political questions, so I am glad that I do not need to make the decision. Making the case for the health service being so different that the health budget is more important than, say, the education or transport and infrastructure budgets would be a challenge. Each of those things has a part to play. The NHS employs something like 10 per cent of the workforce in Scotland, so cuts there would have a dramatic impact in other areas, which brings us back to the question whether cuts lead to genuine cost savings. However, it is probably difficult to justify an approach that leaves health, alone of all parts of the budget, unscathed.
Does anyone else want to respond?
It is a decision for the politicians. As a mere academic, I will not comment.
Does another mere academic want to add anything?
If we are coming from the perspective that we are trying to reform services to make them much more effective and therefore more efficient, it is dangerous to appear to take any service out of consideration and imply that it should remain unchanged—I do not think that anyone means to imply that. The NHS itself has said that it needs to save between £15 billion and £20 billion over the next few years merely to cope with the demographic change that we have been talking about.
David Whitton has what he assures me is a short, final question.
It is on a point of clarification. Professor Hancock, you talked about the differences between residential care and care at home and mentioned that some local authorities prefer the cheaper approach. Is that UK-wide or were you talking about England?
I was talking about a system in which there is no free personal care for people in residential homes but there is help for people at home.
Therefore, what you described is happening outwith Scotland.
The issue might arise in Scotland if people needed intensive care at home, the cost of which exceeded the free personal care element of residential care. That might bring people up against the same, rather perverse incentive.
Do the witnesses want to make final comments?
The majority of older adults will enjoy good health for most of their lives. The extensive costs kick in in the final two or three years of life. We should regard longer life as a real benefit. We want to encourage people to be healthy, to work longer and to enjoy their lives; we should not just think about the cost implications of that.
My final comment is on the issue of universal versus means-tested provision. If we have a universal system and a fixed budget, we must find some way to ration. In such a system, only the eligibility criteria can be used to ration, in the context of care, people who need lower levels of care might lose out. In a system in which there is a degree of means testing and user contribution, there is another tool in the armoury, which can be manipulated. That might be seen as an advantage.
I thank the committee for the opportunity to give evidence. You are asking difficult but necessary questions. In the submissions that you have received from diverse organisations, the need for more preventive approaches seems to have come up again and again. We talked about that shift in approach.
The committee is well aware of the importance of the matter.