Item 5 is an evidence-taking session on the Alcohol etc (Scotland) Bill. The first of our two panels of witnesses comprises organisations representing groups such as young people and those vulnerable to problem drinking, and I welcome to the meeting Major Dean Logan, addictions service officer with the Salvation Army; Bruce Thomson, assistant regional director for dependency services with the Aberlour Child Care Trust; Tom Roberts, head of public affairs with Children 1st; Margaret McLeod, policy and information manager with YouthLink Scotland; and Liam Burns, president of the National Union of Students in Scotland.
Our learning about what should be done about Scotland’s alcohol problem is still evolving. It is, of course, a major problem and has over time proved to be intractable. However, we feel strongly that the minimum pricing policy, which is relatively cost effective and could have quite a quick impact, will set down a marker showing that the Government means business and is determined to address the issue. That said, in our submission, we make it clear that there is no quick fix or magic bullet and that a number of other measures have to be implemented in concert if we are to make a significant impact. We also feel strongly that this measure must have cross-party support lasting well beyond the lifetime of a single Parliament. Although we say that the bill is a missed opportunity, we appreciate that, at the moment, it is covering only certain elements. I guess that those involved in pushing through the bill will have to think about what needs to be done on a number of fronts to deal with the problem.
What gaps have you identified?
With regard to your comment on identifying children at risk, the committee has heard about difficulties in that respect because the children themselves will not tell teachers or others about their parents for fear of social workers taking them away from their families. How might such children be identified?
According to a recent and very interesting ChildLine report, the name of which escapes me, a large proportion of children are contacting the organisation. For me, the frustrating thing is that, although those children are coming forward and looking for help, things do not really go much further because they get worried about the consequences of having to give their name and other personal details. As you say, they think that social workers or police officers might descend on their home.
I want to look at the wider issues that most of the witnesses have raised in their submissions. I know that the Poverty Truth Commission has not been able to attend this morning but, in its submission, it says:
Will you expand on your proposal for a social responsibility charter, which you mention on page 5 of your submission?
I just thought that I would pick up on the point because I was not sure about it. The levy is targeted. It is not just a general thing, as I understand it.
It seems to us that the bill will target the cheaper end of the scale and drinks that are thought to cause problems for particular groups—for example, young people buying cheap cider. However, there are people who consume other types of drinks to excess. Some ordinary table wines are very strong. They are relatively more expensive at the moment, but we understand that minimum pricing will have no impact on the consumption of more expensive drinks of that sort. We are concerned about the impact across the board. We are broadly in support of minimum pricing, but the evidence seems to be evolving. I admit that we have limited knowledge of the evidence, but it seems that there are issues in how we translate what might happen elsewhere into a Scottish context.
YouthLink Scotland is broadly in favour of sensible pricing. We are concerned about particular drinks that are targeted at young people and would like such drinks to be targeted. We do not have the expertise to say at what level minimum pricing will have an impact economically or will drive down demand; that is not our area. However, we are concerned about drinks such as alcopops, which taste considerably different from other alcoholic drinks. Young people have told us that they do not see alcopops as such a high risk because of how those drinks taste. That lulls them into a false sense of security as regards the amount that they are drinking. Our concern is to target products that are aimed specifically at young people.
Is part of the problem for us that, when we consider the age restriction in the bill, we are considering public order issues but, when you give evidence on other matters—the impact on families and behind-the-net-curtains drinking—we are looking at health issues? They are often interlinked but more often so with young people because we are talking about long-term damage from drinking.
I would not mind if the point about public disorder was linked to evidence. The only police force that gave proper statistics for the drinking age trials was Lothian and Borders Police. It saw a reduction of one incident per week in vandalism and public disorder and a 0.1 increase in minor incidents. I use those figures in a reserved way because the Royal Statistical Society branded the statistics that we have from the trials as insignificant and disappointing. We are operating in a vacuum and I find it disappointing that we are targeting efforts at young people with no evidence to say that raising the age has an impact.
It is a different basis; it is not the argument but the basis that has changed. The question was directed not only at you but at all the witnesses on the panel.
No, I am trying to differentiate the ideas of raising the drinking age and stopping the early onset of drinking alcohol. In America, where the drinking age is higher, many states are now considering a reduction in age because the higher age has not had the desired impact.
It is clear from the written evidence that, with one exception, the witnesses’ organisations broadly support the principle of introducing minimum pricing as a mechanism to tackle the alcohol problem. The exception is YouthLink, whose submission I am a little confused about and would therefore like some clarity on. YouthLink questioned whether minimum pricing is “an effective tool” and stated that the approach to take is to have “a sensible way” of pricing alcohol. Could the witness from YouthLink give me a clearer understanding of what is meant by “sensible” pricing? In addition, what are YouthLink’s views on how such pricing should be delivered through the bill?
It is certainly one of the components, but we also made it clear that education, counselling and health must go alongside pricing, which will not work on its own.
Yes, I think that it could. One of the other things that we need to consider is the comparative impact on children of home drinking, which Tom Roberts mentioned, as opposed to pub drinking. I am talking about excessive drinking. Are children more subject to harm if the drinking takes place in the home rather than elsewhere?
I do not know whether Mary Scanlon wants to ask about the focus on families that we saw in Finland, which is a point that she has raised before. It would be an interesting point to put to our witnesses.
If you are not going to raise it, I would like to put the point to our witnesses. You have raised the issue before, citing the Finnish example. Do you want to ask about that, as you have raised the matter previously?
Yes, I will defer to Richard.
Yes.
A lot of work has been done on the development of policy and procedures to identify children of parents who are attending services, on the sharing of information across professional boundaries and generally on finding the best way to tackle the problem. Our experience is that that is not happening as it should. Without pointing the finger at professional colleagues elsewhere, I would say that there are patches of good practice, and there is a lot of focus on the person who is presenting the addiction problem, rather than on the impact that their addiction is having. We need to do an awful lot more in that regard, perhaps developing policy documents and working at a strategic level. People need to be confident that the procedures are in place. The evidence on the ground suggests that that is not happening as consistently as it should. That is a concern.
Our members made a few points about what is not in the bill. Pardon me if I do not necessarily know about the things that it is possible for it to cover. We have talked about alcohol pricing, but people also came back to us about the pricing of soft drinks and their inaccessibility in the on-trade, with people choosing to drink alcoholic drinks simply on that premise.
I thank Dr Simpson for his additional questions. There is a firm belief that alcohol misuse can be familial—there are strong family links to the use of alcohol. We recently conducted a study among people who utilise our homeless service provision. There have now been more than 1,000 forensic interviews with people who have come into our units, and 70 to 80 per cent of them have significant alcohol problems. Many of them speak of early childhood experience of alcohol as a predictor of their exclusion in later life. Any intervention that can be offered at an early stage—by considering the whole family in situations where someone presents with an alcohol problem—is of vital importance, although I am not an expert, and I do not know how we do that. If we are to break the cycle, there must be more than just a legislative response. Other interventions must be made available.
I thank the witnesses for those answers. Arrest referral has rather stuttered as well; we have only five schemes in Scotland. Arrest referral provides an opportunity for people to address their problems and link to treatment right away. We have not rolled that out.
That point links back to the earlier point about recording and identifying children who are affected by alcohol use in the family. Our submission raises a number of points on that, particularly about the need for services to be joined up. When an adult presents with alcohol issues, services should also look at the wider family, including who is caring for that adult, because all too often it is the children and young people. Also, that care is often unseen. It might well start off with the children getting themselves ready for school in the morning, and extend from there. It is a huge issue.
The committee was unanimous and quite firm on the important role of health visitors in its report on child and adolescent mental wellbeing.
I want to emphasise what Tom Roberts said about young children and the role of young carers. We all appreciate that young carers play an extremely valuable role in keeping families together and looking after siblings and parents. However, when very young children find themselves in such situations, it starts to have an impact on their childhood—their experience of being a child, having fun and so on, which is important. We need to bear that in mind.
Throughout the years since the Parliament was established, we have received very important presentations from young carers. Many did not even know that they were young carers—they were just getting on with life. They indicated that their role as carers impacted on their education, as it led to their falling asleep at school and so on. Your point is well made, but could we include in the bill a duty on local authorities and NHS boards to publish an audited strategy on what they are doing in their areas to draw together social work, housing, the NHS, education, the police and so on with regard to alcohol issues?
There is value in holding local authorities to account on the issue. We know that early childhood experience of alcohol, especially in the family, has an impact on the direction a young person’s life may—not will—take. We have evidence that it can lead to social exclusion and addiction issues for the young person.
Those comments are helpful.
I return to the issue of price, consumption and harm. We heard from the University of Sheffield that the study that it published was based on modelling rather than evidence and practice, because no country has ever gone down this road and the university had nothing other than modelling on which to base its research. Last week, it was suggested to us that the modelling may have been based on price reductions rather than price increases. When we were in Finland, we saw that the impact of price reduction was huge—people’s drinking rose immediately and there were much greater sales of alcohol. However, when an attempt was made to redress that by increasing prices, sales did not fall proportionately. That is a concern.
I appreciate that the University of Sheffield paper is based on modelling. My journey began when I read the book “Alcohol Policy and the Public Good” by Griffith Edwards et al, which was published by the World Health Organization. That work clearly shows how, even way back in the early 1980s, there was a distinct link between the availability and price of alcohol, and public health, which makes it a societal issue. Thomas Babor backs up that point in his book “Alcohol: No Ordinary Commodity—Research and public policy”. Only last week, I received by e-mail a copy of the WHO’s latest pronouncement on alcohol, which also comes out strongly in favour of Governments effecting a societal change in drinking behaviour by using the two levers of price and availability. Therefore, the issue is not just about modelling, although I understand that the model goes deeper. As no country has ever trialled what the Scottish Government is proposing, it is always difficult to say what the effect will be. However, I think that enough of a body of evidence exists from over the years to say that price and availability are the two levers that can be used to affect alcohol consumption at a societal level.
Thank you very much.
My question was touched on by Rhoda Grant and Ross Finnie. The NUS’s written submission states:
On setting the minimum price, the short answer is that we have absolutely no idea. I think that it is not for our organisation to do that.
The BMA’s position, which I think is shared by many of the royal colleges, is that that is a matter for the Parliament; it is a matter for the legislative process.
That is helpful. I was not necessarily looking for a specific price; rather, I wanted to find out whether you believe that a price in the range of 30p to 40p would not make a significant difference and that therefore the principle of the bill could not be sustained. I am trying to get a discussion of a range, but not too wide a range, as that is not helpful to us. A figure of 40p to 60p is now unhelpful in terms of the debate, although that is not your fault.
I have no quarrel with the range that is being discussed. The price must be set at a level that will improve public health. It is hard to know what conditions will prevail when a minimum price is introduced, which raises problems for predicting an exact level now. Also, the price would have to be revised from time to time depending on the prevailing economic state. The range that has been given is sensible, but to be more specific would be unwise. Our intention is to have a level that will radically improve the public health of the nation.
The range that you have described is reasonable.
My second question is on your views about raising the age for off-sales purchases, from 18 to 21. The BMA did not have a policy on that.
Right. I am with you now.
If we are setting priorities, I would strongly agree with Dr Crighton that price is a key factor—and more important than raising the age to 21. As others have said, we are talking about a raft of measures—no one is suggesting that one measure on its own will make all the difference to this major problem. We also have to be conscious that we do not want to demonise young people. We are talking about young people now, but alcohol problems go right across the board in age.
Will members of the panel comment on the evidence base for minimum pricing for alcohol? In particular, I highlight the Scottish Health Action on Alcohol Problems briefing paper entitled “Minimum Pricing for Alcohol: Frequently Asked Questions”, which includes the unreferenced statement that where social reference pricing
Reference pricing has been explored by Dr Tim Stockwell. I think that largely positive evidence has been taken from him. I have not seen that evidence, but I understand that such information is available.
In the letter that you wrote to my colleague, Jackie Baillie, which was also signed by Dr Rice, you said that the Labour Party was overstating our concern about the profit to retailers that would accrue from minimum unit pricing. However, the Sheffield study modelling states:
Before they do, could you clarify which parts of what you are saying are quotations and which parts are your own comments?
I can give the quotations to the official report after the meeting.
It is not private now, because you have quoted from it.
So that is the quotation from your letter, Dr Rice.
I am sorry—
What is the question?
I cannot follow the line of questioning if people interrupt each other.
There is no mention of further investment in the bill, convener.
We are getting nowhere, and I feel a wee headache coming on again.
The bill contains no such mechanism. The money would simply go to the industry. The issue of a separate levy is a totally different matter; the part of the bill that we are discussing would put profit directly into retailers’ pockets.
We can hear further views on that point from Dr Crighton and Mr Law.
I recall that from your earlier evidence, Dr Rice. We will be able to see it in the Official Report.
Yes. If people get the correct treatment early on they might be prevented from resorting to alcohol. The fact is, however, that people are continuing to drink. The profile of people who use our alcohol-related brain damage services is getting younger and younger, which is why we are so concerned about the high levels of alcohol consumption in Scotland.
I want to offer a personal reflection. For 25 or 30 years now, I have been working with people with alcohol-related problems, many of whom have had psychological problems that have led them to use alcohol as a drug. Of course alcohol is a drug; that is why we have to manage it differently from other commodities. My impression is that it is the consequences of drinking on the individual and the individual’s family that become overwhelmingly more important than the initial factors that led to the excessive drinking. There is an interplay between the two issues, but the consequences of alcohol misuse have a huge psychological impact that has become more and more prominent.
I understand that no work has been carried out on how minimum pricing would affect different income groups, particularly lower-income families. If, as has quite often been suggested, the minimum price is set at 40p, it would have no impact on people at my income level because the alcohol that they buy will always be more expensive than that, but it would have an impact on people on lower incomes such as pensioners on fixed incomes, who might buy cheaper or value brands. Would that mask the effect of a minimum price? People who do not have an alcohol problem but are on a lower income would, unless they can free up some more income to pay for alcohol, have to reduce their consumption. That might show up as an overall reduction in consumption but there would be no impact on people who are harmful drinkers and can afford to buy alcohol at that price—it would not reduce their consumption. That element is missing from the equation, and I am keen to hear views on it.
We do not know as much as we would like to about the income profile of people who purchase cheap alcohol. As I said earlier, there are data lying around in databases in Scotland that would, if we could access them, be very useful.
Before I let Rhoda Grant back in, I will bring Jack Law and Dr Crighton in on that point.
We must remember that poor people—people on a limited income—are not a homogenous mass. People behave differently, irrespective of their income or status. We know that those with the lowest incomes spend the least on alcohol and that those with the greatest alcohol problems spend most on alcohol—about 80 per cent of the alcohol that is sold is bought by 20 per cent of people who drink.
The differences in mortality between social classes in Scotland, with high prevalence in deprived areas, are a major concern. Recently the chief medical officer for Scotland identified alcohol as one of the drivers of that discrepancy. The situation has improved in some respects, but not in respect of factors and illnesses relating to alcohol, which seems to be one of the important influences on the difference in mortality between deprived and more affluent areas. It is worth bearing in mind that people in deprived areas are paying for that in other ways: the cost of health damage due to alcohol impacts directly on those individuals and they pay for the consequences in the increased cost to the health service and in the damage to their communities—the public order issues that make their surroundings less desirable.
I am conscious of what you say about drug abuse. Has there been any work on mixed alcohol and drug abuse and on whether, if people do not have access to alcohol, they will use drugs instead?
I think that the committee and, indeed, the whole country recognises that we have a serious problem and that it has got significantly worse—I do not think that that is in doubt. I also think that, certainly from the committee’s point of view—I hope that I am not misquoting or misrepresenting my colleagues—price, availability and culture are the three main drivers. We accept all that. However, I want to look at the issue from a slightly different angle. Given the changes that have occurred over the past 20 or 30 years that have led to our increasing alcohol problem, which groups are you most concerned about? Treating the problem as a homogeneous one, as I think Jack Law said, even in terms of the poor, is perhaps not the best way to look at it. Which population groups, in terms of age, gender or whatever, give you the greatest concern regarding increases in consumption and increases in hazardous or harmful consumption?
My answer is the same, in that I think that the problem covers all people in Scotland. One is reminded that no man is an island, because everyone’s drinking influences all the rest of us. Further, the heavier a population drinks, the more people get caught up in the heavy drinking culture. I would therefore say that it is a problem for everyone.
Sorry to interrupt but, to be clear, are you really saying that someone with the sort of income that I have will be affected one jot by minimum pricing? Are you really saying that the proportion of the population with an income above the average, which is £24,000, will be affected by minimum unit pricing? Will they really be affected, rather than there being a population effect, which is predominantly a result of those who have lower incomes in relation to their alcohol consumption buying less?
Yes—you are in the hot seat. We certainly cannot take a wee malt to warm us up in the middle of the session. I am sorry about the temperature.
Michael Matheson asked how common modelling is. Under the National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence technology programme, which tries to assess different measures and different elements that interplay to achieve a certain effect, big population studies cannot necessarily be designed. We take studies that paint the reality and we use mathematics to model what will happen. NICE uses modelling as the basis for making recommendations and that is probably the most-used way of making recommendations on public health interventions.
Modelling is a mathematical way of guessing what would happen if we did certain things. It is based on certain assumptions, which must be tested. Once the measures are put in place, we must go back and see how many of the assumptions that we made were correct. That is why, when we are asked what the minimum price should be, we have to see whether the assumptions have been realised and we must have a way of adjusting and bringing things up to date, testing whether the assumptions that we made for the future were right.
If we did not introduce this kind of measure, we would add a huge burden to the other measures that will need to be introduced. In other words, we would disadvantage some of the other measures that will, undoubtedly, be introduced. Things can be done to address promotions and discounting whereby someone buys three products for the price of two, which encourages people to buy more alcohol. In Scotland, we are not particularly renowned for storing our alcohol.
Except inside ourselves.
Yes, and that is not for very long. Essentially, such promotions encourage us to drink more and more frequently. We undertook a brief study on the issue that suggested that that was the case. People buy more and return more frequently when alcohol is discounted, so stopping discounting would be an important measure.
I made the case earlier that floor price—the price of the cheapest alcohol—is the most important factor. If we are going to start somewhere, that is where we should start. Affecting the price on the shelf is what matters.
That would be very helpful.
However, our work did not come up with any realistic option other than minimum pricing. That is just in relation to price—I agree with all the other measures, which would reinforce the basic measure of changing the price in relation to disposable income.
We know that alcohol is a tremendous problem in Scotland and we learn that 70 per cent of it—we might quibble about a percentage point or two—is bought in supermarkets, where some alcohol is sold at very low prices. We have also heard evidence that when changes in duty have been attempted, outlets have boasted that they have absorbed the duty increase so that the shelf price remains the same. Apart from the rest of the United Kingdom, do you know of any country where there is such a strong link between the sale of alcohol and the purchase of other grocery goods—or is the UK only place in the world where that link occurs?
Convener, I first have another supplementary, which I hope will not take long.
Rhoda Grant, I think, mentioned the Finnish experience. Sadly, we in Scotland have much more experience of the impact that falling prices have on the heaviest drinkers than we have of the reverse. My experience over 20 years is that alcohol-dependent people are not brand loyal—or even drink loyal—but will switch. They used to drink super-strenth lagers, they switched to white ciders when those came on to the market and they have now switched to vodka.
Speaking from a service provider’s perspective, I point out that some of our services are specifically for alcohol-related brain damage. We also have services for homeless people, many of whom have serious drink problems, and more of our mental health services are now dealing with people with serious alcohol problems. We are working with the kind of heaviest drinkers we have been discussing; indeed, when we put together our submission for the committee we considered the issue very carefully and spoke to the people who work in the area. Obviously we do not have the wherewithal to put together a proper model, but our perception is that consumption would fall as a result of minimum pricing. We know that it is not a magic wand; it will not fix everything and people will not stop drinking just because of it, but we think that it will lead to a reduction in consumption and the associated reduction in harm to health that Peter Rice talked about.
Colleagues of mine who work with people with severe dependency and who visit the wards have been asking questions about what would happen if the policy were introduced. Such drinkers have a fixed budget and buy as much as they can for their money, so if the alcohol is much more expensive they will buy less of it.
I am coming to you shortly.
I am going to help you.
You are going to help me?
Yes. Mary Scanlon has covered my question, apart from one small point, which is about the booze cruise phenomenon that we have seen in England and France. I ask the witnesses to add that point into their answers.
It is difficult to have a booze cruise between Hawick and Carlisle, but we will think about it.
What about between Rosyth and Zeebrugge and Scotland and Ireland?
I will give some quick-fire answers. It would be great to know more about cross-border sales. Again, the industry will have a lot of data on that. I doubt whether people will travel to buy cheap cider in the same way as they travel to buy a cheaper version of an expensive malt. With minimum pricing, we are talking about the cheapest alcohol and I do not think that the cross-border traffic will be the same for that.
That has not answered my question. With respect, Dr Rice has not answered it either and nor did he answer Mary Scanlon’s point.
I will leave that hanging in the air as it is a really good question for the supermarkets. We can ask them about internet ordering because they are hot potatoes on that now.
That highlights the lack of an impact assessment for various issues. That has not been done in the Sheffield report, which had a limited remit.
I thought that the Aberlour Child Care Trust’s submission was excellent, first-class and very interesting to read. On page 3, you say:
We are particularly interested in the impact on families and children of parental problem drinking and, indeed, drug use. We know that those things are not mutually exclusive. In many families alcohol and drug problems occur together, and we need to do a lot more to identify earlier children who might be at risk and to put in the necessary support. Such an approach is not cheap, but the resources need to be in place.
That is the point. The big point that will emerge from this morning’s evidence is that many issues that the panel members have raised in their written and oral evidence are not in the bill.
Within the scope of the bill, we have advocated that some of the money raised by a social responsibility levy on off-licences could be used in some way for the public good. One of our suggestions was that it could be used for investment in youth services. Perhaps it could also be used to find ways of identifying and supporting children earlier.
First and foremost, we are not against the principle of a social responsibility levy. The point that we are trying to make is that it has to be targeted where it will make a difference and will not be to the detriment of good initiatives that are under way. For a long time, our student associations have had to deal with the idea of having a duty of care to their members, because they are very different from commercial operations. That has ranged from participating in initiatives such as best bar none, which is a scheme that gives student associations the opportunity to win awards for ensuring that they have a positive impact and observe a positive duty of care to their customers. Many student associations also run alcohol awareness initiatives. A few student associations have started to work with universities to help to educate academics in early intervention over problems associated with alcohol. There are many good initiatives but, if a social responsibility levy were introduced, it would take money away from developing those activities. I do not think that student associations are alone in having a culture of responsibility for what their members do. The proposal would also have a detrimental impact on other organisations, which is contrary to the bill’s intention. If money is to be generated from a social responsibility levy, we support the idea that it should be focused on local communities. It should be directed to the communities where it is generated so that a difference can be made there, rather than being kept centrally.
What are the panel’s thoughts on a waiver of the social responsibility levy? YouthLink Scotland’s submission proposes that the levy should be waived for certain on-sales and off-sales licence holders. I invite it to justify that.
I do not think that the bill is clear enough about the conditions in which the levy would be applied.
One difficulty that we have with the proposal is that it is aimed, as Bruce Thomson said, at drinks whose price relative to their alcohol content is low. As the French Government has discovered, unless one has a clever formula to create an equation that combines sugar and alcohol, and tax that accordingly, it is difficult to increase the price of alcopops.
One of the questions that we were asked to answer in our submission was specifically about the level at which the proposed minimum price should be set. We looked at the evidence that accompanied the request to provide evidence to the committee on the bill, particularly the Sheffield study. After considering the impact of a minimum price on a range of alcohol use, we decided that a price of 50p per unit seemed to be the level at which we could get the most benefit without putting the price out of the range of normal social drinkers. We were comfortable with a minimum price of 50p.
My second question is on a completely different subject—the proposal that provides the capacity to limit the sale of alcohol to under-21s, which, as I understand it, is still in the bill, although the Aberlour Child Care Trust seems to take a different view. I believe that section 8 contains that proposal, although the trust said in its submission that it might have opposed the bill if it had continued to contain such a provision. In other words, it thought that the provision had been removed. However, I will not debate that, if Bruce Thomson does not mind, and we can agree to disagree. The trust’s view is not material, because section 8 is in the bill.
That is helpful because the Association of Chief Police Officers in Scotland is coming before us on 17 March.
Even if one accepted those figures and was not as critical of them as Liam Burns is, they come from an experiment that was based on the current existence of cheap alcohol. The purpose of the bill is to eliminate that issue. If that element of the bill is successful, part of the reason for raising the age from 18 to 21 will have been removed, will it not?
If you are asking whether that means that the change in age should not be pursued, I agree absolutely.
Do you agree, Mr Burns? You are nodding, are you not?
To clarify, I am looking at the matter in the round. We are considering the whole impact of the proposed legislative package. If we maximise the opportunity that it presents on a societal scale, the debate about whether the drinking age should be 18 or 21 will probably not be as significant as it currently is.
It is paragraph 3.1 on page 2.
That is helpful—thank you.
It should happen in parallel. On the link between price, consumption and harm, if we assume that consumption and therefore harm must go down when price goes up, that will be very good for children growing up in problem-drinking families. However, if the problem is more intractable than that, so that a price rise does not reduce consumption but results in people paying more for alcohol—we are talking about families who already have very limited means—we are concerned about the impact of that on meeting children’s basic needs for food, clothing and so on. We therefore said in our submission that we support the principle of minimum pricing but that its impact on families should be monitored to ensure that it works.
In your and your organisation’s experience of working with children and families in such situations, do you think that such research could reasonably be undertaken in parallel with the minimum pricing policy being in place?
No, I would like to follow up Ross Finnie’s first question.
No, you—
Whatever. You are friends, so you can resolve it. Rhoda, are you deferring to Richard—for once?
I think that the word that you were looking for was “counterfeited“.
The official report may wish to put that in instead, gently to amend as we go. I do not know whether we are entitled to ask that.
In our written evidence, we explained that we see minimum pricing as only one way of tackling the issue. We have seen some of the Finnish research, which shows that there is not an exact link between price and consumption. However, from what we have seen, there is enough evidence to suggest that, as price changes, consumption habits change. Price is one important way of tackling the real crisis in drinking that exists in Scotland, which is why we have supported minimum pricing.
The University of Sheffield study did not consider the impact of a minimum price on different income groups. Given that the jury is still out about the real impact, I am concerned that a minimum price might affect the child who is growing up in a low-income family in which alcohol is already being abused. Could a minimum price for alcohol create more problems for such children? Should we consider alternatives—and, indeed, consider the impact on different income groups—before implementing a minimum pricing policy, so that we can see whether the policy stacks up?
Right. I also welcome Dr Bruce Ritson, chair of Scottish Health Action on Alcohol Problems; Dr Emilia Crighton, convener of the committee of the Faculty of Public Health in Scotland; Jack Law, chief executive of Alcohol Focus Scotland; and Carolyn Roberts, head of policy and campaigns at the Scottish Association for Mental Health.
I was just trying to be helpful to the convener. I did not realise that it was going to cause a kerfuffle.
Hang on a minute. You have far greater knowledge and understanding of these matters; parliamentarians acquire that knowledge by taking evidence. The whole purpose of taking evidence is to guide and help us. We do not pluck figures out of the air and vote on them; we vote on the basis of evidence. With all due respect, we are looking to people with your levels of knowledge, understanding and experience to assist us. It is not a matter just for the Parliament.
If I were to absolutely guarantee that my colleagues and I would take account of all material economic changes between now and then—which would be the sensible and rational thing to do—what should our starting point be?
Based on the current evidence, most of our faculty members went for 60p in the survey that we conducted, simply because of their desire to maximise the public health benefit. Any price in the range that has been suggested in the evidence would be acceptable, because it would have an impact but, as public health specialists, our members wish to maximise the benefit to the population. That is why we gave that figure in our submission.
I have little to add to what the other witnesses have said, other than to remind ourselves that we are talking about the relationship between price and consumption. Irrespective of the eventual outcome of the Administration’s decision, all the modelling suggests that there is a range of minimum unit prices that would be effective. That is the important point. Certain factors would need to be considered in that context, such as price inflation. We are in a period in which it seems that inflation will increase. It is difficult to give a specific unit price at the moment, because all the other factors must be taken into account. However, Alcohol Focus Scotland believes that a range of 45p to 60p is a reasonable one within which to set the price. According to the modelling that has been done, anything less than that would not really have the required impact on overall population consumption.
That is the importance of modelling; it creates an understanding that enables decision makers to make the right decision.
I do not have much to add. I agree with what my colleagues have said: it is not appropriate to set a price immediately; you have to take into account the change in economic conditions between now and when a price would be set. I do not think that we are the best organisation to advise on setting a price.
I got lost in your question. You all followed it, but I got a bit lost. I thought that we were talking about raising the age limit from 18 to 21.
We are.
I am sorry. It is my fault, not yours.
The Faculty of Public Health says that it thinks price is more important than the age limit. My second point is that some have referred specifically in their evidence to cheap alcohol in off-sales and yet one of the purposes of the bill is to change that. I was just asking whether they would still support raising the age to 21.
Would you increase the age as a matter of principle, not just for off-sales but for on-sales?
In terms of consequences for health there is a good case for it; in terms of fairness and many of the other issues that have been debated, it would have to be very carefully evaluated.
I have not seen those data so I cannot comment, but perhaps one of my colleagues can.
Forgive me for having a healthy scepticism about modelling given that people throughout the UK are victims of modelling when it comes to road design, traffic modelling and weather forecasts.
The case for the influence of price on consumption is well made. Long before the modelling study was undertaken, SHAAP commissioned a study of price measures that might reduce harm. It was published about two years ago. The evidence that price influences consumption was very strong.
It would be useful if members of the committee could be told, though. We do not have that letter.
Could you tell us which parts of what you are saying are quotations and which bits are your comments?
Here are the quotations. Page 7 of the Sheffield study says:
It is from the letter from Dr Rice and Dr Ritson.
Since that letter was written, there has been an uplift in investment in alcohol treatment services of about £80 million. In Tayside, to answer your—
I am sorry, I have just been corrected by Mary Scanlon. It is £130 million, not £90 million.
No, please, Helen.
A further uplift in investment in treatment would be welcome. We have shown that we have been able to deliver using the increase in investment that we have already had, and we will continue to do that across the whole sector.
If we are victims of modelling on the roads and in weather forecasts, we are victims of modelling on the minimum wage. Modelling is a way of exploring the what-ifs when complex reality exists. Modelling is widely used and it has been used in positive ways in health.
Saying that no mechanisms are proposed in the bill to recoup some of the money is a false assertion; there are several. The social responsibility fee is the most obvious. It would enable not all but some money to be taken back. Another mechanism exists—taxation. Companies are taxed on their profits. If the profits were significant, some of them would go back to the Exchequer.
The data that I quoted from Scandinavia are based on the behaviour of Swedish consumers in those stores. I do not know whether that counts as evidence in your book, but that is where that information is from.
First and foremost, modelling can be seen as evidence. We cannot design a randomised controlled trial to put populations through minimum pricing, taxation or any other measure, so we need to build a model of the reality of using different interventions, and the best way we can achieve that is to use mathematics. It would be unethical to have randomised controlled trials of minimum pricing.
We know that there is an extremely strong relationship between the misuse of alcohol and mental health problems. That is one of the main reasons why SAMH broadly supports the bill. Up to one patient in two who have alcohol problems will also have a mental health problem. The recent national confidential inquiry into suicide by people with mental health problems specifically stated that it is likely that alcohol and drugs lie behind Scotland’s high rates of suicide. Also, around a sixth of all discharges from psychiatric hospitals are alcohol related.
You mentioned mental health, which was timely because that is the topic that I want to get on to. Many of the submissions discuss our complex and cultural relationship with alcohol. We drink when we are happy and when we are sad; we also drink to celebrate. My question is not so much about liver disease or alcohol-related brain disease, which is mentioned in the SAMH submission, but about the comment in the Audit Scotland report that up to three out of four problem drinkers have an underlying health problem. Would you and Peter Rice comment on alcohol as a form of self-medication and the elasticity of demand for those people in terms of minimum pricing?
You are right to raise that. Alcohol can be used as a form of self-medication. That is why we were clear in our submission that we support minimum pricing but a broader range of measures is needed. Through our own experience we know that people who are seen as having alcohol problems often also have mental health problems but, because they have been sent to an alcohol service, their mental health needs are not met. The same happens in reverse.
I acknowledge Mary Scanlon’s long-standing interest in the issue—indeed, we have discussed it in the cross-party group on mental health. The fact is that alcohol abuse and mental health problems go hand in hand. As members will know, a group that I chaired produced for the Government a report that suggested that the two issues are so intertwined that we need services that deal with both and do not simply pass people from pillar to post. That is certainly what we try to achieve in our services.
A male who lives in a deprived area is 11 times more likely—a female is six times more likely—to die from the effects of chronic liver disease on the back of alcohol. Our poor communities are already severely affected, so any measures that reduce the amount of alcohol that people consume would have a beneficial effect.
I will be unfashionable and say men, who are often forgotten about. There is a lot of focus on the changes in women’s drinking, but the lines on the graph follow each other in parallel and it is easy for men to get forgotten about. The other group is older people. For example, the over-45s are among those who have the fastest-rising rates of hospital admissions. I guess we must admit that they are older people.
They are still young to me.
Well, the over-65s—I will test this one out—have hospital admission rates that are rising fast in Scotland.
Last week, I spoke to Professor Colin Drummond of the national addiction centre, who told me that he had looked at survey data from England that showed that the rates of hazardous consumption are rising fastest in women over 65; it is from a low base, but the rates are increasing fastest in that group.
I am anxious about the whole population. Overall, we are drinking far too much. The effect on people living in the most deprived areas is more marked. I am most concerned about the west of Scotland, because we drink far too much.
The answer is that we should be concerned about pretty well everyone, although there may be certain groups that we should be particularly concerned about, which may shift.
Minimum pricing is not the only measure that the Government is proposing. Changing the culture is not to do with minimum pricing by itself. It is also to do with everything else that goes with it. It is about changing the mindset. It is about the fact that we now have a dialogue. The papers are full of articles saying that we drink too much. It is all those things that will make people think twice when they go to buy alcohol. I have certainly changed the way in which I run the faculty conference. I allow just enough alcohol to be within the drinking limits. Those are the kind of changes that we will see because of the wider debate, and minimum pricing will be one of the measures.
Richard Simpson is right, but the debate is not just about minimum pricing. Unfortunately, the discourse has been pushed towards minimum pricing for many different reasons. We might have different views about that. We argue that minimum pricing is an important part of the package of approaches because it underpins so much else that needs to go on, but I remind you that the bill contains other things to do with education, improving knowledge and understanding of alcohol, working in communities to shift and change understanding and attitudes, and improving people’s knowledge of harmful and non-harmful drinking. All those things are part of the package.
As Jack Law said, there is a range of actions. I would add that, for hazardous drinkers, screening and brief intervention are important. If that can be achieved throughout Scotland, huge numbers of people will be positively influenced. Primary health care is the key area for that. Breath testing and driving limits will also have an effect on hazardous drinkers.
Are members cold? I feel the temperature dropping. I would like somebody who is in front of a control panel somewhere to know that we are cold. The witnesses must be getting cold—just say yes, so that we can have the heating turned up.
This feels more like the hot seat.
What is your response to the argument that modelling is not evidence?
Yesterday, I was involved in a decision in Angus to invest a six-figure sum in prescribing software that encourages general practitioners to prescribe generic rather than branded products to save money. It is estimated that that will save £700,000 over the next year. We went for it on the basis of calculations about the number of branded products that are prescribed and the difference in price of the cheaper generic products, multiplying the figures to reflect how much prescribing goes on in Angus. We made that decision because everybody thought that it was a good idea to save money. That is an example of a real decision that was made on the basis of modelling.
I would ask how real you are about trying to do something that is effective. It is clear from WHO evidence that dealing with pricing and dealing with availability are the two most effective ways of tackling alcohol consumption. Therefore, we do not see any alternative that would achieve the same as the implementation of minimum pricing together with a ban on discounting.
I agree with all that has been said. We considered some other mechanisms on price. As has already been mentioned, taxation is not a mechanism that is available to us. Furthermore, the merit of taxation has been undermined in recent years by the power of the multinational corporations, which can absorb tax increases or redistribute them over other commodities. As we have seen from recent figures, some of the impact of taxation has been weakened.
That is a very interesting question. I very rarely see pub drinkers in my clinical work now—that has changed over the 20 years that I have been in practice—and the same thing came out of the survey that was done in Edinburgh. There has been a big shift in drinking. It is difficult to run a good pub now, given the competition.
If that is the case and the situation and the relationship with alcohol in this country are fairly unique, we are perhaps wasting our time waiting for evidence from other countries where the same situation does not exist, as there will be different ways to deal with the matter elsewhere; the solutions elsewhere will be different. Do you agree?
Absolutely. Scotland has escalating consumption and harm at almost epidemic proportions, as I think we all agree. We compare very unfavourably with most of the rest of Europe in that respect. The situation is exceptional and just tinkering will not be enough. That is what seems to be coming across. That exceptional situation exists for a variety of reasons.
We will hear responses from Dr Rice, Ms Roberts and then Dr Crighton before I let Mary Scanlon and Helen Eadie ask their supplementaries. I advise both members that time is pressing, so I hope that their questions are new and short. We have had an hour and a half with this panel; I do not want us to go over old stuff again.
Mary Scanlon, do you have a short supplementary?
Well, it is not short. I asked only a very short question on mental health and I think that this question is important.
No.
As you say, the data on reduction in consumption come from the Scottish health survey. It does not matter how accurate they try to be, people will always be subject to recall bias when they are asked how much they drink. I can give you the exact figures that you referred to in your question. According to the survey, alcohol consumption fell from 34 per cent in 2003 to 30 per cent in 2008, but that figure is based on a certain number of males saying that they cut down on their drinking, which does not mean anything. A more accurate measurement is the amount of alcohol that has been released for consumption, which has plateaued. Of course, it, too, has certain shortcomings as a proxy for alcohol consumption because, for example, not everyone drinks the same. We continue to see hospital admissions because we are still drinking. The pattern of drinking might have changed because, after all, the issue is not only what you drink but how you drink. If someone is completely plastered at the weekend and becomes acutely ill and comatose, they will end up in casualty. We still see that, despite the drop from 34 to 30 per cent. That means that the patterns of drinking are different and that we continue to drink quite a lot.
Dr Crighton can have the last comment. That is for my own comfort, because I am absolutely frozen and I do not know what has happened to the man at the controls.
That is right Helen—you stand up for me.
I am glad that you are chairing the meeting, now, Mary, because I am about to abdicate. Could somebody deal with the booze cruise issue?
That point has been made several times in several evidence sessions.
With regard to Bruce Thomson’s comments about messages from young people and relationships within families, YouthLink Scotland strongly supports the whole-population approach to alcohol. In our “Being Young in Scotland 2009” survey, the results of which were launched just last week, young people strongly indicate that families and their peers within the family circle are the most important influence on them. Our concern is that we tackle this as a whole society issue and do not focus only on young people.
I am grateful for those comments, but I remind the panel that we are taking evidence on a bill, so I ask you to focus on what is in the bill. We agree with many of your comments, but we want to test what is in the bill and establish whether you think that it will work and whether you disagree with it. It will be helpful if they focus on what is in the bill, or on what is not in it but ought to be.
However, we must bear in mind that the purpose of a bill limits what can go into it. We cannot start bolting stuff on to a bill, even though it may have its inadequacies. At this stage, we are considering the bill at stage 1 and I would like the general focus to be on the measures that the Government is trying to implement. People are entitled to make other comments, but it will help us to deal with what is before us today if they focus on the bill.
I have a supplementary on Bruce Thomson’s response to Mary Scanlon. It is concerning that we know about children out there who need help but, because of how we offer help, will not accept or are afraid to accept it. Could we add something to the bill that would make help available to young people in a way that is acceptable to them?
My question relates primarily to the NUS Scotland submission, which I was interested in for a number of reasons. NUS Scotland has given a lot of thought to the issue and it has also recognised issues with the legal competence of the bill—I congratulate you on having picked up on that.
The national organisation of which we are a part, NUS UK, is working on that. The stimulus for it was a different debate. In England, the debate about minimum pricing is based on on-sales rather than the off-trade. That started a debate within our membership about what we should do on minimum pricing, which led to a wider discussion about whether we should have a minimum standard that all our members must achieve with regard to their duty of care to their members. That work is proceeding through the NUS and our buying consortium, and we are fairly interested in introducing such a standard in Scotland.
The proposal picks up on a point that the NUS made. Some retailers are responsible. They comply with the proof-of-age schemes and ask people for proof of age when they come into their establishments, particularly in rural areas where the service might be attached to a small corner shop or a post office. We would like those retailers’ efforts to be recognised and not dismissed. If people make extra effort, that should be supported rather than penalised.
Section 10(3) states that the purpose of the social responsibility levy is to meet expenditure that is incurred
Good morning. I have two questions on separate aspects.
We have given broad support to minimum pricing because it tackles what I regard as one of the roots of the problem: consumption by parents who are looking after their children. The minimum price must be set at a level that impacts on consumption, because we want to achieve reduced consumption across a fairly wide range of the population. It is important not to get sidetracked into thinking purely about heavy, problematic drinkers who may already be in touch with social services—we are looking at the wider range of drinking.
Absolutely not. As we understand it, the idea of the drinking age proposal was, as you say, to deal with the issue of access to alcohol, particularly by underage drinkers. We have a huge issue with the fact that the debate seems to be operating in an evidence vacuum. We know that the number of prosecutions for underage drinking is incredibly low and that enforcement of the current law has been nowhere near stringent enough. That should be the Government’s focus, not bolting on legislation simply to deal with the failings of the current legislation.
I agree that enforcement of the current legislation is a significant issue. If we are having difficulty enforcing a minimum age of 18, I am not quite sure what difference increasing the minimum age to 21 will make. When the use of the Young Scot card as a proof-of-age card has been backed up by the provision of support such as the age-restricted sales pack that North Lanarkshire Council has provided for retailers in its area to help with enforcement, it has proved more successful than the alternatives.
We are heavily guided by the views that we heard from young people at an event that we held last year at which they clearly told us that they felt stigmatised by approaches to alcohol that focused purely on their age group. Young people’s drinking is certainly problematic, but it is often more visible because they may be drinking in our communities, whereas the heavy drinking that happens throughout our society is more hidden because it takes place in pubs or at home, which is a growing issue. The idea that problematic drinking is not okay at 20 but is okay at 22 loses sight of some of the priorities in tackling alcohol issues. On that basis, we did not support any change in the age.
The Salvation Army made no substantive comment on that question when it made its submission. However, the earlier the age of onset of drinking behaviour, the more problematic that behaviour becomes as the person gets older. If the purpose of the bill is, as Mr Finnie has clearly said, to use the current legislation to enforce the age of 18 as the cut-off point for the use of alcohol, I agree with his argument. If we can delay the onset of drinking behaviour through the alcohol bill, the societal benefits in a generation in Scotland will be significant. I agree that raising the drinking age to 21 as a stand-alone measure would not be as effective as ensuring that we drive through the other parts of the bill. If we do that, perhaps the drinking age will not be the concern that we currently think it is.
It would be helpful for the official report if you could say what page and paragraph you are referring to.
The issue that we were trying to elaborate on was not the minimum unit price. The big issue for us is the promotion of alcohol through, for example, the promotional activities of supermarkets, in that people who might previously have bought only a couple of cans now buy a couple of cases, because the pricing is more attractive. We perhaps should have clarified that point in our submission. Our approach is to consider all the evidence, but there were mixed views among our membership about minimum pricing. However, members recognised the damage that is being done by many of the promotional aspects of the sale of alcohol and believe that that must be tackled.
Would it be fair to say that YouthLink’s view is that price must be one of the components to be addressed in dealing with the issue of cheap alcohol?
In Finland, we were impressed that the public health message asked parents to examine their conscience about the effect that their drinking was having on their family. We all agreed that the advertising was clever and forced people to question their drinking. We also discovered that, as a consequence of that, the level of drinking among those aged 18 to 25 had fallen significantly. We have heard about the issues regarding peers and families, and we have heard from the NUS about the issues for young people. There seems to be an assumption that drinking is a problem for young people, but, if we look only at young people and think that they are the problem, we will miss what the Finns are doing. One of the most impressive things that we saw on our visit was the public health message, which made parents look at the effect of their drinking on their relationships with their children. It was a very powerful message.
It is useful to put that on the record. The advertising was focused on the child’s point of view. The parent thought that they were dancing with the child, or the father thought that he was embracing the child, but they were being rough and the child was being hurt. The parent did not realise it because of their intoxication. That was a very powerful message. I do not know whether you have come across that in the projects that your various organisations have undertaken. We will move on, but I thought that it was useful to point out that we had seen that and had been impressed with it.
Do you want to go first, Rhoda?
My feeling is that we are focusing too much on minimum unit pricing. I want to bring us back to the child issues, which are crucial, in order to address what is missing from the bill. In my experience as a consultant in addictions working with alcohol problems, I found that the presence of children in problem families was not being recorded—that was simply not happening when I worked in Glasgow, Edinburgh and West Lothian. The bill does not require the recording of that information by treatment services.
I welcome the comments that have been made about the Young Scot card. I was involved in its early days, as it changed from what was known as a dumb card to a smart card. I find that gratifying—that is nearly 10 years ago now. The big thing that has changed the situation round and brought about a lack of counterfeiting has been the engagement of young people in the process. They feel ownership in their local areas, as they are involved through the discounts that are offered. The education services have been engaged, and the engagement of young people in the process has helped that change to take place. If we are to consider some form of enforcement with local authorities in other areas, we need to continue with that engagement with young people. That is where success lies.
I think that that is a question that was not answered. It could be put into legislation that local authorities or NHS boards are required to publish annually or be audited on their strategies for dealing with alcohol problems in their area.
Over the past 50 years, the trend has been that alcohol consumption in this country has more than doubled while the price in real terms has come down significantly. Another point is that using minimum pricing as a lever was first proposed, I think, by the royal colleges of medicine.
We have already commented that we think both things could be done in parallel. On balance, we feel that minimum pricing is worth trying. The policy could have a significant impact, but no one in this room knows what the impact will be. Our view is that, on balance, the policy is worth trying but it would need widespread support to work. In addition, the policy could not work in isolation from other measures, which, as people have suggested, need to be part of the whole package.
I have found this evidence session very helpful. Indeed, the convener will be pleased to hear that some of my questions have already been answered. We all agree that much more needs to be done about our society’s alcohol problem than can be done in this—and probably in any—bill, because the problem is not just for the Government but for the whole of society. I think that we all accept that all sorts of different things need to be done to tackle the issue. However, for the moment, we are considering the bill.
We have already considered the level of the minimum price in response to Ross Finnie’s question, to which we heard two counter-arguments. Mr Thomson has already addressed the impact that minimum pricing will have on family budgets, so I think that we are going back over old ground. Therefore, I feel that it is time to bring this evidence session to an end. I thank the witnesses very much for their evidence, which has been very helpful.
The witnesses on our second panel represent medical and health organisations. I welcome Dr Peter Rice, consultant psychiatrist at the British Medical Association Scotland and chairman of the Royal College of Psychiatrists. Are you wearing both hats today?
Yes.
I was going to go on to say that the Parliament requires good data and good econometric modelling. The committee has already taken some evidence on that. Considerably more data are available than we have had access to in the past. An enormous amount of data is available from retailers on a localised basis, and that could feed into the debate.
I want to add something before Carolyn Roberts comes in. I do not think that there is too much argument about the relationship; the difficulty that arises in connection with the bill’s principles and whether it will be effective is that there has to be a significant change to justify the kind of market interference that is proposed. That is why we want to be clearer about what we mean by “significant”, which relates to the price that you would impose.
I will start answering the question, which was addressed to us specifically. We have looked at the effectiveness of different interventions. In our answer to the specific questions, we argued that interventions on price and availability are more effective than simply changing the age limit. Therefore, we strongly support the principle of minimum pricing and banning discounts, which will reduce the availability of cheap drink to this specific group of individuals. We are not necessarily against raising the age limit, but reducing availability and modifying the price would be higher in the hierarchy of effectiveness of interventions.
Perhaps I can say a bit about the under-18s, because drinking among that group is an important issue. The Scottish schools adolescent lifestyle and substance use survey of 13 and 15-year-olds shows us that, increasingly in Scotland, access to alcohol for 13 and 15-year-olds is through agents—third-party purchase; it is not through direct purchase. Age verification schemes have worked and have led to quite big changes in purchasing practice. The opportunity for 15-year-olds to buy has fallen. Their access is now through agent purchase rather than buying alcohol themselves.
The approach that Peter Rice suggests is sensible, but I remind the committee that we are talking about relationships between initiatives. We have a major alcohol problem in Scotland. The price of alcohol is undoubtedly one of the issues. Alcohol is incredibly cheap, which means that it is more readily available to young people on a limited income. Attached to that is the issue of licensing and enforcement. One of the primary objectives of the Licensing (Scotland) Act 2005 is the promotion and improvement of public health, which this bill also seeks to tackle. The question is about availability and enforcement of the law. We keep missing the fact that the first point of enforcement of licensing legislation is the licensee. If there has been a failure in the voluntary codes on the introduction of challenge 21 and so on across the board, something else needs to be introduced.
I am sorry to interrupt, but can you give the number of the page of the paper to which you are referring for the official report?
I do not have the briefing paper with me; it was circulated previously, to me at least. It states that where social reference pricing
We have not taken evidence from Dr Stockwell, but we will have—
I would like to follow up on what has been said. SPICe spoke to Dr Timothy Stockwell, who is head of the centre for addictions research of British Columbia and was part of the systematic review team for the Sheffield research. He confirmed that there is no published evidence that social reference pricing has had any significant beneficial effect except for Canadian distillers, as it guarantees a stable market and stable profit margins. Do you concede that Dr Stockwell is well placed to know about that issue?
Dr Stockwell is well placed to comment. The point that has been made has been identified as one of the weaknesses in Canada, where there is an interesting range and mix of price controls. In general, there have not been the rises in alcohol-related harm in Canada that there have been here, so there are lessons to be learned from it, but I think that it is recognised that it has not evaluated things as well as it should have done.
I am quoting from a private letter between Jackie Baillie and a number of other people—
I am happy to read out the quotations.
Who is that quotation from?
To answer your question about what difference that investment has made to treatment, we have three times as many people in specialist alcohol treatment as we had a year ago; we delivered 3,500 brief interventions in general practice last year—
I think that he has misunderstood my point, though, convener.
You asked what difference an investment of £90 million would make in terms of treatment.
That is not the question that I asked.
My point is that that £90 million—or £130 million—will not go into the public purse. It would make a huge difference to you if it did, but it will not; it will go into private commerce. That is what the bill would do.
Further investment would be welcome. There has been a big uplift in investment in alcohol services in the past two years. That has made a difference.
There is no mention of further investment—
In the written papers that we received from the witnesses, you all talk about evidence, but you have now admitted to us that you are talking only about modelling. That seems to be the case.
Let me say to everybody—not just Helen Eadie—that we should have shorter questions.
We must bear it in mind that the disadvantaged communities of Scotland suffer most because of alcohol-related problems. The number of deaths from liver disease is vastly higher in some of the most deprived areas. We have to take that into account when we consider the benefits to deprived areas. We have to argue from a health point of view.
Including measures, for example, to treat those with mental health problems to stop them resorting to alcohol?
Given that people in non-deprived areas have more disposable income you might say that if the issue was the affordability of alcohol more affluent people would have higher rates of chronic alcohol-related disease. Given your answers, we are perhaps missing something. Why do people in deprived communities appear to fare worse from alcohol consumption? Why does alcohol have more impact on their health? Are there other measures that we should take? Is the impact on people in deprived communities greater because they have fewer life chances and are more dependent on alcohol? No one is saying that they are more dependent on alcohol, but the evidence seems to suggest that the impact of alcohol on deprived communities is greater. Why is that the case?
That is an interesting question that cuts right across health inequalities work. Cigarette by cigarette, deprived communities are harder hit by smoking disease than affluent communities; we do not fully understand the reasons for that. With alcohol, we have clues that there may be a dietary factor. I am working with colleagues to put together some research into the issue. Green vegetable consumption varies considerably across Scotland and the United Kingdom. There are theoretical reasons for thinking that it might protect against liver disease, for example.
As Dr Rice indicated, we do not know fully why alcohol has a greater impact on deprived communities. We know from the Scottish health survey that people who live in deprived areas are more likely than people in the more affluent sections of society to drink heavily—more than 50 units a week. We have still to find out why, but we must take measures to reduce consumption, as prevention is the only way of reducing the inequalities that we currently face.
Yes, there has been such work. Alcohol is a gateway drug for other drugs. Young people who drink will also smoke and use other drugs; young people who use less alcohol will smoke less and use other drugs less. The only setting in which any substitution behaviour has been shown is in nightclubs during the rave era—access to stimulants reduced alcohol purchases in such close spaces—but in the great big wide world we can be fairly clear that alcohol is a gateway drug, so if people drink less, they will use tobacco and illicit drugs less.
We are all silent.
I reiterate that we are concerned about the whole population. As a population, we are drinking far more than is good for us. However, there are certain cohorts that we are particularly concerned about, one of which—older people—has already been mentioned. A recent survey that Alcohol Focus did through one of our projects found that more than 85 per cent of the respondents of pensionable age drank significantly on a daily basis and had very little knowledge of the impact that their alcohol consumption was having on their general health and wellbeing, or of the relationship between their alcohol consumption and any medication that they were taking.
First and foremost, minimum pricing will affect everyone, more or less. Making small changes for very large numbers of people in the population will have a significant effect. What we will see with minimum pricing is a population shift. We have modelled the benefits from that. I would argue that it is not true to say that it will not affect moderate drinkers. It will, but in smaller numbers. Again, people will not behave in a homogeneous way. Within the population, different individuals will behave in different ways.
Some questions that I wanted to ask have been covered. I do not have a background in the field of modelling for the purpose of developing public health and other policy measures and I am conscious that questions have been asked about the work that the University of Sheffield undertook. The CEBR report, which has been mentioned, critiqued and expressed concerns about the university’s report, although I should say that the critique was sponsored by SABMiller, which has a clear interest.
It is quite hot here.
My nose is cold.
I have nothing to add on the acceptability of modelling in public health—it has been clearly stated. The methodology of the Sheffield study received a strong endorsement from scientists and alcohol specialists around the world when it was published recently in a peer-reviewed journal. Modelling is not only well established; it was seen as a real advance in methodology on these issues.
There is no question but that price is one of the factors that must be addressed in dealing with the alcohol problem. If we were not to go down the route of minimum pricing, what alternative method could we use to address the issue of the price of alcohol in Scotland?
The WHO regularly surveys alcohol consumption across the world, and a report showing what happens in different countries is available. There are some countries in which there is a monopoly on the sale of alcohol—there are specific shops where people have to go. In the UK, we have allowed supermarkets to run how alcohol pricing has developed. There has been a shift in the amount of alcohol that gets sold through their premises, simply because of prices dropping year on year compared with the retail prices index.
That is why we are using the modelling, which tries to put the current situation into the mathematics.
We have frequently heard that Scotland has a unique relationship with alcohol. From what my public health colleagues are saying, that seems to be the case. We may well have to consider unique ways to address the situation. Other countries might not have done exactly what is proposed here but, given the state of the relationship with alcohol in this country, we might well need to consider things that have not been tried elsewhere.
It is useful that we will take evidence next week from the representatives of individual supermarkets as well as from the producers. Two other members want to ask a supplementary question.
Let me make two points. First, the study that was done a long time ago in Scotland—it was an Edinburgh-based study back in the 1980s, which seems very long ago—showed that the heaviest drinkers reduced their consumption significantly and that the level of harm that they experienced also reduced significantly. They did not just carry on drinking at the previous level and pass on the cost to other family members. There was no evidence for that.
And no one else has asked it?
We have to put some of the statistics into historical context. We have more than doubled our alcohol consumption in the past 50 years. Our starting point now is a significant level, which has a considerable impact. There has been a 500 per cent increase in liver disease in the past 25 years and a 700 per cent increase in women in their 20s with chronic liver disease in the past 20 years. We are starting with an extremely high level of evidence of significant alcohol misuse.
I agree with my colleagues that consumption data are a better indicator than survey data. It has always been a pity that we do not get customs data at a Scotland level, as they would tell us where we really stand. As Mary Scanlon said, the evidence from the Nielsen data is that consumption has plateaued. I would be interested to see those data corrected for age. The population is getting older, and although older people drink more than they used to they drink less than younger people, so we would expect the per capita consumption to be falling a bit because of demographic changes, but it looks as though it is stable at about 12.2 to 12.4 litres.
The data that I am using are dated 23 February and they came from the Information Services Division.
Convener—
I understand. I am sorry—I was being flippant, because I am cold.
I will be brief. None of the aspects that have been mentioned is a concern because the current pattern of consumption in Scotland is not particularly based on them. On cross-border sales, we are lobbying the UK Government to ensure that minimum pricing will be implemented UK wide. As a UK faculty, we are trying to ensure that.
I just want to ask about internet sales. I could sit in my home in Fife and order on the internet. There could be massive deliveries to any address in a major conurbation. If I purchased alcohol from a location outwith Scotland, it could retain that cheap price.
Previous
Subordinate Legislation